Skip to main content
Log in

Two-sided search with experts

  • Published:
Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we study distributed agent matching in environments characterized by uncertain signals, costly exploration, and the presence of an information broker. Each agent receives information about the potential value of matching with others. This information signal may, however, be noisy, and the agent incurs some cost in receiving it. If all candidate agents agree to the matching the team is formed and each agent receives the true unknown utility of the matching, and leaves the market. We consider the effect of the presence of information brokers, or experts, on the outcomes of such matching processes. Experts can, upon payment of either a fee or a commission, perform the service of disambiguating noisy signals and revealing the true value of a match to any agent. We analyze equilibrium behavior given the fee set by a monopolist expert and use this analysis to derive the revenue maximizing strategy for the expert as the first mover in a Stackelberg game. Interestingly, we find that better information can hurt: the presence of the expert, even if the use of her services is optional, can degrade both individual agents’ utilities and overall social welfare. While in one-sided search the presence of the expert can only help, in two-sided (and general \(k\)-sided) search the externality imposed by the fact that others are consulting the expert can lead to a situation where the equilibrium outcome is that everyone consults the expert, even though all agents would be better off if the expert were not present. As an antidote, we show how market designers can enhance welfare by compensating the expert to change the price at which she offers her services.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See “Appendix 2” for a summary of all the notations used in this paper.

  2. For simplicity of presentation, and in line with the literature, we focus on partnerships of size two. The extension to teams of any size \(k\) is straightforward, as described in Sect. 4.3.

  3. Alternatively, one can assume that searchers are acquainted with the distribution of values from which a partnership’s values are drawn, \(f_v(v)\), and the conditional distribution of signals given the values, \(f_s(s|v)\). These are interchangeable by Bayes’ rule.

  4. Meaning that the searcher keeps on reviewing new opportunities as long as the highest-valued opportunity encountered so far is below the reservation value.

  5. In general, in two-sided search, the value function \(V\) will also be dependent on the strategies being used by others. Where it is clear from context we suppress such dependence.

  6. We note that there are situations where some subset of the \(k\) might form a team, but we study the case where exactly k agents are needed (e.g., in the case where each agent has a certain capability necessary for a task).

  7. It can be assumed that results in this section use this distribution unless otherwise noted.

  8. \(\gamma _e\) denotes the commission, as a fraction of the value of the transaction to the agent, that the agent needs to pay the expert.

References

  1. Albrecht, J., Anderson, A., & Vroman, S. (2010). Search by committee. Journal of Economic Theory, 145(4), 1386–1407.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  2. Anshelevich, E., Das, S., & Naamad, Y. (2013). Anarchy, stability, and utopia: creating better matchings. Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, 26(1), 120–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Armstrong, M. (2006). Competition in two-sided markets. RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 668–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bakos, Y. (1997). Reducing buyer search costs: Implications for electronic marketplaces. Management Science, 43(12), 1676–1692.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Bloch, F., & Ryder, H. (2000). Two-sided search, marriages, and matchmakers. International Economic Review, 41(1), 93–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Burdett, K., & Wright, R. (1998). Two-sided search with nontransferable utility. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1, 220–245.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Chade, H., & Ventura, G. (2005). On income taxation and marital decisions. Review of Economic Dynamics, 8(3), 565–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Chhabra, M., Das, S., & Sarne, D. (2014). Competitive information provision in sequential search markets. In Proceedings of the international joint conference on autonomous agents and multi-agent systems, To appear.

  9. Chhabra, M., Das, S., & Sarne, D. (2014). Expert-mediated sequential search. European Journal of Operational Research, 234(3), 861–873.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  10. Das, S., & Kamenica, E. (2005). Two-sided bandits and the dating market. In Proceedings of IJCAI (pp. 947–952).

  11. Diamond, P. (1982). Aggregate demand management in search equilibrium. The Journal of Political Economy, 90(5), 881–894.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Duffie, D., Malamud, S., & Manso, G. (2009). Information percolation with equilibrium search dynamics. Econometrica, 77(5), 1513–1574. 09.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  13. Endriss, U., Kraus, S., Lang, J., & Wooldridge, M. (2011). Designing incentives for boolean games. In Proceedings of AAMAS (pp. 79–86).

  14. Fotakis, D., Karakostas, G., & Kolliopoulos, S. (2010). On the existence of optimal taxes for network congestion games with heterogeneous users. In Proceedings of SAGT’10 (pp. 162–173).

  15. Gale, D., & Shapley, L. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage. American Mathematical Monthly, 69, 9–15.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  16. Gorman, M., Salisbury, D., & Brannon, I. (2009). Who wins when price information is more ubiquitous? An experiment to assess how infomediaries influence price. Electronic Markets, 19(2–3), 151–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Grosfeld-Nir, A., Sarne, D., & Spieglier, I. (2009). Modeling the search for the least costly opportunity. European Journal of Operational Research, 197(2), 667–674.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Janssen, M., & Moraga-Gonzalez, J. (2004). Strategic pricing, consumer search and the number of firms. Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1089–1118.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Jovanovic, B. (1979). Job matching and the theory of turnover. The Journal of Political Economy, 87(5), 972.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  20. Kephart, J., & Greenwald, A. (2002). Shopbot economics. Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, 5(3), 255–287.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  21. Kephart, J., Hanson, J., & Greenwald, A. (2000). Dynamic pricing by software agents. Computer Networks, 32, 731–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Ketchpel, S. (1994). Forming coalitions in the face of uncertain rewards. In Proceedings of AAAI (pp. 414–419).

  23. Kraus, S., Shehory, O., & Taase, G. (2003). Coalition formation with uncertain heterogeneous information. In Proceedings of AAMAS (pp. 1–8).

  24. Lee, R., & Schwarz, M. (2009). Interviewing in two-sided matching markets. NBER Working Paper.

  25. Lippman, S., & McCall, J. (1976). The economics of job search: A survey. Economic Inquiry, 14(2), 155–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Masters, A. (1999). Wage posting in two-sided search and the minimum wage. International Economic Review, 40(4), 809–826.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. McCall, J. (1970). Economics of information and job search. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(1), 113–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. McMillan, J., & Rothschild, M. (1994). Search. In R. Aumann & S. Hart (Eds.), Handbook of game theory with economic applications (pp. 905–927). North-Holland: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  29. Milgrom, P. (1981). Good news and bad news: Representation theorems and applications. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 380–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Mortensen, D., & Pissarides, C. (1999). New developments in models of search in the labor market. Handbook of labor economics, 3, 2567–2627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Nermuth, M., Pasini, G., Pin, P., & Weidenholzer, S. (2009). Price dispersion, search externalities, and the digital divide. Vienna Economics Papers 0916, University of Vienna, Department of Economics.

  32. Panos, M., & Ungar, L. (2002). Shopbots and pricebots in electronic service markets. In S. Parsons, P. Gmytrasiewicz, M. Wooldridge, & G. Weiss (Eds.), Game theory and decision theory in agent-based systems, volume 5 of multiagent systems, artificial societies, and simulated organizations (pp. 177–195). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Penn, M., Polukarov, M., & Tennenholtz, M. (2009). Random order congestion games. Mathematics of Operations Research, 34(3), 706–725.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  34. Penn, M., Polukarov, M., & Tennenholtz, M. (2009). Taxed congestion games with failures. Annals of Mathematics and Artificial Intelligence, 56(2), 133–151.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  35. Rothschild, M. (1974). Searching for the lowest price when the distribution of prices is unknown. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 689–711.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Rysman, M. (2009). The economics of two-sided markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(3), 125–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Sahib, P., & Gu, X. (2002). To tie the knot or not: Cohabitation, marriage and individuals’ attitudes to risk. Demographic Research, 6(13), 355–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Sarne, D., & Kraus, S. (2008). Managing parallel inquiries in agents’ two-sided search. Artificial Intelligence, 172(4–5), 541–569.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  39. Sarne, D., Manisterski, E., & Kraus, S. (2010). Multi-goal economic search using dynamic search structures. Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems, 21, 204–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Shehory, O., & Kraus, S. (1998). Methods for task allocation via agent coalition formation. Artificial Intelligence, 101(1), 165–200.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  41. Shimer, R., & Smith, L. (2001). Matching, search, and heterogeneity. The BE Journal of Macroeconomics, 1(1), 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Smith, L. (2011). Frictional matching models. Annual Reviews in Economics, 3, 319–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Waldeck, R. (2008). Search and price competition. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(2), 347–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Wan, Y., & Peng, G. (2010). What’s next for shopbots? IEEE Computer, 43, 20–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Wiegmann, D., Weinersmith, K., & Seubert, S. (2010). Multi-attribute mate choice decisions and uncertainty in the decision process: A generalized sequential search strategy. Journal of Mathematical Biology, 60(4), 543–572.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  46. Wright, R. (1986). Job search and cyclical unemployment. The Journal of Political Economy, 94(1), 38–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This work is supported in part by a US-Israel BSF Grant (#2008-404) to Das and Sarne. Sarne acknowledges additional support from ISF Grant 1083/13. Das acknowledges additional support from an NSF CAREER Award (IIS-1414452). A preliminary version of this work appears in the Proceedings of the ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce (EC 2012).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David Sarne.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proofs

1.1 Proof of Theorem 1

The proof is based on showing that, if according to the optimal search strategy the searcher should resume her search given a signal \(s\), then she must necessarily also do so given any other signal \(s'<s\). Let \(V\) denote the expected benefit to the searcher if resuming the search if signal \(s\) is obtained. Since the optimal strategy given signal \(s\) is to resume search, we know \(V>E[v|s]\). Given the HSGN assumption, \(E[v|s] \ge E[v | s']\) holds for \(s'<s\). Therefore, \(V>E[v|s']\), proving that the optimal strategy is reservation-value. Then, the expected value of the searcher when using reservation signal \(t\) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} V(t)&= -c_s + V(t) \Big (1-B\int \limits _{s=t}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds\Big )\nonumber \\&+\, B\int \limits _{s=t}^{\infty }E[v|s]f_s(s) \,ds =\frac{-c_s + B\int _{s=t}^{\infty } E[v|s]f_s(s) \,ds}{B\big (1-F_s(t)\big )} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

where B is the probability of being accepted by the other searcher, and \(F_s(s)\) is the cumulative distribution function of the signal \(s\). Setting the first derivative according to \(t\) of Eq. 35 to zero we obtain: \(V(t^*) = E[v|t^*]\) as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d V(t)}{dt}&= \frac{d V(t)}{dt} \Big (1-B\int \limits _{s=t}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds\Big ) \\&+\, V(t) Bf_s(t)- B \cdot E[v|t] f_s(t) \\ V(t^*)&= E[v|t^*] \quad \quad f_s(t^*) \ne 0 \quad B \ne 0 \end{aligned}$$

To verify that \(t^*\) is global maximum, we calculate the second derivative.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2V}{dt^2}&= \Big (1-B\int \limits _{s=t}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds\Big ) \frac{d^2V}{dt^2} + B \cdot f_s(t) \frac{dV}{dt} \\&+\, B\frac{d(V(t)f_s(t))}{dt} - B\frac{d(E[v|t] f_s(t))}{dt} \\ \\ \frac{d^2V}{dt^2}|t^*&= \frac{1}{B\big (1 - F_s(t^*)\big )} B\left( \frac{ d\big ((V(t) - E[v|t])f_s(t) \big ) }{dt}|t^* \right) \\&= -\frac{f_s(t^*)}{1-F_s(t^*)} \left( \frac{dE[v|t]}{dt}|t^* \right) \end{aligned}$$

Given the HSGN assumption, \(E[v|t]\) is an increasing function in \(t\). Therefore \(\frac{dE[v|t]}{dt} > 0\), this implies that the value of second derivative evaluated at \(t^*\) is less than zero, which confirms that \(t^*\) is indeed a global maximum.

Finally substituting \(V(t^*)=E[V|t^*]\) in Eq. 35 we obtain Eq. 4 as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} V(t^*)&= -c_s + V(t^*) \left( 1-B\int \limits _{s=t^*}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds \right) + B\int \limits _{s=t^*}^{\infty } E[v|s] f_s(s)\,ds \\ E[v|t^*]&= -c_s + E[v|t^*] \left( 1-B\int \limits _{s=t^*}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds \right) + B\int \limits _{s=t^*}^{\infty } E[v|s] f_s(s)\,ds \\ c_s&= B\int \limits _{s=t^*}^{\infty } \Big (E[v|s]-E[v|t^*]\Big )f_s(s) \,ds \end{aligned}$$

Since all the searchers end up using the same threshold, we get that:

$$\begin{aligned} B=\int \limits _{s=t^*}^\infty f_s(s) \,ds \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, the value \(t^*\) can be calculated using the above equation.\(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Theorem 2

The proof extends the methodology used for proving Theorem 1. We first show that if, according to the optimal search strategy the searcher should resume her search given a signal \(s\), then she must also do so given any other signal \(s' < s\). Then, we show that if, according to the optimal search strategy the searcher should terminate her search given a signal \(s\), then she must also necessarily do so given any other signal \(s'' > s\). Again, we use \(V\) to denote the expected benefit to the searcher if resuming search.

If the optimal strategy given signal \(s\) is to resume search then the following two inequalities should hold, describing the superiority of resuming search over terminating search (Eq. 36) and querying the expert (Eq. 37):

$$\begin{aligned} V&> E[v|s] \end{aligned}$$
(36)
$$\begin{aligned} V&> VF_v(V|s) + \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } y f_v(y|s) \,dy - c_e \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Given the HSGN assumption and since \(s' < s\), Eq. 36 holds also for \(s'\). Similarly, notice that:

$$\begin{aligned} V&> VF_v(V|s) + \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } y f_v(y|s) \,dy - c_e \\&= V+\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } (1- F_v(y|s)) \,dy - c_e\\&> V+\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } (1- F_v(y|s')) \,dy - c_e\\&= VF_v(V|s') + \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } y f_v(y|s') \,dy - c_e \end{aligned}$$

and therefore Eq. 37 also holds for \(s' < s\).

The proof for \(s''>s\) is exactly equivalent: the expected cost of accepting the current opportunity can be shown to dominate both resuming the search and querying the expert. The optimal strategy can thus be described by the tuple (\(t_l,t_u,V\)) as stated above. Equations 6, 9, 11 are obtained after replacing the intervals \(S,S'\) with the thresholds \(t_l,t_u\):

$$\begin{aligned} V&= -c_s -c_e\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{s=t_u} f_s(s) \,ds+(1-AB)V+BC \\ V&= \frac{-c_s-c_e\big (F_s(t_u)-F_s(t_l)\big )+BC}{AB}\\ A&= \int \limits _{s=t_u}^{\infty } f_s(s)\,ds+\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}f_s(s)\Big (1-F_v(V|s)\Big ) \,ds \\ A&= 1-F_s(t_l)-\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}f_s(s)F_v(V|s)ds\\ C&= \int \limits _{s=t_u}^{\infty }f_s(s)E[v|s]\,ds+\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}\biggl (f_s(s) \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty } y f_v(y|s) \,dy\biggl ) \,ds \end{aligned}$$

Equation 10 represents the fact that the system is symmetric in the way that ultimately all agents choose the same tuple \((t_l,t_u,V)\), and so the probability of being accepted is equal to the probability of accepting the match. Now we will show the correctness of Eqs. 7 and 8:

Taking the derivative of Eq. 6 w.r.t. \(t_l\) and equating to zero, we obtain a \(t_l\) which maximizes the expected benefit.

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial V}{ \partial t_l}&= \frac{(c_ef_s(t_l)+B\frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l})AB+(-c_s-c_e\big (F_s(t_u)-F_s(t_l)\big )+BC)\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}B}{A^2B^2}\\&= \frac{\Big (c_ef_s(t_l)+B\frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}\Big )AB-VAB\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}B}{A^2B^2}\\&= \frac{c_ef_s(t_l)+B\frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}-V\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}B}{AB}\\&= \frac{c_ef_s(t_l)+B\Big (\frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}-V\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}\Big )}{AB} \end{aligned}$$

Calculating \(\frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}-V\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}\) separately, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}&= -f_s(t_l)\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t_l) \,dy+\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}f_s(s)\big (-Vf_v(V|s)\big )\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l}\,ds\\ \frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}&= -f_s(t_l)+f_s(t_l)F_v(V|t_l)-\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}f_s(s)f_v(V|s)\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l} \,ds \\&= -f_s(t_l)\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }f_v(y|t_l) \,dy-\int \limits _{s=t_l}^{t_u}f_s(s)f_v(V|s)\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l} \,ds\\ \end{aligned}$$

and so

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial C}{ \partial t_l}&-V\dfrac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}=-f_s(t_l) \displaystyle \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy \end{aligned}$$

and so

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial V}{ \partial t_l}&= \frac{c_ef_s(t_l)+B\big (-f_s(t_l) \int _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\big )}{AB}\\&= \frac{f_s(t_l)\big (c_e-B\int _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\big )}{AB} \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l}=0\) we get Eq. 7.

To confirm that this is a maximum, we compute the second derivative:

$$\begin{aligned} AB\frac{ \partial ^2 V}{\partial {t_l}^2} +\frac{ \partial A}{ \partial t_l}B\frac{ \partial V}{ \partial t_l}=&\frac{ \partial \big ( f_s(t_l)\big )}{ \partial t_l}\big (c_e-B\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\big )\\&-\, f_s(t_l)B\frac{ \partial \bigg (\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\bigg )}{ \partial t_l}\\ \end{aligned}$$

By substituting \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l}=0\) and \(c_e = B\int \limits _{V}^{\infty } (y-V) f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\) we get:

$$\begin{aligned}&AB\frac{ \partial ^2 V}{\partial {t_l}^2}=-f_s(t_l)B\frac{ \partial \bigg (\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\bigg )}{ \partial t_l} \end{aligned}$$

Or alternatively:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{ \partial ^2 V}{\partial {t_l}^2}=\frac{-f_s(t_l)\frac{ \partial \bigg (\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\bigg )}{ \partial t_l}}{A} \end{aligned}$$

All that is left to show is that \(\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\) increases with \(t_l\) to complete the proof of maximum.

$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy&= \lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }\int \limits _{y=V}^{b}(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\\&= \lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }[(y-V)F_v(y|t_l)]_{y=v}^{b}+\lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }\int \limits _{y=V}^{b}F_v(y|t_l) \,dy \\&= \lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }(b-V)F_v(b|t_l)+\lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }\int \limits _{y=V}^{b}F_v(y|t_l) \,dy \\&= \lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }(b-V)+\lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }\int \limits _{y=V}^{b}F_v(y|t_l) \,dy\\&= \lim _{b\rightarrow \infty }\int \limits _{y=V}^{b}(1-F_v(y|t_l)) \,dy=\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }\big (1-F_v(y|t_l)\big ) \,dy \end{aligned}$$

and so

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{ \partial \bigg (\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }(y-V)f_v(y|t_l) \,dy\bigg )}{ \partial t_l}=\frac{ \partial \bigg (\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }\big (1-F_v(y|t_l)\big ) \,dy\bigg )}{ \partial t_l} \\&\quad =-\Big (\big (1-F_v(V|t_l)\big )\Big )\frac{ \partial V}{ \partial t_l}+\int \limits _{y=V}^{\infty }\frac{ \partial \big (-F_v(y|t_l)\big )}{ \partial t_l} \,dy >0 \end{aligned}$$

The inequality is given by substituting \(\frac{\partial V}{\partial t_l}=0\) and due to HSGN assumption, which determines that \(\forall y : \frac{ \partial \big (F_v(y|t_l)\big )}{ \partial t_l}<0\). The proof for Eq. 8 is exactly similar to the proof for Eq. 7. We have 6 Eqs. (611) in 6 variables. We can solve these simultaneously to calculate the value of \(V\), \(t_l\) and \(t_u\). \(\square \)

1.3 Proof of Theorem 3

The proof steps resemble those used for Theorem 2. We first show that if, according to the optimal search strategy the searcher should terminate her search (and accept the partnership) given a signal \(s\), then she must also necessarily do so given any other signal \(s' > s\). The partnership is accepted based on signal \(s\) iff the following two conditions hold:

  1. 1.

    \(E[v|s]>V\)

  2. 2.

    \(E[v|s]>VF_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s)+\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|s)dy\)

Or equivalently:

  1. 1.

    \(E[v|s]>V\)

  2. 2.

    \(\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(y-V)f_v(y|s)dy + \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_eyf_v(y|s)dy>0\)

For every \(s' > s\), we get that \(E[v|s'] \ge E[v|s]>V\).

We show that for any \(s' > s\):

$$\begin{aligned}&\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(y-V)f_v(y|s')dy + \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_eyf_v(y|s')dy\\&\qquad \ge \int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(y-V)f_v(y|s)dy + \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_eyf_v(y|s)dy >0 \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging the above equation we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(y-V)[f_v(y|s')-f_v(y|s)]dy + \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_ey[f_v(y|s')-f_v(y|s)]dy \\&\quad =\big [(y-V)[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)] \big ]_{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}- \int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy\\&\qquad +\, \big [{\gamma }_ey[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)] \big ]_{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^\infty - \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_e[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy\\&\quad =[(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)-V)(F_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s')\\&\qquad -\, F_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s))-0]-\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy\\&\qquad +\, [0-{\gamma }_eV/(1-{\gamma }_e)[F_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s')\\&\qquad \, -F_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s)]-\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_e[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy\\&\quad =-\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy -\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }{\gamma }_e[F_v(y|s')-F_v(y|s)]dy \\&\quad \ge 0+0=0 \end{aligned}$$

where the last inequality is obtained since \(F_v(y|s')<F_v(y|s)\) according to the HSGN assumption. Therefore, there is a single threshold for acceptance without querying the expert. Once this is established, Eqs. 28, 30, 32 are obtained by replacing the set of intervals \(S\) with the threshold \(t\). Equation 31 represents the fact that the system is symmetric in the way that ultimately all agents choose the same tuple \((t,V)\), and so the probability of being accepted is equal to the probability of accepting the match. Finally, the correctness of Eq. 29 is proved by taking the derivative of Eq. 28 w.r.t. \(t\), equating to zero, obtaining \(t\) which maximize the expected benefit:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dV}{dt}&= \frac{B\frac{dC}{dt}AB-\Big (-c_s+BC\Big )\frac{dA}{dt}B}{(AB)^2}\\&= \frac{B\frac{dC}{dt}AB-\big (VAB\big )\frac{dA}{dt}B}{(AB)^2}\\&= \frac{\frac{dC}{dt}-V\frac{dA}{dt}}{A} \end{aligned}$$

however,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dA}{dt}&= -f_s(t)F_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|t)-\int \limits _{s=t}^{\infty }f_s(s)f_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s)ds\frac{dV}{dt}\\ \\ \frac{dC}{dt}&= -f_s(t)E(v|t)+f_s(t)\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy\\&+\int \limits _{s=t}^{\infty } f_s(s)(-1)(1-{\gamma }_e)\frac{V}{(1-{\gamma }_e)}f_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s)ds\frac{dV}{dt}\\&= -f_s(t)E(v|t)+f_s(t)\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy\\&-\int \limits _{s=t}^{\infty }f_s(s)Vf_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|s)ds\frac{dV}{dt} \end{aligned}$$

and so:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dV}{dt}&= \frac{\frac{dC}{dt}\!-\!V\frac{dA}{dt}}{A}\\&= \frac{\!-f_s(t)E(v|t)+f_s(t)\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1\!-\!{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy+f_s(t)VF_v(V/(1\!-\!{\gamma }_e)|t)}{A}\\&= \frac{f_s(t)\bigg (-E(v|t)+\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy+VF_v(V/(1-{\gamma }_e)|t)\bigg )}{A}\\&= \frac{f_s(t)\bigg (-\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy+\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy+V\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}f_v(y|t)dy\bigg )}{A}\\&= \frac{f_s(t)\bigg (-\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)} yf_v(y|t)dy- \int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy+\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }(1-{\gamma }_e)yf_v(y|t)dy+V\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}f_v(y|t)dy\bigg )}{A}\\&= \frac{f_s(t)\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )}{A} \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(\frac{dV}{dt}=0\) and assuming that \(f_s(t) \ne 0\), we obtain Eq. 29

To verify maximum we compute the second derivative

$$\begin{aligned} A\frac{dV}{dt}&=f_s(t)\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )\\ A\frac{d^2V}{dt^2}+\frac{dA}{dt}\frac{dV}{dt}&=\frac{df_s(t)}{dt}\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )\\&+\,f_s(t)\frac{d\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )}{dt}\\ \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(\frac{dV}{dt}=0\), hence \(\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy={\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2V}{dt^2}&=\frac{f_s(t)\frac{d\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^ {V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/ (1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )}{dt}}{A}\\ \end{aligned}$$

But since \(A,f_s(t)>0\), it is enough to show that \(\bigg (\int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\bigg )\) decreases as \(t\) increases. As part of the proof that the optimal strategy is based on reservation value, it was shown that:

$$\begin{aligned} \int \limits _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(y-V)f_v(y|t)dy+ {\gamma }_e\int \limits _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy \end{aligned}$$

increases as \(t\) increases.

Hence \(\int _{y=-\infty }^{V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}(V-y)f_v(y|t)dy-{\gamma }_e\int _{y=V/(1-{\gamma }_e)}^{\infty }yf_v(y|t)dy\) decreases as \(t\) increases.\(\square \)

Appendix 2: Nomenclature

Notation

Meaning

\(s\)

The drawn signal

\(v\)

The real value of the match

\(f_v(y)\), \(F_v(y)\)

The probability density function and cumulative distribution function from which the real values of the match are drawn

\(f_s(s)\), \(F_s(s)\)

The probability density function and cumulative distribution function from which the signals are drawn

\(f_s(s|v)\), \(F_s(s|v)\)

The probability density function and cumulative distribution function from which the signals are drawn, given that the true value of the match is \(v\)

\(f_v(y|s)\), \(F_v(y|s)\)

The probability density function and cumulative distribution function from which the real values of the matches are drawn, given that the drawn signal is \(s\)

\(E{[}v|s{]}\)

The expected value of the match, given that the drawn signal is \(s\)

\(c_s\)

The search cost. i.e., the cost of drawing another signal

\(c_e\)

The cost of querying the expert

\(\gamma _e\)

The commission (in percentages) paid to the expert

\(V\)

The expected utility of an agent, using the optimal strategy. By Bellman optimality principle, this value is also the threshold for the real value revealed by the expert

\(t_l\)

The lower threshold. Drawing a signal which is less than \(t_l\), the agent rejects the match without querying the expert

\(t_u\)

The upper threshold. Drawing a signal which is greater than \(t_u\), the agent accepts the match without querying the expert

\(V(S,S^*)\)

The expected utility of an agent in a noisy two-sided search with no expert present, where the agent accepts the match if and only if the signal she sees is in \(S\), and the other agents accept the match if and only if the signal they see is in \(S^*\)

\(V(S',S'')\)

The expected utility of an agent in a noisy two sided search with an expert present, where the agent accepts the match if the signal she sees, denoted \(s\), is in \(S'\), rejects it if \(s\in S''\), queries the expert if \(s\notin S'\cup S''\), and whenever the expert is queried, the agent accepts if and only if the revealed value is greater or equal to \(V(S,S'')\). This is defined for \(S'\cap S''=\emptyset \)

\(d_e\)

The cost to the expert of producing the exact value of a match

\(\eta _{c_e}\)

The expected number of expert queries a searcher performs, whenever the expert charges a fixed price \(c_e\)

\(\eta _{\gamma _e}\)

The expected number of expert queries a searcher performs, whenever the expert charges a fixed commission percentage \(\gamma _e\)

\(\pi _e\)

The expected utility of the expert

\(W\)

The expected social welfare, defined as \(\pi _e+V\)

\(k\)

The size of the match formed (\(k=1\) implies a one-sided search, \(k=2\) implies a two-sided-search etc.)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Nahum, Y., Sarne, D., Das, S. et al. Two-sided search with experts. Auton Agent Multi-Agent Syst 29, 364–401 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10458-014-9260-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10458-014-9260-6

Keywords

Navigation