Skip to main content
Log in

Bargaining powers of buyers and sellers on the online diamond market: a double perspective non-parametric analysis

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the relative efficiency of buyers and sellers on the online diamond market using a non-parametric double-frontier setting. Our data consists in a sample of more than 100,000 round cut diamonds offered for sale online. For a given quality defined by a combination of color and clarity grades, we turn to the free disposal hull model to estimate the sets of efficient diamonds respectively for buyers and sellers in the price-weight space. We find that the average bargaining power of buyers is lower than that of sellers. Regression estimates show that the relative efficiency of buyers is reduced for heavier diamonds and when there are many diamonds of the same quality offered for sale.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For recent evidence of geographic price dispersion in retail markets, see for instance Lee (2010).

  2. To explain the online price dispersion, Baylis and Perloff (2002) and Pan et al. (2004) suggest that there exist differences in e-tailer service quality, which may be part of product differentiation strategy.

  3. As emphasized in Lins et al. (2005, p. 95), the DP-DEA method “can possibly be applied to any situation—typically those encountered in auctions—in which there is a game situation where one player aims at maximizing an output which is the input that the other player would like to minimize”. Hadley and Ruggiero (2006) provide an application to final-offer arbitration in major league baseball.

  4. In the price-quality space, Wolff (2014) identifies the set of efficient decision making units using data on French ski resorts. Efficient resorts are located on the outer envelope where price is the lowest for any given quality.

  5. All diamonds have a certificate which is obtained following a professional examination in order to authenticate the diamond’s attributes. While certificates provide unbiased information on each diamond, the issue of biased information on the general state of the diamond market remains an open question.

  6. See the following url: http://www.info-diamond.com/diamonds/loose-diamonds.html. For more detailed information on the various characteristics of diamonds, see http://www.lumeradiamonds.com/diamond-education/glossary. Note that there is no specific information of the end-use of the diamonds. Everyone connecting to the website may buy one or several diamonds offered for sale, meaning that sales are not restricted to jewelry or industrial use.

  7. Several websites presents an average per carat price for different color and clarity combinations for a given shape. See for instance http://www.ajediam.com/diamond_price_calculator.html or http://www.pricescope.com/diamond-prices/round.

  8. Scott and Yelowitz (2010) and Vaillant and Wolff (2013) investigate the impact of diamonds’ characteristics on their prices using both OLS and quantile hedonic regressions.

  9. In our data set, there are less than 100 diamonds offered for sale per color in the P–Z range of colors (whatever clarity). Also, there are 40 color-clarity combinations with zero diamond offered for sale.

  10. For instance, a D-VVS1 diamond is of better quality compared to a E-VVS2 diamond (better color, better clarity), but we cannot rank a D-VVS2 diamond and a E-VVS1 diamond. Banker and Morey (1986) have investigated the use of categorical variables in DEA.

  11. Using a sample of digital cameras sold in Germany, Chumpitaz et al. (2010) find that test statistics lead to a rejection of the convexity assumption in their price hedonic frontier setting.

  12. As emphasized in Farrell (1959, pp. 378–379), “a glance at the world about us should be enough to convince commodities are to some extent indivisible and that many have large indivisibilities”.

  13. All calculations for this study were made using the Stata software. We use the orderalpha command proposed by Tauchmann (2012) to estimate the two sets of efficient units. Detailed codes are available upon request.

  14. Another interpretation is that these diamonds are poor sales that should be disregarded. For that purpose, we further investigate the characteristics of the efficient diamonds located on the lower frontier. For these 37 diamonds, 70.3 % have either excellent or very good cut grade, 78.4 % have either excellent or very good polish, 70.3 % have either excellent or very good symmetry, and 70.3 % have either no or light fluorescence. While these proportions tend to be slightly lower than those found for the 2729 inefficient diamonds (82.8 % for excellent/very good cut shape, 91.9 % for excellent/very good polish, 88.6 % for excellent/very good symmetry, 74.6 % for no/light fluorescence), this comparison shows that most diamonds offering the lowest price for a given weight are not necessarily bad features.

  15. When interpreting the vertical distance between the inferior and superior frontiers, one should consider both the imperfection of the market (in terms of incomplete information for instance) and the likely heterogeneity of the exogenous variables characterizing each observed transaction.

  16. On the one hand, the average bargaining power of buyers is below 35 % for diamonds with slight inclusions (clarity grade of SI3) and slightly tinted white (color grades of I and G). On the other hand, the bargaining power exceeds 0.6 for high-quality diamonds of the type exceptional white \(+\) (color grade of D) and no inclusion (clarity grade of IF) or very small inclusions invisible to the naked eye (clarity grade of VVS2).

  17. As a consequence, buyers will pay on average too much for their purchases and do not behave in an efficient way.

  18. However, the relative efficiency of buyers is also higher for diamonds characterized by color grades of L and M (tinted white or tinted color) and with very very small or very small inclusions (clarity grades of VVS1, VVS2, VS1, VS2). The range of diamonds available for sale in these categories is more restricted.

  19. We thank an anonymous reviewer for this insight. For the sake of robustness, we have also estimated a beta distribution with the mean and scale parameter as functions of carat weight and number of diamonds and reach similar conclusions.

  20. We obtain a very similar negative coefficient (equal to \(-\)0.163 and highly significant) when taking into account the log of price instead of the log of carat weight, which was expected given the very high correlation between price and weight.

References

  • Angulo-Meza, L., & Estellita Lins, M. P. (2002). Review of methods for increasing discrimination in data envelopment analysis. Annals of Operations Research, 116, 225–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, O. (2011). Do consumers make too much effort to save on cheap items and too little to save on expensive items? Experimental results and implications for business strategy. American Behavioral Scientist, 55, 1077–1098.

  • Banker, R. D., & Morey, R. C. (1986). The use of categorical variables in data envelopment analysis. Management Science, 32, 1613–1627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M., Morgan, J., & Scholten, P. (2004). Price dispersion in the small and in the large: Evidence from an Internet price comparison site. Journal of Industrial Economics, 52, 463–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baylis, K., & Perloff, J. M. (2002). Price dispersion on the Internet: Good firms and bad firms. Review of Industrial Organization, 21, 305–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben Lakhdar, C., Leleu, H., Vaillant, N., & Wolff, F. C. (2013). Measuring efficiency of purchasing and selling agents in markets when quality matters: The case of illicit drug transactions. European Journal of Operational Research, 226, 646–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., & Smith, M. (2000). Frictionless commerce? A comparison of internal and conventional retailers. Management Science, 46, 563–585.

  • Buis, M. L. (2010). Analyzing proportions. In mimeo, German Stata Users’ Group Meetings.

  • Charnes, A., Cooper, W. W., & Rhodes, E. (1978). Measuring the efficiency of decision-making units. European Journal of Operational Research, 2, 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chumpitaz, R., Kerstens, K., Paparoidamis, N., & Staat, M. (2010). Hedonic price function estimation in economics and marketing: Revisiting Lancaster’s issue of noncombinable goods. Annals of Operations Research, 173, 145–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clay, K., Krishnan, R., & Wolff, E. (2001). Price and price dispersion on the web: Evidence from the online book industry. Journal of Industrial Economics, 49, 521–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, W. W., Seiford, L. M., & Zhu, J. (2004). Data envelopment analysis: History, models and interpretations. In W. W. Cooper, L. M. Seiford, & J. Zhu (Eds.), Handbook on Data Envelopment Analysis (pp. 1–39). Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Deprins, D., Simar, L., & Tulkens, H. (1984). Measuring labor inefficiency in post offices. In M. Marchand, P. Pestieau, & H. Tulkens (Eds.), The performance of public enterprises: Concepts and measurements (pp. 243–267). Amsterdam: North Holland.

  • Ellison, G., & Ellison, S. (2005). Lessons about markets from the internet. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 139–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, M. J. (1959). Convexity assumption in theory of competitive markets. Journal of Political Economy, 67, 377–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Castro, A. S., & Smith, P. C. (2002). Lancaster’s characteristics approach revisited: Product selection using non-parametric methods. Managerial and Decision Economics, 23, 83–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrari, S., & Cribari-Neto, F. (2004). Beta regression for modelling rates and proportions. Journal of Applied Statistics, 31, 799–815.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadley, L., & Ruggiero, J. (2006). Final-offer arbitration in major league baseball: A nonparametric analysis. Annals of Operations Research, 145, 201–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger, D. A., & Storchmann, K. (2011). Wine retail price dispersion in the United States: Searching for expensive wines? American Economic Review, 101, 136–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keane, M. P. (2010). Structural vs. atheoretic approaches to econometrics. Journal of Econometrics, 156, 3–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, I. (2010). Geographic price dispersion in retail markets: Evidence from micro-data. Journal of Macroeconomics, 32, 1169–1177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J. D., Hwan, S. W., & Kim, T. Y. (2005). The measurement of consumption efficiency considering the discrete choice of consumers. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 23, 65–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lins, M. P., Novaes, L. F., & Legey, L. F. (2005). Real estate appraisal: A double perspective data envelopment analysis approach. Annals of Operations Research, 138, 79–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mouchart, M., Russo, F., & Wunsch, G. (2010). Inferring causal relations by modeling structures. Statistica, 70, 411–432.

  • Mouchart, M., & Vandresse, M. (2007). Barganing powers and market segmentation in freight transport. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 22, 1295–1313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mouchart, M., & Vandresse, M. (2010). A double-frontier approach for measuring market imperfection. Annals of Operations Research, 173, 137–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novaes, L. F., & Paiva, S. A. (2010). Double perspective data envelopment analysis: One approach to estimate the “LOOP” arbitrage. iBusiness, 2, 354–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pan, X., Ratchford, B. T., & Shankar, V. (2004). Price dispersion on the internet: A review and directions for future research. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 18, 116–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck, R. S., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (2011). Microeconomics (8th ed.). Upper Saddle River: Pearson Prentice Hall.

  • Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, F., & Yelowitz, A. (2010). Pricing anomalies in the market for diamonds: Evidence of conformist behavior. Economic Inquiry, 48, 353–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shephard, R. W. (1970). Theory of cost and production functions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simar, L., & Wilson, P. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. Journal of Econometrics, 136, 31–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tauchmann, H. (2012). Partial frontier efficiency analysis. Stata Journal, 12, 461–478.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaillant, N. G., & Wolff, F. C. (2013). Understanding diamond pricing using unconditional quantile regressions. Asian Economic and Financial Review, 3, 1540–1561.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolff, F. C. (2014). Lift ticket prices and quality in French ski resorts: Insights from a non-parametric analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 237, 1155–1164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolff, F. C. (2015). Does price dispersion increase with quality? Evidence from the online diamond market. Applied Economics, 47, 5996–6009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing, X. (2008). Does price converge on the internet? Evidence from the online DVD market. Applied Economics Letters, 15, 11–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to François-Charles Wolff.

Additional information

We are indebted to two anonymous reviewers for many insightful comments and valuable suggestions on previous drafts.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wolff, FC. Bargaining powers of buyers and sellers on the online diamond market: a double perspective non-parametric analysis. Ann Oper Res 244, 697–718 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2160-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2160-1

Keywords

Navigation