Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Frugal innovation in supply chain cooperation considering e-retailer’s platform value

  • Methodologies and Application
  • Published:
Soft Computing Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

E-retailers have recently paid close attention to frugal innovation in their supply chains. However, there are few studies on frugal innovation considering the e-retailer’s platform value raised by the increase in the platform user scale. Motivated by industrial practice, we consider a supply chain consisting of an e-retailer and a manufacturer in the context of frugal innovation, where the platform value of the retailer is characterized by Metcalfe’s law. We use game models to investigate the frugal product price and optimal degree of frugality decisions for the centralized, decentralized, retailer-led revenue-sharing contract and bargaining revenue-sharing contract scenarios. Our results indicate that the bargaining revenue-sharing contract can improve the frugal degree of the development-intensive frugal product (DIFP), while the frugal degree of the marginal cost-intensive frugal product (MIFP) cannot be improved by cooperation in the supply chain. We then compare the supply chain profit, the platform value of the retailer and the profit of the manufacturer in different scenarios. The results show that the centralized scenario is the optimal scenario where the platform retailer implements vertical integration strategy. Otherwise, establishing strategic partnership through the bargaining revenue-sharing contract is suboptimal for both the platform retailer and the manufacturer.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abichandani Y (2012) Jugaad innovation: think frugal, be flexible, generate breakthrough growth. Eur J Train Dev 38(7):689–691

    Google Scholar 

  • Agnihotri A (2015) Lowcost innovation in emerging markets. J Strateg Market 23(5):399–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson EG Jr, Parker GG, Tan B (2014) Platform performance investment in the presence of network externalities. Inf Syst Res 25(1):152–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowman J (2019) Top Chinese e-commerce stocks to buy in 2019. https://finance.yahoo.com/news/top-chinese-e-commerce-stocks-163100177.html

  • Briscoe B, Odlyzko A, Tilly B (2006) Metcalfe law is wrong-communications networks increase in value as they add members-but by how much. IEEE Spectr 43(7):34–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers C, Kouvelis P, Semple J (2006) Quality-based competition, profitability, and variable costs. Manage Sci 52(12):1884–1895

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chen L, Peng J, Liu Z, Zhao R (2017) Pricing and effort decisions for a supply chain with uncertain information. Int J Prod Res 55(1):264–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gassmann O, Neumann L, Knapp O, Zollenkop M (2017) Frugal: simply a smart solution. Roland Berger Focus 8:1–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghosh D, Shah J (2015) Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract. Int J Prod Econ 164:319–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannoccaro I, Pontrandolfo P (2004) Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int J Prod Econ 89(2):131–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hänninen M, Mitronen L, Kwan S (2019) Multi-sided marketplaces and the transformation of retail a service systems perspective. J Retail Consum Serv 49:380–388

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendler J, Golbeck J (2008) Metcalfe’s law, web 2.0, and the semantic web. Web Semant Sci Serv Agents World Wide Web 6(1):14–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain M (2017) Mapping the frugal innovation phenomenon. Soc Sci Electron Publ 51:199–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Hossain M (2018) Frugal innovation: a review and research agenda. J Clean Prod 182:926–936

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hossain M, Simula H, Halme M (2016) Can frugal go global? Diffusion patterns of frugal innovations. Technol Soc 46:132–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao L, Chen YJ (2014) Strategic motive for introducing internet channels in a supply chain. Prod Oper Manage 23(1):36–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huawei (2019) Huawei investment holdings co., ltd. 2018 annual report. https://www.huawei.com/cn/press-events/annual-report/2018

  • Jiang B, Jerath K, Srinivasan K (2011) Firm strategies in the ‘mid tail’ of platform-based retailing. Market Sci 30(5):757–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahle HN, Dubiel A, Ernst H, Prabhu J (2013) The democratizing effects of frugal innovation. J Indian Bus Res

  • Khan R (2016) How frugal innovation promotes social sustainability. Sustainability 8(10):1034

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim K, Chhajed D (2002) Product design with multiple quality-type attributes. Manage Sci 48(11):1502–1511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kong X (2018) The top-selling 288 yuan sweeping robot sold by pdd were producted in this way... http://www.sohu.com/a/281593618_161795

  • Krishnan V, Gupta S (2001) Appropriateness and impact of platform-based product development. Manage Sci 47(1):52–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnan V, Zhu W (2006) Designing a family of development-intensive products. Manage Sci 52(6):813–825

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacourbe P, Loch CH, Kavadias S (2010) Product positioning in a two-dimensional market space. Prod Oper Manage 18(3):315–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levänen J, Hossain M, Lyytinen T, Hyvärinen A, Numminen S, Halme M (2016) Implications of frugal innovations on sustainable development: evaluating water and energy innovations. Sustainability 8(1)

  • Linh CT, Hong Y (2009) Channel coordination through a revenue sharing contract in a two-period newsboy problem. Eur J Oper Res 198(3):822–829

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Max M, Anne M, Rukhshana M (2016) Saving, scrimping, and...splurging? New insights into consumer behavior. https://www.mckinsey.com/industries/consumer-packaged-goods/our-insights/saving-scrimping-and-splurging-new-insights-into-consumer-behavior

  • Meagher K (2018) Cannibalizing the informal economy: frugal innovation and economic inclusion in Africa. Eur J Dev Res 30(1):17–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moon K, Bimpikis K, Mendelson H (2018) Randomized markdowns and online monitoring. Manage Sci 64(3):1271–1290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moorthy KS, Png IPL (1992) Market segmentation, cannibalization, and the timing of product introductions. Manage Sci 38(3):345–359

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M, Rosen S (1978) Monopoly and product quality. J Econ Theory 18(2):301–317

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • PDD (2019) Pinduoduo inc. 2018 annual report. http://investor.pinduoduo.com/financial-information/annual-reports

  • Perdikaki O, Peng DX, Heim GR (2015) Impact of customer traffic and service process outsourcing levels on e-retailer operational performance. Prod Oper Manage 24(11):1794–1811

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pisoni A, Michelini L, Martignoni G (2018) Frugal approach to innovation: state of the art and future perspectives. J Clean Prod 171:107–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prabhu J, Jain S (2015) Innovation and entrepreneurship in India: understanding Jugaad. Asia Pacific J Manage 32(4):843–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian L (2011) Product price and performance level in one market or two separated markets under various cost structures and functions. Int J Prod Econ 131(2):505–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed DP (2001) The law of the pack. Harvard Bus Rev 79(2):23–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet JC, Tirole J (2003) Platform competition in two-sided markets. J Eur Econ Assoc 1(4):990–1029

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosca E, Arnold M, Bendul JC (2017) Business models for sustainable innovation—an empirical analysis of frugal products and services. J Clean Prod 162:S133–S145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C, Carl S, Varian HR et al (1998) Information rules: a strategic guide to the network economy. Harvard Business Press, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharma A, Iyer GR (2012) Resource-constrained product development: implications for green marketing and green supply chains. Ind Market Manage 41(4):599–608 (green marketing and its impact on supply chain)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen Y, Willems SP, Dai Y (2019) Channel selection and contracting in the presence of a retail platform. Prod Oper Manage 28(5):1173–1185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shibin KT, Dubey R, Gunasekaran A, Luo Z, Papadopoulos T, Roubaud D (2018) Frugal innovation for supply chain sustainability in smes: multi-method research design. Prod Plan Control 29(11):908–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song H, Gao X (2018) Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing contract. J Clean Prod 170:183–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang F (2017) Demystifying netease’s strict selection of factories: How to achieve ‘good life is not so expensive’? https://www.yicai.com/news/5365721.html

  • Weyrauch T, Herstatt C (2017) What is frugal innovation? Three defining criteria. J Frugal Innov 2(1):1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao Z, Leung SC, Lai KK (2008) Manufacturer’s revenue-sharing contract and retail competition. Eur J Oper Res 186(2):637–651

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Yu X (2019) The small-biu sweeper of suning, scheduled to only 999 yuan. http://biz.ifeng.com/a/20190403/45588066_0.shtml

  • Zeschky M, Widenmayer B, Gassmann O (2014) Organising for reverse innovation in western mncs: the role of frugal product innovation capabilities. Int J Technol Manage 64(2–4):255–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang P, Xiong Y, Xiong Z (2015) Coordination of a dual-channel supply chain after demand or production cost disruptions. Int J Prod Res 53(10):3141–3160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu W, He Y (2017) Green product design in supply chains under competition. Eur J Oper Res 258(1):165–180

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the associate editor and the anonymous referees for their thorough and constructive comments. This research is supported in part by the Graduate Innovative Research Projects of Chongqing Technology and Business University (yjscxx2019-101-90).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rong Gao.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Communicated by V. Loia.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

A Proof of Proposition 2

As for the DIFP, we first compare the optimal degree of frugality under revenue-sharing contract and centralized model. Note that the condition \(a, \beta \ne 0, 4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2\ne 0\) and \(8r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2\ne 0\) implies that \(a, \beta \ne 0, 4r-\frac{\beta ^2}{1-\lambda ^2}\ne 0\) and \(8r-\frac{\beta ^2}{1-\lambda ^2}\ne 0\). Since \(\frac{a\beta }{4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}>\frac{a\beta }{2[4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2]}=\frac{a\beta }{8r(1-\lambda ^2)-2\beta ^2}>\frac{a\beta }{8r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}\), we can obtain that \(\alpha (B)>\alpha (RS)>\alpha (D)\).

Then, we should prove that \(\alpha (B)>\alpha (BS)>\alpha (RS)\). Since \(\frac{a\beta }{4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}>\frac{2}{3}\cdot \frac{a\beta }{4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}=\frac{2a\beta }{12r(1-\lambda ^2)-3\beta ^2}>\frac{1}{2}\cdot \frac{a\beta }{4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}= \frac{a\beta }{8r(1-\lambda ^2)-2\beta ^2}\), we know that \(\alpha (B)>\alpha (BS)>\alpha (RS)\). Thus, \(\alpha (B)>\alpha (BS)>\alpha (RS)>\alpha (D)\) when \(a, \beta \ne 0, 4r-\frac{\beta ^2}{1-\lambda ^2}\ne 0\) and \(8r-\frac{\beta ^2}{1-\lambda ^2}\ne 0\).

B Proof of Proposition 4

We first compare the total supply chain profit of the MIFP under different scenarios. From Table 2, it is easy to say that \(\frac{(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{64k^2(1-\lambda ^2)}>\frac{(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{72k^2(1-\lambda ^2)}>\frac{3(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{256k^2(1-\lambda ^2)}\). Since \(\varPi _C^m(D)=\varPi _C^m(RS)\), it can be derived that \(\varPi _C^m(B)>\varPi _C^m(BS)>\varPi _C^m(RS)=\varPi _C^m(D)\). Note that the condition is \(k\ne 0\).

For the DIFP, we first compare the total supply chain profit under centralized model, bargaining revenue-sharing contract and revenue-sharing contract. Since \(\frac{a^r}{4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}>\frac{8a^r}{9[4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2]}=\frac{8a^2r}{36r(1-\lambda ^2)-9\beta ^2}>\frac{3a^2r}{4[4r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2]}=\frac{3a^2r}{16r(1-\lambda ^2)-4\beta ^2}\), it is easy to see that \(\varPi _C^d(B)>\varPi _C^d(BS)>\varPi _C^d(RS)\). The conditions of establishment are \(a, r, \beta \ne 0\) and \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}\ne \frac{4r}{\beta ^2}\). Next, we compare the total supply chain profit between decentralized model and revenue-sharing contract. It can be obtained that \(\scriptstyle {\frac{\varPi _C^d(D)}{\varPi _C^d(RS)}=\frac{192r^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2-48r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2-16r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2+4\beta ^4}{192r^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2-48r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2+3\beta ^4}}\). When \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}\le 16r\), \(\varPi _C^d(B)>\varPi _C^d(BS)>\varPi _C^d(RS)\ge \varPi _C^d(D)\). When \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}>16r\), \(\varPi _C^d(RS)<\varPi _C^d(D)\). We continue to compare the total supply chain profit under the decentralized model and bargaining revenue-sharing contract. Similarly, we can obtain that when \(16r<\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}\le \frac{20r}{\beta ^2}\), the order is \(\varPi _C^d(B)>\varPi _C^d(BS)\ge \varPi _C^d(D)>\varPi _C^d(RS)\); when \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}>\frac{20r}{\beta ^2}\), the order is \(\varPi _C^d(B)>\varPi _C^d(D)>\varPi _C^d(BS)>\varPi _C^d(RS)\), while in practice \(\lambda \in [0,0.5]\Leftrightarrow \frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}<1.3\), \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}\) will not be larger than 16r. In summary, \(\varPi _C^d(B)>\varPi _C^d(BS)>\varPi _C^d(RS)\ge \varPi _C^d(D)\).

C Proof of Proposition 5

When the centralized scenario cannot be realized, the bargaining revenue-sharing contract is the optimal contract to coordinate the supply chain. Both the manufacturer and the e-retailer have incentive to choose this contract. For the manufacturer of the MIFP, since \(\frac{(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{128k^2(1-\lambda ^2)}<\frac{(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{96k^2(1-\lambda ^2)}\) (\(k\ne 0\)), \(\varPi _M^m(BS)>\varPi _M^m(D)=\varPi _M^m(RS)\). The profit of the manufacturer under bargaining revenue-sharing contract is larger than other scenarios. For the e-retailer selling the MIFP on the platform, since \(\frac{\lambda ^2(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{64k^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2}>\frac{\lambda ^2(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{144k^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2}>\frac{\lambda ^2(\beta ^2+4ak)^2}{256k^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2}\), the platform value added under centralized model is larger than other scenarios. Moreover, the platform value added under bargaining revenue-sharing contract is the second largest. Therefore, if the centralized model cannot be achieved, the bargaining revenue-sharing contract is the optimal contract both for the manufacturer and the e-retailer.

For the manufacturer of the DIFP, since \(\frac{2a^2r}{12r(1-\lambda ^2)-3\beta ^2}>\frac{a^2r}{8r(1-\lambda ^2)-2\beta ^2}>\frac{a^2r}{8r(1-\lambda ^2)-\beta ^2}\) (\(r\ne 0\)), \(\varPi _M^d(BS)>\varPi _M^d(RS)>\varPi _M^d(D)\). The profit of the manufacturer under bargaining revenue-sharing contract is larger than other scenarios. For the e-retailer selling the DIFP, since \(\frac{4a^2r^2\lambda ^2}{(4r-4r\lambda ^2-\beta ^2)^2}>\frac{16a^2r^2\lambda ^2}{9(4r-4r\lambda ^2-\beta ^2)^2}>\frac{a^2r^2\lambda ^2}{(4r-4r\lambda ^2-\beta ^2)^2}\), \(V^d(B)>V^d(BS)>V^d(RS)\), where we use V to denote the platform value added. The platform value added under bargaining revenue-sharing contract is larger than revenue-sharing contract. We then compare \(V^d(D)\) and \(V^d(RS)\) by using the equation \(\frac{V^d(D)}{V^d(RS)}=\frac{64r^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2-32r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2+4\beta ^4}{64r^2(1-\lambda ^2)^2-16r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2+\beta ^4}\). It is easy to see that when \(3\beta ^4-16r(1-\lambda ^2)\beta ^2>0\), \(V^d(D)>V^d(RS)\). By algebra, we have \(V^d(D)>V^d(RS)\Leftrightarrow 3\beta ^2>16r(1-\lambda ^2)\Leftrightarrow \frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}>\frac{16r}{3\beta ^2}\), where \(\beta \ne 0\). The parameter \(\lambda \) represents the user conversion rate of the platform e-retailer, and \(\lambda \in [0,0.5]\) in practice usually. Hence, \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}<1.3\). The parameters r and \(\beta \) reflect the fixed cost coefficient of the DIFP and the consumer sensitivity with respect to the frugal level \(\alpha \), respectively. r is much larger than \(\beta \) in practice. In summary, what is in line with the actual situation is that \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}<\frac{16r}{3\beta ^2}\). Therefore, \(\frac{1}{1-\lambda ^2}<\frac{16r}{3\beta ^2}\Leftrightarrow V^d(D)<V^d(RS)\). It can be obtained that \(V^d(B)>V^d(BS)>V^d(RS)>V^d(D)\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Li, Z., Zhang, H. & Gao, R. Frugal innovation in supply chain cooperation considering e-retailer’s platform value. Soft Comput 24, 15373–15387 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-020-04872-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-020-04872-1

Keywords

Navigation