Skip to main content
Log in

An axiomatization of the human development index

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In 2010 the UNDP unveiled a new methodology for the calculation of the Human Development Index (HDI). In this paper I investigate the normative and practical properties of this change vis a vis the original formulation of the HDI in 1990. The main conceptual innovation of the new index can be summarized as follows: the new HDI penalizes both low and uneven achievements across all dimensions of human development, whereas the old formulation is not sensitive to such uneven development. In practice, however, both methodologies agree considerably in terms of how they rank countries, but when they differ, the new methodology produces results more consistent with what the HDI is intended to measure: human development and capabilities, as conceptualized by Sen (Commodities and capabilities. Elsevier, Oxford 1985).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. UNDP (2010a), p. 14.

  2. Sen (2008), p. 23.

  3. For an account of the collaboration between Mahbud ul Haq and Sen that led to the publication of the first HDR in 1990 see UNDP (2010b) and Sen (2003a), pp. vii–xiii.

  4. UNDP (1990), p. 14. This is one of many references that can be given on the matter. See, e.g., the references in the reader compiled by Fukuda-Parr and Kumar (2003).

  5. Sen (2003b), p. 5.

  6. Sen (1995), p. 40.

  7. This is to some extent as in the approach of ‘household production functions’ developed by Becker (1976) and Lancaster (1966), but the capabilities approach goes well beyond that in the inclusion of functionings footnote 7 continued that cannot be easily seen as detached objects that the person or the household happen to ‘own’ or ‘produce.’ See Sen and Hawthorn (1989), p. 104.

  8. Sen (2008), p. 24.

  9. UNDP (1993), p. 105.

  10. Sen (2008), p. 24.

  11. Anand and Sen (1994a), p. 2.

  12. Herrero et al. (2010b), based on the contributions by Anand and Sen (1994a, b), Hicks (1997); Sagar and Najam (1998), Osberg and Sharpe (2002), Phillipson and Soares (2001), Pinilla and Goerlich (2004), Foster et al. (2005), Becker et al. (2005), Stiglitz et al. (2009) and Herrero et al. (2004).

  13. For example, in the old HDI an extra year of expected life would be deemed to contribute as much to the development of any country as ten extra months of expected schooling (instead of a full year), simply because the years of schooling across countries oscillate over a narrower range than life expectancy does. Normatively, however, it is not warranted that a dimensional achievement is more valuable for development simply because most countries have similar levels of attainment in that dimension.

  14. Point (c), regarding the distribution of achievements of these variables across the population in these countries, has been addressed by the UNDP by the launching, in 2010, of a HDI (the Inequality Adjusted Human Development Index) that fully takes those distributional considerations into account. The methodology and rationale for the computation of such index is explained in detail in Alkire and Foster (2010). In a related contribution, Hartgen and Klasen (2012), compute Human Development Indices at the household level for a sample of 15 countries. These household indices can then be used for constructing country level Human Development Indices that are affected by the level of inequality in human development existing across households.

  15. This assumption is called ‘Minimum lower boundedness’ in Herrero et al. (2010a).

  16. This is not to say that the raw variables themselves contribute equally to aggregate capabilities, a point to which I return in Sect. 4.2 below.

  17. This is, for example, the point of view implicit in the Gender Inequality Index launched by the UNDP in 2010. See Gaye et al. (2013).

  18. This was not so in the old formulation, as explained at the beginning of Sect. 3 above.

  19. UNDP (2010a), p. 216.

  20. In this respect, it is important to notice that the magnitudes of the tradeoffs under study do not appear to be very sensitive in practice to small changes in the values of the subsistence levels for life expectancy and income.

  21. Conservative in the sense that the HDI grows more slowly than any polynomial function of income as income grows.

  22. Aggressive in the sense that the HDI shrinks more rapidly than any polynomial function of income as income declines to the normatively determined subsistence level.

  23. Which is not to say there aren’t other sensible options, a point to which I return in Sect. 6.

  24. A much stronger form of independence.

  25. The Spearman and Kendall rank correlation coefficients between the multiplicative and the additive HDI rankings equal 0.9991 and 0.9784, respectively.

  26. The only mention of this convergence in the entire report is the following sentence: “The geometric

    mean has only a moderate impact on HDI ranks,” which shows up in page 217 of the 2010 HDR, in the statistical annex.

  27. Regardless, these were the principles of design implicit in the formulation adopted in 2010 and it is important for us all to understand what those principles say, if the HDI is to be used properly in policy circles worldwide.

References

  • Alkire S, Foster J (2010) Designing the inequality-adjusted human development index (IHDI). Human Development Reports Research Paper 2010/28

  • Anand S, Sen A (1994a) Human development index: methodology and measurement, Human Development Report Office Occasional Paper 12, UNDP

  • Anand S, Sen A (1994b) The income component of the human development index. J Hum Dev 1:83–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1976) The economic approach to human behavior. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker G, Phillipson T, Soares R (2005) The quantity and quality of life and the evolution of world inequality. Am Econ Rev 95:277–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty S (2003) A generalized human development index. Rev Dev Econ 7(1):99–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai M (1991) Human development: concepts and measure. Eur Econ Rev 35:350–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, López-Calva L, Székely M (2005) Measuring the distribution of human development: methodology and an application to Mexico. J Hum Dev Capab 6:5–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuda-Parr S, Kumar S (eds) (2003) Readings in human development. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Gaye A, Klugman J, Kovacevic M, Twigg S, Zambrano E (2013) Measuring key disparities in human development: the gender inequality index. In: Figart D, Warnecke T (eds) Handbook of research on gender and economic life. Edward Elgar, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartgen K, Klasen S (2012) A household-based human development index. World Dev 40(12):878–899

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrero C, Martínez R, Villar A (2010a) Multidimensional social evaluation. An application to the measurement of human development. Rev Income Wealth 56(3):483–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrero C, Martínez R, Villar A (2010b) Improving the measurement of human development, human development, Research Paper 2010

  • Herrero C, Soler A, Villar A (2004) Capital Humano y Desarrollo Humano en España, sus Comunidades Autónomas y Provincias. 1980–2000. Fundación Bancaja, Valencia

  • Hicks D (1997) The inequality-adjusted human development index: a constructive proposal. World Dev 25:1283–1298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lady E (2005) The logarithm function, manuscript. University of Hawaii

  • Lancaster K (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. J Political Econ 74:132–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2010) Historical statistics of the world economy: 1–2008 AD. Organisation for economic co-operation and development.

  • Moreno-Ternero J, Roemer J (2006) Impartiality, priority and solidarity in the theory of justice. Econometrica 74(5):1419–1427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osberg L, Sharpe A (2002) An index of economic wellbeing for selected OECD countries. Rev Income Wealth 48:291–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillipson T, Soares R (2001) Human capital, longevity and economic growth, manuscript. University of Chicago

  • Pinilla F, Goerlich F (2004) Renta per capita y potencial de calidad de vida en España (1981–1999). Investig Reg 4:53–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Riley J (2005) Poverty and life expectancy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion M (2012) Troubling tradeoffs in the human development index. J Dev Econ 99:201–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sagar A, Najam A (1998) The human development index: a critical review. Ecol Econ 25:249–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1985) Commodities and capabilities. Elsevier, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1995) Inequality reexamined. Harvard University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (2008) The economics of happiness and capability. In: Luigino A, Comin F, Pugno M (eds) Capabilities and happiness. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (2003a) Foreword. In: Fukuda-Parr S, Kumar S (eds) Readings in human development. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (2003b) Development as capability expansion. In: Fukuda-Parr S, Kumar S (eds) Readings in human development. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen A, Hawthorn G (eds) (1989) The standard of living. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Seth S (2009) Inequality, interactions and human development. J Hum Dev Capab 10:375–396

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seth S (2010) A class of association sensitive multidimensional welfare indices, manuscript. Vanderbilt University.

  • Stiglitz J, Sen A, Fitoussi J (2009) Beyond GDP. Report by the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress, European Commission

  • UNDP (1990) Human development report

  • UNDP (1993) Human development report

  • UNDP (2010a) Human development report

  • UNDP, A (2010b) 20th Anniversary human development discussion with Amartya Sen. http://hdr.undp.org/en/media/Amartya-Sen-interview-transcript.1.pdf. Accessed 30 March 2013

  • Zambrano E (2013a) The troubling tradeoffs paradox and a resolution, manuscript, California Polytechnic State University.

  • Zambrano E (2013b) Polity human development indices, manuscript, California Polytechnic State University.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am indebted to Francisco Rodríguez, Jeni Klugman, Antonio Villar, Herve Roche, Emma Samman and especially two anonymous referees for their very valuable input, and Martin Heiger for his research assistance. Research support from the UNDP and the Orfalea College of Business and the hospitality of the Institute for International Economic Policy at George Washington University is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eduardo Zambrano.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Theorem 1

\(\left( \leftarrow \right) \hbox {Let}HDI\left( {h,e,y} \right) =I\left( {C_h \left( h \right) ,C_e \left( e \right) ,C_y \left( y \right) } \right) \) with \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =C_h ^{1/3}\cdot C_e ^{1/3}\cdot C_y ^{1/3}\) and \(C_h \left( h \right) =\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}, C_e \left( e \right) =\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}, C_y \left( y \right) =\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\) .

Functions \(C_h \left( h \right) , C_e \left( e \right) \) and \(C_y \left( y \right) \) are all strictly increasing, and so is \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) \) in all its arguments. Therefore, Monotonicity holds. Now let (h,e,y), (h’,e’,y’) be in \(\Omega \) with \(h,h^{{\prime }}>h^{o};e,e^{{\prime }}>e^{o}and\,y,y^{{\prime }}>y^{o}\) and assume \(C(h,e,y)\ge C(h,e^{{\prime }},y^{{\prime }})\). If we multiply each side by \(\left[ {C_h \left( h^{{\prime }} \right) /C_h \left( h \right) } \right] ^{\frac{1}{3}}\) we get \(C(h^{\prime },e,y)\ge C(h^{\prime },e^{{\prime }},y^{{\prime }})\). Now assume \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) \ge C\left( {h^{{\prime }},e,y^{{\prime }}} \right) .\) If we multiply each side by \(\left[ {C_e \left( {e^{\prime }} \right) /C_e \left( e \right) } \right] ^{\frac{1}{3}}\) we get \(C\left( {h,e^{{\prime }},y} \right) \ge C\left( {h^{{\prime }},e^{{\prime }},y^{{\prime }}} \right) .\) Now assume \(C(h,e,y)\ge C(h^{\prime },e^{\prime },y)\). If we multiply each side by \(\left[ {C_y \left( {y^{\prime }} \right) /C_y \left( y \right) } \right] ^{\frac{1}{3}}\) we get \(C(h,e,y^{\prime })\ge C(h^{\prime },e^{\prime },y^{\prime })\). Therefore Independence holds. Since \(C_h \left( {h^{o}} \right) =C_e \left( {e^{o}} \right) =C_y \left( {y^{o}} \right) =0\) and \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) \) is multiplicative, clearly Subsistence holds. Scale holds since \(I\left( {c,c,c} \right) =c\). Now fix \((h,e,y) \)  and consider feasible values for \(\Delta h, \Delta e\) and \(d_y \). Then \(\Delta C_h \left( {h,\Delta h} \right) =\frac{\Delta h}{h^{*}-h^{o}}, \Delta C_e \left( {e,\Delta e} \right) =\frac{\Delta e}{e^{*}-e^{o}}\) and \(\Delta C_y \left( {y,y \cdot d_y } \right) =\frac{\log \left( {1+d_y } \right) }{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\). Therefore Partial Capabilities Growth holds. Aggregation Symmetry is straightforward to verify.

\(\left( \rightarrow \right) \) Since \(C\) satisfies Monotonicity, Subsistence and Independence it is a consequence of Theorem 1 in Herrero et al. (2010a) that

$$\begin{aligned} C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =f\left( h \right) \cdot g\left( e \right) \cdot m\left( y \right) \!, \end{aligned}$$

where \(f\left( h \right) :H\rightarrow \left[ {0,1} \right] ,g\left( e \right) :E\rightarrow \left[ {0,1} \right] \mathrm{and}\,m\left( y \right) :Y\rightarrow \left[ {0,1} \right] \) are increasing functions such that \(f\left( {h^{o}} \right) =g\left( {e^{o}} \right) =m\left( {y^{o}} \right) =0\) and \(f\left( {h^{*}} \right) =g\left( {e^{*}} \right) =m\left( {y^{*}} \right) =1.\) By Scale and Aggregation Symmetry, \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =C_h ^{1/3}\cdot C_e ^{1/3}\cdot C_y ^{1/3}\) with \(C_h \left( h \right) =f\left( h \right) ^{3}, C_e \left( e \right) =g\left( h \right) ^{3}, C_y \left( y \right) =m\left( y \right) ^{3}\). Partial Capabilities Growth implies that (i) \(C_h \left( h \right) \) is of the form \(C_h \left( h \right) =\alpha _h +\beta _h h\) for some values for \(\alpha _h \) and \(\beta _h ,\) and \(C_h \left( {h^{o}} \right) =0, C_h \left( {h^{*}} \right) =1\) implies that \(C_h \left( h \right) =\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}\). (ii) \(C_e \left( e \right) \) is of the form \(C_e \left( e \right) =\alpha _e +\beta _e e\) and \(C_e \left( {e^{o}} \right) =0, C_e \left( {e^{*}} \right) =1\) implies that \(C_e \left( e \right) =\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}\). (iii) \(C_y \left( y \right) =\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\). To see this last step let \(s\left( y \right) =C_y \left( y \right) \) and notice that Partial Capabilities Growth implies that

$$\begin{aligned} s\left( {y\left( {1+d_y } \right) } \right) =s\left( y \right) +s\left( {\left( {1+d_y } \right) y^{o}} \right) \!. \end{aligned}$$

Now let \(a=d_y \cdot y\). Then \(s\left( {\left( {1+\frac{a}{y}} \right) y} \right) =s\left( y \right) +s\left( {\left( {1+\frac{a}{y}} \right) y^{o}} \right) .\) The steps below are based on Lady (2005):

Step 1: Show \(s^{\prime }\left( y \right) =\frac{K}{y}\) for some constant \(K\). To see that this is so notice that

$$\begin{aligned} s^{{\prime }}\left( y \right)&= \mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y+a} \right) -s\left( y \right) }{a}=\mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y\left( {1+\frac{a}{y}} \right) } \right) -s\left( y \right) }{a}\\&= \mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( y \right) +s\left( {\left( {1+\frac{a}{y}} \right) y^{o}} \right) -s\left( y \right) }{a}\\&= \mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {\left( {1+\frac{a}{y}} \right) y^{o}} \right) -s\left( {y^{o}} \right) }{a}=\mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y^{o}+\frac{a}{y}y^{o}} \right) -s\left( {y^{o}} \right) }{a}\\&= \mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y^{o}+\frac{y^{o}}{y}a} \right) -s\left( {y^{o}} \right) }{\frac{y}{y^{o}}\frac{y^{o}}{y}a}\\&= \frac{y^{o}}{\hbox {y}}\mathop {\lim }\limits _{a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y^{o}+\frac{y^{o}}{y}a} \right) -s\left( {y^{o}} \right) }{\frac{y^{o}}{y}a}=\frac{y^{o}}{\hbox {y}}\mathop {\lim }\limits _{\frac{y^{o}}{y}a\rightarrow 0} \frac{s\left( {y^{o}+\frac{y^{o}}{y}a} \right) -s\left( {y^{o}} \right) }{\frac{y^{o}}{y}a}\\&= \frac{y^{o}}{\hbox {y}}s^{{\prime }}\left( {y^{o}} \right) \end{aligned}$$

with the desired constant \(K\) given by \(y^{o}s^{{\prime }}\left( {y^{o}} \right) \). Notice that K \(\ne \) 0 because otherwise \(s^{{\prime }}\left( y \right) =0\)  and \(s\) would be a constant function, which cannot be since \(s\left( {y^{o}} \right) =0\) and \(s\left( {y^{*}} \right) =1\). Indeed, the same argument shows that \(K>0\) and that therefore \(s\) is a strictly increasing function.

Step 2: Show that \(s\left( {y^{r} \cdot y^{o}} \right) =rs\left( {y \cdot y^{o}} \right) \). To see this notice that, by the Chain Rule,

\(\frac{d}{dy}s\left( {y^{r} \cdot y^{o}} \right) =\frac{K}{y^{r} \cdot y^{o}}y^{o}ry^{r-1}=r\frac{K}{y}=rs^{{\prime }}\left( y \right) ,\) and \(s^{\prime }\left( {y \cdot y^{o}} \right) =\frac{K}{y \cdot y^{o}}y^{o}=s^{{\prime }}\left( y \right) \).

The implication is that, since \(rs\left( {y \cdot y^{o}} \right) \) and \(s\left( {y^{r} \cdot y^{o}} \right) \)  have the same derivative, they differ by a constant, that is, \(rs\left( {y \cdot y^{o}} \right) =s\left( {y^{r} \cdot y^{o}} \right) +Q\), for some number \(Q\). Letting \(y=1\) shows \(Q =0\), since \(s\left( {y^{o}} \right) =0\).

Step 3: Show that \(\ell =s(y)\) if and only if \(\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \right) ^{\ell }=\frac{y}{y^{o}}\), that is, \(\ell \) is the logarithm of \(\frac{y}{y^{o}}\) with respect to the base \(\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}.\)

To see this notice that, by the conclusion from Step 2 above,\(\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \right) ^{\ell }=\frac{y}{y^{o}}\) implies \(s\left( y \right) =s\left( {\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \right) ^{\ell }y^{o}} \right) =\ell \cdot s\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}} \cdot y^{o}} \right) =\ell \cdot s\left( {y^{*}} \right) =\ell .\)

On the other hand, \(\ell =s(y)\) implies, as shown above, that \(s\left( y \right) =s\left( {\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \right) ^{\ell }y^{o}} \right) \) and since \(s\) is strictly increasing it follows that \(y=\left( {\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \right) ^{\ell }y^{o}\).

I have thus shown that \(C_y \left( y \right) =s\left( y \right) =\log _{\frac{y^{*}}{y^{o}}} \frac{y}{y^{o}}=\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\) and the proof is complete.

To separate the properties consider the following indices:

  1. (1)

    The \(HDI_a \). Satisfies Monotonicity, Independence, Scale, Aggregation Symmetry and Partial Capabilities Growth but not Subsistence.

  2. (2)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =0.\) Satisfies Subsistence, Independence, Scale, Aggregation Symmetry and Partial Capabilities Growth but not Monotonicity.

  3. (3)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}\cdot \frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}\cdot \frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\quad .\) Satisfies Subsistence, Independence, Monotonicity, Partial Capabilities Growth and Aggregation Symmetry but not Scale.

  4. (4)

    \( C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =\frac{\log h-\log h^{o}}{\log h^{*}-\log h^{o}}^{1/3}\cdot \frac{\log e-\log e^{o}}{\log e^{*}-\log e^{o}}^{1/3}\cdot \frac{y-y^{o}}{y^{*}-y^{o}}^{1/3}.\) Satisfies Subsistence, Independence, Monotonicity, Aggregation Symmetry, Scale, but not Partial Capabilities Growth.

  5. (5)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =min\left\{ {\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}},\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}},\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}} \right\} \) Satisfies Subsistence, Partial Capabilities Growth, Monotonicity, Aggregation Symmetry, Scale, but not Independence.

  6. (6)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =\left( {\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}} \right) ^{a}\cdot \left( {\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}} \right) ^{b}\cdot \left( {\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}} \right) ^{c}\) with \(a+b+c=1\) and \(a\ne b\ne c.\) Satisfies Subsistence, Independence, Monotonicity, Partial Capabilities Growth, Scale but not Aggregation Symmetry.

\(\square \)

Proof of Theorem 2

\(\left( \leftarrow \right) \hbox {Let}\,\, HDI_a \left( {h,e,y} \right) =I_a \left( {C_h \left( h \right) ,C_e \left( e \right) ,C_y \left( y \right) } \right) \) with \(I_a \left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =\frac{C_h +C_e +C_y }{3}\) and \(C_h \left( h \right) =\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}, C_e \left( e \right) =\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}, C_y \left( y \right) =\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\) .

Functions \(C_h \left( h \right) , C_e \left( e \right) \) and \(C_y \left( y \right) \) are all strictly increasing, and so is \(I_a \left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) \) in all its arguments. Therefore, Monotonicity holds. Now let (h,e,y), (h’,e’,y’) be in \(\Omega \) with \(h,h^{{\prime }}>h^{o};e,e^{{\prime }}>e^{o}\mathrm{and}\,y,y^{{\prime }}>y^{o}\) and assume \(C(h,e,y)\ge C(h,e^{{\prime }},y^{{\prime }})\). If we add \(\frac{1}{3}\left( {C_h \left( {h^{\prime }} \right) -C_h \left( h \right) } \right) \) to each side we get \(C(h^{\prime },e,y)\ge C(h^{\prime },e^{{\prime }},y^{{\prime }})\) . Scale holds since \(I_a \left( {c,c,c} \right) =c\). Now fix \((h,e,y) \)and consider feasible values for \(\Delta h, \Delta e\) and \(d_y \). Then \(\Delta C_h \left( {h,\Delta h,e,y} \right) =\frac{1}{3}\frac{\Delta h}{h^{*}-h^{o}}, \Delta C_e \left( {h,e,\Delta e,y} \right) =\frac{1}{3}\frac{\Delta e}{e^{*}-e^{o}}\) and \(\Delta C_y \left( {h,e,y,y \cdot d_y } \right) =\frac{1}{3}\frac{\log \left( {1+d_y } \right) }{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\). Thus Partial Capabilities Growth holds. Now fix (\(C_h ,C_e ,C_y ) \quad \) and consider feasible values for \(\Delta C_h \quad \Delta C_e \) and \(\Delta C_y\). Then \(\Delta I_h \left( {C_h ,\Delta C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =\frac{1}{3}\Delta C_h , \quad \Delta I_e \left( {C_h ,C_e ,\Delta C_e ,C_y } \right) =\frac{1}{3}\Delta C_e \) and \( \Delta I_y \left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y ,\Delta C_y } \right) =\frac{1}{3}\Delta C_y .\) Therefore, Capabilities Growth Independence holds. Aggregation Symmetry is straightforward to verify.

\(\left( \rightarrow \right) \) Since \(C\) satisfies Monotonicity and Capabilities Growth Independence, for any pair \(\left( {C_e ,C_y } \right) \in \left[ {0,1} \right] ^{2}\) there exists \(\beta _h \in \mathbb{R }_{++} \) and \(\alpha _h ,\gamma _h \in \mathbb{R }\) such that: \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =\alpha _h +\beta _h \cdot C_h +\gamma _h \cdot I\left( {1,C_e ,C_y } \right) \). Now, again by Monotonicity and Capabilities Growth Independence, for any \(C_y \in \left[ {0,1} \right] \) and given \(C_h =1\) there exists \(\beta _e \in \mathbb{R }_{++} \) and \(\alpha _e ,\gamma _e \in \mathbb{R }\) such that \(I\left( {1,C_e ,C_y } \right) =\alpha _e +\beta _e \cdot C_e +\gamma _e \cdot I\left( {1,1,C_y } \right) \). Monotonicity and Capabilities Growth Independence, again, imply that given \(C_h =C_h =1\) there exists \(\beta _y \in \mathbb{R }_{++} \) and \(\alpha _y ,\gamma _y \in \mathbb{R }\) such that \(I\left( {1,1,C_y } \right) =\alpha _y +\beta _y \cdot C_y +\gamma _y \cdot I\left( {1,1,1} \right) \). Nesting these implications we get

$$\begin{aligned} I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right)&= \left( {\alpha _h +\gamma _h \cdot \alpha _e +\gamma _h \cdot \gamma _e \cdot \left( {\alpha _h +\gamma _y } \right) } \right) \nonumber \\&+\left( {\beta _h \cdot C_h +\gamma _h \cdot \beta _e \cdot C_e +\gamma _h \cdot \gamma _e \cdot \beta _y \cdot C_y } \right) \!. \end{aligned}$$

Letting \(C_h =C_e =C_y =0\) we learn that \(\left( {\alpha _h +\gamma _h \cdot \alpha _e +\gamma _h \cdot \gamma _e \cdot \left( {\alpha _h +\gamma _y } \right) } \right) =0.\) By Aggregation Symmetry, \(\beta _h =\gamma _h \cdot \beta _e =\gamma _h \cdot \gamma _e \cdot \beta _y \)and Scale implies that \(\beta _h +\gamma _h \cdot \beta _e +\gamma _h \cdot \gamma _e \cdot \beta _y =1.\) The consequence is that \(I\left( {C_h ,C_e ,C_y } \right) =\frac{C_h +C_e +C_y }{3}\). From this point on, the proof that the partial capabilities indices \(C_h \left( h \right) , C_e \left( e \right) \) and \(C_y \left( y \right) \) are of the desired form follows the same steps as in the proof of Theorem 1 above. I omit the details here.

To separate the properties consider the following indices:

  1. (1)

    The new \(HDI\). Satisfies Monotonicity, Aggregation Symmetry, Scale and Partial Capabilities Growth but not Capabilities Growth Independence.

  2. (2)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =0.\) Satisfies Capabilities Growth Independence, Aggregation Symmetry, Scale and Partial Capabilities Growth but not Monotonicity.

  3. (3)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}+\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}+\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\quad \). Satisfies Capabilities Growth Independence, Monotonicity, Partial Capabilities Growth and Aggregation Symmetry but not Scale.

  4. (4)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =\frac{1}{3}\frac{\log h-\log h^{o}}{\log h^{*}-\log h^{o}}+\frac{1}{3}\frac{\log e-\log e^{o}}{\log e^{*}-\log e^{o}}+\frac{1}{3}\frac{y-y^{o}}{y^{*}-y^{o}}\). Satisfies Capabilities Growth Independence, Monotonicity, Scale and Aggregation Symmetry but not Partial Capabilities Growth.

  5. (5)

    \(C\left( {h,e,y} \right) =a\frac{h-h^{o}}{h^{*}-h^{o}}+b\frac{e-e^{o}}{e^{*}-e^{o}}+c\frac{\log y-\log y^{o}}{\log y^{*}-\log y^{o}}\) with \(a+b+c=1\) and \(a\ne b\ne c.\) Satisfies Capabilities Growth Independence, Monotonicity, Partial Capabilities Growth and Scale but not Aggregation Symmetry.

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Zambrano, E. An axiomatization of the human development index. Soc Choice Welf 42, 853–872 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-013-0756-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-013-0756-9

Keywords

Navigation