Skip to main content

An Integrated Approach to Pricing, Inventory, and Market Segmentation Decisions with Demand Leakage

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Book cover Operations Research Proceedings 2012

Part of the book series: Operations Research Proceedings ((ORP))

Abstract

Differentiated pricing is among the widely practised Revenue Management (RM) tactics in which a firm offers its products/services at differentiated prices to distinct markets. Earlier researches have shown that the benefits from differentiated pricing are evident when the market segmentation is assumed perfect which are regarded as distinct markets with deterministic demands. In perfect market segmentation customers associated with a market segment do not cannibalize (move) between market segments. However, it is not uncommon to notice that the market segmentation a firm exercises is seldom perfect, and due to imperfect segmentation customers cannibalize between market segments which is also referred as demand leakage. In addition to this, the demand is often uncertain, and thus a firm also experiences short sales and leftovers due to uncertain demand. This research addresses the issue of establishing an integrated framework to optimize price differentiation strategy, pricing, and order quantity for a firm that experiences demand leakage. The models to determine the optimal market segmentation strategy, pricing, and order quantities for a firm are developed facing price dependent deterministic demand, stochastic demand, and when the demand is stochastic, yet the distribution is unknown. The models are analyzed to identify the optimal pricing, order quantities, and price differentiation strategy. Numerical experimentation show that optimizing the price differentiation strategy (market segmentation) along with optimizing the joint pricing and order quantity decisions price significantly improve the revenue to a firm although it experiences customer cannibalization. This paper, however, only highlights the deterministic model and its analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  1. Bell, P. C.: Revenue management: That’s the ticket. OR/MS Today, 1998

    Google Scholar 

  2. Chiang, W.C., Chen, J.C.H., Xu, X.: An overview of research on revenue management: Current issues and future research. Int. J. Revenue Manag. 1(1), 97–128 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. McGill, J.I., Van Ryzin, G.J.: Revenue Management: Research overview and prospects. Transp. Sci. 33, 233–256 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Petruzzi, N.C., Dada, M.: Pricing and the news vendor problem: A review with extensions. Oper. Res. 47, 183–194 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Philips, R. L.: Pricing and revenue optimization. Standford university press, 2005

    Google Scholar 

  6. Talluri, K. T., Van Ryzin, G.: The Theory and Practice of Revenue Management. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht (2004)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This publication was made possible by the support of an NPRP grant # 4-173-5-025 from the Qatar National Research Fund. The statements made herein are solely the responsibility of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Syed Asif Raza .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Using the Karush Kuhn Tucker Optimality condition we get the following Lagrange function for the problem

$$\begin{aligned} L(p_1,p_2,\upsilon ,\lambda _1, \lambda _2)= (p_1 -c) z_1 + (p_2- c) z_2 + \lambda _1(p_1 -\upsilon ) + \lambda _2(\upsilon - p_2) \end{aligned}$$
(4.6)

Where in Eq. 4.6, \(z_1= (1 -\theta ) (\alpha _1 - \beta p_1) + \mu _1\), and \(z_2= (\beta \upsilon - \beta p_2) + \theta (\alpha _1 -~\beta \upsilon )+\mu _2\). Also \(\lambda _1\), and \(\lambda _2\) are non-negative. The First order Optimality Conditions (FOCs) are:

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial L}{\partial p_1}&= (p_1 -c) \frac{\partial z_1}{\partial p_1} + z_1 + \lambda _1 \le 0, p_1 \ge 0, \left( (p_1 -c) \frac{\partial z_1}{\partial p_1} + z_1 + \lambda _1 \right) p_1 =0 \end{aligned}$$
(4.7)
$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial L}{\partial p_2}&= (p_2 -c) \frac{\partial z_2}{\partial p_2} + z_2 - \lambda _2 \le 0, p_2 \ge 0, \left( (p_2 -c) \frac{\partial z_2}{\partial p_2} + z_2 - \lambda _2\right) p_2=0 \end{aligned}$$
(4.8)
$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial L}{\partial \upsilon }&= (1 - \theta ) \beta - \lambda _1 + \lambda _2 \le 0, \left( (1 - \theta ) \beta - \lambda _1 + \lambda _2\right) \upsilon =0 \end{aligned}$$
(4.9)
$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda _1}&= p_1 - \upsilon \ge 0, \lambda _1 \ge 0, \left( p_1 - \upsilon \right) \lambda _1 =0 \end{aligned}$$
(4.10)
$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda _2}&= \upsilon - p_2 \ge 0,\lambda _2 \ge 0, \left( \upsilon - p_2 \right) \lambda _2 =0 \end{aligned}$$
(4.11)

Consider Eq. 4.10, since \(p_1 \ge \upsilon \), and \(\left( \upsilon - p_1\right) \lambda _1 =0\), and \(\lambda _1 \ge 0\), thus the only feasible solution is, \(\upsilon = p_1\), and \(\lambda _1 > 0\). Now, since \(\upsilon = p_1\), from Eq. 4.11, we can only have \(p_2 < \upsilon \), which is possible only when \(\lambda _2=0\). Using Eq. 4.9, as \(\upsilon >0\), therefore,\(\lambda _1= (1-\theta ) \beta \), and \(\lambda _2= 0\). To find optimal prices, \(p_1\), and \(p_2\), we need to solve Eqs. 4.7 and 4.8. Notice here, \(\displaystyle \frac{\partial z_1}{\partial p_1} =-(1- \theta ) \beta \), and \(\displaystyle \frac{\partial z_2}{\partial p_2}= - \beta \). The unique optimal prices would be: \(p_1 = \displaystyle \frac{\mu _1}{2 \beta (1-\theta )}+\frac{\alpha _1+\beta +\beta c}{2 \beta }\); and \(p_2 = \displaystyle \frac{\alpha _1+\beta +\theta \left( \alpha _1-\beta (c+1)\right) +3 \beta c+\mu _1+2 \mu _2}{4 \beta }\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this paper

Cite this paper

Raza, S.A. (2014). An Integrated Approach to Pricing, Inventory, and Market Segmentation Decisions with Demand Leakage. In: Helber, S., et al. Operations Research Proceedings 2012. Operations Research Proceedings. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-00795-3_58

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics