Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal recovery strategy of manufacturers: Remanufacturing products or recycling materials?

  • S.I.: SOME
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Manufacturers are increasingly taking positive actions to handle used products by adopting “recycling materials” (RM), “remanufacturing product” (RP) or the hybrid strategy combining with both RM and RP (RMP). Under each strategy, in addition to the optimal quantity and price of new product, manufacturers may also face important decisions on the optimal quantity and price of remanufactured product and (or) recycling materials. To address such challenging issues, we consider a manufacturer who sells a new product to consumers, and examine the optimal recovery strategy and associated decisions by developing three models, i.e., models without incorporating recovery strategy, with considering recovery strategy and both recovery strategy and government subsidy. We further explore the impacts of product quality and government subsidy on the optimal decisions. Our results show that, neither recovery strategy including not implementing recovery strategy is always superior to the others, which depends on cost savings from remanufacturing products and benefits of recycling materials. Interestingly, the manufacturer with a higher product quality prefers to choose RP but RM otherwise. Government subsidy increases the manufacturer’s profit under each recovery strategy. In general, government subsidy helps to increase consumer surplus but reduce environment impact. However, as government subsidy increases, the manufacturer may prefer to implement RMP rather than RP, which may result in less consumer surplus and more environmental impact. Therefore, a higher subsidy unexpectedly may lead to a lower social welfare. This suggests that, the government should design an appropriate and more practical subsidy policy to dispose used products.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abbey, J. D., Kleber, R., Souza, G. C., & Voigt, G. (2017). The role of perceived quality risk in pricing remanufactured products. Production and Operations Management,26(1), 100–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, V. V., Atasu, A., & Van Ittersum, K. (2015). Remanufacturing, third-party competition, and consumers’ perceived value of new products. Management Science,61(1), 60–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, V. V., Ferguson, M., & Souza, G. C. (2016). Trade-in rebates for price discrimination and product recovery. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management,63(3), 326–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agrawal, V. V., Ferguson, M., Toktay, L. B., & Thomas, V. M. (2012). Is leasing greener than selling? Management Science,58(3), 523–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akan, M., Ata, B., & Savaşkan-Ebert, R. C. (2013). Dynamic pricing of remanufacturable products under demand substitution: A product life cycle model. Annals of Operations Research,211(1), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aksen, D., Aras, N., & Karaarslan, A. G. (2009). Design and analysis of government subsidized collection systems for incentive-dependent returns. International Journal of Production Economics,119(2), 308–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atasu, A., Sarvary, M., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. (2008). Remanufacturing as a marketing strategy. Management Science,54(10), 1731–1746.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atasu, A., & Souza, G. C. (2013). How does product recovery affect quality choice? Production and Operations Management,22(4), 991–1010.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atasu, A., & Subramanian, R. (2012). Extended producer responsibility for e-waste: Individual or collective producer responsibility? Production and Operations Management,21(6), 1042–1059.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atasu, A., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. (2012). An operations perspective on product take-back legislation for e-waste: Theory, practice, and research needs. Production and Operations Management,21(3), 407–422.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldé, C. P., Wang, F., Kuehr, R., & Huisman, J. (2015). The global e-waste monitor–2014. Bonn: United Nations University, IAS–SCYCLE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boone, T., Vaidyanathan, J., & Ganeshan, R. (Eds.). (2012). Sustainable supply chains: Models, methods, and public policy implications (Vol. 174). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calcott, P., & Walls, M. (2005). Waste, recycling, and “design for environment”: Roles for markets and policy instruments. Resource and Energy Economics,27(4), 287–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debo, L. G., Toktay, L. B., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. (2005). Market segmentation and product technology selection for remanufacturable products. Management Science,51(8), 1193–1205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esenduran, G., Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, E., & Swaminathan, J. M. (2016). Take-back legislation: Consequences for remanufacturing and environment. Decision Sciences,47(2), 219–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esenduran, G., Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, E., & Swaminathan, J. M. (2017). Impact of take-back regulation on the remanufacturing industry. Production and Operations Management,26(5), 924–944.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, M. E., & Toktay, L. B. (2006). The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Production and Operations Management,15(3), 351–368.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer, G. (1996). Market segmentation and product line design in remanufacturing. Fontainebleau: INSEAD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrer, G., & Swaminathan, J. M. (2006). Managing new and remanufactured products. Management Science,52(1), 15–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geyer, R., Van Wassenhove, L. N., & Atasu, A. (2007). The economics of remanufacturing under limited component durability and finite product life cycles. Management Science,53(1), 88–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gui, L., Atasu, A., Ergun, Ö., & Toktay, L. B. (2015). Efficient implementation of collective extended producer responsibility legislation. Management Science,62(4), 1098–1123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Han, X., Wu, H., Yang, Q., & Shang, J. (2016). Reverse channel selection under remanufacturing risks: Balancing profitability and robustness. International Journal of Production Economics,182, 63–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Han, X., Yang, Q., Shang, J., & Pu, X. (2017). Optimal strategies for trade-old-for-remanufactured programs: Receptivity, durability, and subsidy. International Journal of Production Economics,193, 602–616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauser, W., & Lund, R. T. (2003). The remanufacturing industry: Anatomy of a giant. Boston: Boston University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heese, H. S., Cattani, K., Ferrer, G., Gilland, W., & Roth, A. V. (2005). Competitive advantage through take-back of used products. European Journal of Operational Research,164(1), 143–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huisman, J., Boks, C. B., & Stevels, A. L. N. (2003). Quotes for environmentally weighted recyclability (QWERTY): Concept of describing product recyclability in terms of environmental value. International Journal of Production Research,41(16), 3649–3665.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, H., Lei, M., Deng, H., Leong, G. K., & Huang, T. (2016). A dual channel, quality-based price competition model for the WEEE recycling market with government subsidy. Omega,59, 290–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Z., Tang, J., Li, B. Y., & Wang, Z. (2017). Trade-off between remanufacturing and recycling of WEEE and the environmental implication under the chinese fund policy. Journal of Cleaner Production,167, 97–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma, W. M., Zhao, Z., & Ke, H. (2013). Dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government consumption-subsidy. European Journal of Operational Research,226(2), 221–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Majumder, P., & Groenevelt, H. (2001). Competition in remanufacturing. Production and Operations Management,10(2), 125–141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitra, S., & Webster, S. (2008). Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. International Journal of Production Economics,111(2), 287–298.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ongondo, F. O., & Williams, I. D. (2011). Mobile phone collection, reuse and recycling in the UK. Waste Management,31(6), 1307–1315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck, E., & Wang, Q. (2009). Effects of e-waste regulation on new product introduction. Management Science,55(3), 333–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saphores, J. D. M., Ogunseitan, O. A., & Shapiro, A. A. (2012). Willingness to engage in a pro-environmental behavior: An analysis of e-waste recycling based on a national survey of US households. Resources, Conservation and Recycling,60, 49–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Savaskan, R. C., Bhattacharya, S., & Van Wassenhove, L. N. (2004). Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Management Science,50(2), 239–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • United States International Trade Commission. (2012). Remanufactured goods: An overview of the US and global industries, markets, and trade. USITC Publication,4356, 332–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasudevan, H., Kalamkar, V., & Terkar, R. (2012). Remanufacturing for sustainable development: Key challenges, elements, and benefits. International Journal of Innovation, Management and Technology,3(1), 84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walls, M., & Palmer, K. (2001). Upstream pollution, downstream waste disposal, and the design of comprehensive environmental policies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management,41(1), 94–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, C. H. (2012). Product-design and pricing strategies with remanufacturing. European Journal of Operational Research,222(2), 204–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, S., & Zhu, Q. (2017). Remanufacturing supply chain coordination under the stochastic remanufacturability rate and the random demand. Annals of Operations Research,257(1–2), 661–695.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The work was partly supported by programs granted by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC) (Nos. 71571051 and 71571115) and the National Natural Science Foundation of Guangdong Province (No. 2015A030313492). The authors cordially thank the editor and two anonymous referee for their helpful comments and suggestions, which significantly helped to improve our paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yiwen Bian.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Theorem 1

It can be verified that \( \Pi^{R} \) is strictly concave in \( q_{n}^{R} \), \( q_{r}^{R} \), and \( q_{d}^{R} \). The Lagrangian and the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker optimality conditions of model R are:

$$ \begin{aligned} L\left( {q_{n}^{R} ,q_{r}^{R} ,q_{d}^{R} } \right) & = t\left( {Q - q_{n}^{R} - \alpha q_{r}^{R} } \right)q_{n}^{R} + \alpha t\left( {Q - q_{n}^{R} - q_{r}^{R} } \right)q_{r}^{R} + bq_{d}^{R} - ct^{2} q_{n}^{R} \\ & \quad - (c - \Delta )t^{2} q_{n}^{R}- \;\beta \left( {q_{d}^{R} + q_{r}^{R} } \right)^{2} + \lambda_{1} \left( {q_{n}^{R} - q_{d}^{R} - q_{r}^{R} } \right) + \lambda_{2} q_{r}^{R} + \lambda_{3} q_{d}^{R} \\ \end{aligned} $$
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial q_{n}^{R} }} = \lambda_{1} - t\left( {2q_{n}^{R} + 2\alpha q_{r}^{R} + ct - Q} \right) = 0 $$
(A.1)
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial q_{r}^{R} }} = \lambda_{2} - \lambda_{1} + t\left( {\alpha Q - t(c - \Delta ) - 2\alpha \left( {q_{r}^{R} + q_{n}^{R} } \right)} \right) - 2\beta \left( {q_{r}^{R} + q_{d}^{R} } \right) = 0 $$
(A.2)
$$ \frac{\partial L}{{\partial q_{d}^{R} }} = \lambda_{3} - \lambda_{1} + b - 2\beta \left( {q_{r}^{R} + q_{d}^{R} } \right) = 0 $$
(A.3)
$$ \lambda_{1} \left( {q_{n}^{R} - q_{d}^{R} - q_{r}^{R} } \right) = 0 $$
(A.4)
$$ \lambda_{2} q_{r}^{R} = 0 $$
(A.5)
$$ \lambda_{3} q_{d}^{R} = 0 $$
(A.6)

According to the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker condition method, we can derive four optimal strategies, which are characterized as follows.

Case NR (\( \lambda_{1} = 0 \), \( \lambda_{2} > 0 \), and \( \lambda_{3} > 0 \)):

When \( \lambda_{2} > 0 \), and \( \lambda_{3} > 0 \), we can have \( q_{r}^{R} = 0 \), and \( q_{d}^{R} = 0 \), respectively. Therefore, from Eq. (A.1), we can obtain

$$ q_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}(Q - ct),\quad q_{r}^{R*} = 0,\quad q_{d}^{R*} = 0,\quad {\text{and}}\quad \lambda_{2} = t^{2} (c(1 - \alpha ) - \Delta ),\quad \lambda_{3} = b. $$
(A.7)

Substituting them into the linear inverse demand functions in model R, we have:

$$ p_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}t(Q + ct),\quad {\text{and}}\quad p_{r}^{R*} = \frac{t\alpha (Q + ct)}{2}. $$

The values of \( \lambda_{2} \) and \( \lambda_{3} \) must be positive, and the first constraint of model R must be nonnegative, leading to the necessary condition in this case: \( \Delta < c(1 - \alpha ). \)

Case RM (\( \lambda_{1} = 0 \), \( \lambda_{2} > 0 \), and \( \lambda_{3} = 0 \)):

$$ {\text{When}}\;\lambda_{2} > 0,\;{\text{we}}\;{\text{have}}\;q_{r}^{R} = 0. $$
(A.8)

Based on Eqs. (A.1)–(A.3) and (A.7), we can derive:

$$ q_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}(Q - ct),\quad q_{r}^{R*} = 0,\quad q_{d}^{R*} = b/2\beta ,\quad {\text{and}}\quad \lambda_{2} = b - t^{2} (\Delta - c(1 - \alpha )). $$

Substituting them into the linear inverse demand functions in model R, we obtain:

$$ p_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}t(Q + ct),\quad {\text{and}}\quad p_{r}^{R*} = \frac{t\alpha (Q + ct)}{2}. $$

The value of \( \lambda_{2} \) must be positive, and the first and third constraints of model R must be nonnegative, which leads to the necessary condition in this case: \( c(1 - \alpha ) \le \Delta < \frac{b}{{t^{2} }} + c(1 - \alpha ). \)

Case RMP (\( \lambda_{1} = 0 \), \( \lambda_{2} = 0 \), and \( \lambda_{3} = 0 \)):

From Eqs. (A.1)–(A.3), we can obtain: \( q_{n}^{R*} = \frac{{b + Qt(1 - \alpha ) - t^{2} \Delta }}{2t(1 - \alpha )} \), \( q_{d}^{R*} = \frac{b\beta + t((1 - \alpha )(ct\beta + b) - t\beta \Delta )}{2t(1 - \alpha )\alpha \beta }\quad {\text{and}}\quad q_{r}^{R*} = \frac{{t^{2} (\Delta - c(1 - \alpha )) - b}}{2t(1 - \alpha )\alpha }. \)

Substituting optimal prices into the linear inverse demand functions in model R, we have:

$$ p_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}t(Q + ct),\quad {\text{and}}\quad p_{r}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}(b + t(ct + Q\alpha - t\Delta )). $$

In this case, the constraints in model R must be nonnegative; thus, the necessary condition for this case is: \( \frac{b}{{t^{2} }} + c(1 - \alpha ) \le \Delta < \frac{{b\alpha (1 - \alpha ) + (b + ct^{2} (1 - \alpha ))\beta }}{{\beta t^{2} }}. \).

Case RP (\( \lambda_{1} = 0 \), \( \lambda_{2} = 0 \), and \( \lambda_{3} > 0 \)):

$$ {\text{When}}\;\lambda_{3} > 0\;{\text{we}}\;{\text{have}}:\;q_{d}^{R} = 0. $$
(A.9)

From Eqs. (A.1)–(A.3) and (A.8), we can obtain:

$$ \begin{aligned} q_{n}^{{R*}} &= \frac{{Q(t(1 - \alpha )\alpha + \beta ) - t(c\beta + t\alpha \Delta )}}{{2t(1 - \alpha )\alpha + 2\beta }},\quad q_{r}^{{R*}} = \frac{{t^{2} (c(1 - \alpha ) - \Delta )}}{{2t(1 - \alpha )\alpha + 2\beta }},\quad q_{d}^{{R*}} = 0,\quad {\text{and}} \\ {\lambda _{3}} & = \frac{{\beta (t^{2} (\Delta - c(1 - \alpha ))}}{{t(1 - \alpha ) + \beta }} - b.\end{aligned}$$

Substituting optimal prices into the linear inverse demand functions in model R, we have:

$$ p_{n}^{R*} = \frac{1}{2}t(Q + ct),\quad {\text{and}}\quad p_{r}^{R*} = \frac{{t\alpha ((1 - \alpha )(ct^{2} + Q - \Delta t) + (Q + ct)\beta ).}}{2t(1 - \alpha )\alpha + 2\beta } $$

The value of \( \lambda_{3} \) must be positive, and the first and second constraints of model R must be nonnegative, leading to the necessary condition in this case \( \Delta \ge \frac{{b\alpha (1 - \alpha ) + (b + ct^{2} (1 - \alpha ))\beta }}{{\beta t^{2} }}. \)

The proof of model RS is similar to that of model R, and thus omitted here. We provide optimal decisions and outcomes of models R and RS in Tables 2 and 3, respectively. □

1.2 Proof of Corollary 1

We explore the monotonicity of threshold interval lengths by using partial differentiation techniques. For example, taking the first-order partial derivatives of \( \bar{\Delta }_{2} - \bar{\Delta }_{1} \) with respect to \( t \), we have \( \frac{{\partial (\bar{\Delta }_{2} - \bar{\Delta }_{1} )}}{\partial t} = - \frac{2b}{{t^{3} }} \). Therefore, \( \bar{\Delta }_{2} - \bar{\Delta }_{1} \) decreases with \( t \). All the first-order partial derivatives of threshold interval lengths are given in Table 4. According to these results of first-order partial derivatives, we can reach the findings in Corollary 1. □

Table 4 The first-order partial derivatives of threshold interval lengths

1.3 Proof of Proposition 2

We use partial differentiation techniques to examine the sensitivities of optimal solutions to product quality level \( t \). The proof is similar to the proof of Corollary 1, and thus omitted here. □

1.4 Proof of Corollary 2

Substituting optimal solutions under strategy NR into the profit function in model R, we have \( \Pi^{NR} = \frac{{(Q - ct)^{2} t}}{4} \). It can be verified that \( \Pi^{NR} \) is strictly concave in \( t \). By solving the first-order condition \( \frac{{\partial \Pi^{NR} }}{\partial t} = 0 \), we can have the optimal product quality level is \( \bar{t}_{NR}^{*} = Q/3c \). Similarly, we can derive the optimal product quality level under strategy RM is \( \bar{t}_{RM}^{*} = Q/3c. \)

Substituting optimal solutions under strategy RMP into the profit function in model R, we have

$$ \begin{aligned} \Pi^{R} & = \frac{1}{4t(1 - \alpha )\alpha \beta }\left( {b^{2} (t(1 - \alpha )\alpha + \beta ) + t(1 - \alpha )\left( {c^{2} t^{3} \beta + \alpha (Qt(Q - 2ct)\beta )} \right)} \right. \\ & \quad \left. { - 2ct^{4} ((1 - \alpha )\beta \Delta + t^{4} \beta \Delta^{2} + 2bt((1 - \alpha )ct\beta + t\beta \Delta ))} \right). \\ \end{aligned} $$

It can be verified that \( \Pi^{R} \) is strictly concave in \( t \), because \( \frac{{\partial^{2} \Pi^{R} }}{{\partial t^{2} }} > 0 \). Taking the first-order partial derivatives of \( \Pi^{R} \) with respect to \( t \), we can have \( \frac{{\partial \Pi^{R} }}{\partial t} = \frac{Q\alpha (Q - 2ct)}{4} + \frac{R}{{4\alpha t^{2} (1 - \alpha )}} \), where \( R = 3t^{4} (1 - \alpha )((2c - 1)\Delta + (1 - \alpha )c^{2} ) + b(2t^{2} (\Delta - c(1 - \alpha )) + b) > 0 \). Therefore, we have \( \bar{t}_{RMP} > \frac{Q}{2c} > \bar{t}_{RM} = \bar{t}_{NR} \). Similarly, we can have \( \frac{{\partial \Pi^{R} }}{\partial t} = Q(Q - 2ct) + \frac{T}{{4(\alpha t(1 - \alpha ) + \beta )^{3} }} \), where

$$ \begin{aligned} T & = c^{2} t^{2} \left( {t(1 - \alpha )(8 + \alpha )\beta^{2} + 3\beta^{2} } \right) + \left( {3\alpha^{2} t^{2} (1 - \alpha )^{2} + 9\alpha \beta t(1 - \alpha )} \right)\left( {c^{2} t + (2c + t)\Delta } \right) \\ & \quad + \;(2c - \Delta )t(2(\alpha t(1 - \alpha ) + 2\beta ) + \beta (t(\alpha (1 - \alpha ) + \beta ) + 8\beta^{2} \Delta t(2c + t) > R > 0. \\ \end{aligned} $$

Therefore, we can derive that \( \bar{t}_{RP} > \bar{t}_{RMP} > \bar{t}_{RM} = \bar{t}_{NR} . \)

1.5 Proof of Proposition 3

We use partial differentiation techniques to investigate the sensitivities of optimal solutions to government subsidy \( s \). The proof is similar to the proof of Corollary 1, and thus omitted here. □

1.6 Proof of Proposition 4

According to Eqs. (5), (6), we can derive \( CS^{R} = \frac{1}{8t(Q - ct)^{2}} \), and \( CS^{RS} = \frac{1}{8t(Q - ct)^{2}} \) under RM, we can derive \( CS^{R} = \frac{{t(b^{2} + t^{2} (1 - \alpha )(c^{2} t^{2} + (Q - 2)(Q - 2 + 2ct)\alpha ) + 2ct^{4} (1 - \alpha )\Delta + t^{4} \Delta^{2} + 2bt^{2} (c(1 - \alpha ) + \Delta ))}}{8t(1 - \alpha )\alpha } \), and \( CS^{RS} = \frac{{t(b^{2} + t^{2} (1 - \alpha )(c^{2} t^{2} + (Q - 2)(Q - 2 + 2ct)\alpha ) + 2ct^{4} (1 - \alpha )\Delta + t^{4} \Delta^{2} + 2bt^{2} (c(1 - \alpha ) + \Delta ))}}{8t(1 - \alpha )\alpha } \) under RMP, respectively. By comparing the values of \( CS^{R} \) and \( CS^{RS} \), we can obtain \( CS^{R} = CS^{RS} \) under RM and RMP. Thus, the proof of Proposition 4a is completed. Similarly, we can easily prove Proposition 4b, c. □

1.7 Proof of Proposition 5

According to Eq. (7), we can derive \( RR^{R} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \) and \( RR^{RS} = \frac{b + s}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \) under RM. By comparing the values of \( RR^{R} \) and \( RR^{RS} \), we can find \( RR^{R} < RR^{RS} \). Similarly, based on Eqs. (10), (11), we can derive \( H^{NR} = \frac{{e_{d} (Q - ct)}}{2} \) under NR, and \( H^{R} = \frac{{e_{d} ((Q - ct)\beta - b)}}{2\beta } \), \( H^{RS} = \frac{{e_{d} ((Q - ct)\beta - b - s)}}{2\beta } \) under RM, respectively. By comparing the values of \( H^{NR} \), \( H^{R} \) and \( H^{RS} \), we can find \( H^{R} > H^{RS} \). Similarly, we can have \( RR^{R} < RR^{RS} \) and \( H^{R} > H^{RS} \) under RMP and RP. Thus, we can obtain Proposition 5a.

Substituting optimal quantities into \( RR \) under NR, RM, RMP and RP, respectively, we can obtain \( RR_{NR} = 0 \), \( RR_{RM} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \), \( RR_{RMP} = \frac{bt(1 - \alpha )}{\beta (b + t(Q + Q\alpha - \Delta t))} \), and \( RR_{RP} = \frac{{t^{2} (\Delta - c(1 - \alpha ))}}{Q(t\alpha (1 - \alpha ) + \beta ) - t(c\beta + t\alpha \Delta )} \), respectively. Taking the first-order partial derivatives of \( RR_{RM} \), \( RR_{RMP} \), \( RR_{RP} \) with respect to \( \Delta \), respectively, we have \( \frac{{\partial RR_{RM} }}{\partial \Delta } = 0 \),\( \frac{{\partial RR_{RMP} }}{\partial \Delta } = \frac{{bt^{3} (1 - \alpha )}}{{\beta (b + t(Q + Q\alpha - \Delta t))^{2} }} > 0 \), \( \frac{{\partial RR_{RP} }}{\partial \Delta } = \frac{{t^{2} (t\alpha (Q + ct)(1 - \alpha ) + \beta (Q - ct))}}{{(Q(t\alpha (1 - \alpha ) + \beta ) - t(c\beta + t\alpha \Delta ))^{2} }} > 0 \). Therefore, \( RR_{RM} \) is independent of \( \Delta \), but \( RR_{RMP} \) and \( RR_{RP} \) increase with \( \Delta \). Substituting \( \bar{\Delta }_{1} \) and \( \bar{\Delta }_{2} \) into \( RR \) under RM, we can obtain \( RR_{{RM/\bar{\Delta }_{1} }} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \) and \( RR_{{RMP/\bar{\Delta }_{2} }} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \). Similarly, we can obtain \( RR_{{RMP/\bar{\Delta }_{2} }} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \), \( RR_{{RMP/\bar{\Delta }_{3} }} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta - b\alpha } \) and \( RR_{{RP/\bar{\Delta }_{3} }} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta - b\alpha } \).

Thus, we have \( RR_{RM} = \frac{b}{(Q - ct)\beta } \) when \( \bar{\Delta }_{1} \le \Delta < \bar{\Delta }_{2} \); \( \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta } \le RR_{RMP} < \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta - b\alpha } \) when \( \bar{\Delta }_{2} \le \Delta < \bar{\Delta }_{3} \) and \( \frac{b}{(Q - ct)t\beta - b\alpha } \le RR_{RP} \) when \( \bar{\Delta }_{3} \le \Delta \). By comparing the values of \( RR_{NR} \), \( RR_{RMP} \), \( RR_{RM} \) and \( RR_{RP} \), we have \( RR_{NR} < RR_{RM} \le RR_{RMP} < RR_{RP} \). Using the same techniques, we can obtain \( H_{NR} > H_{RM} \ge H_{RMP} > H_{RP} \). Thus, we can prove Proposition 5b. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Han, X., Shen, Y. & Bian, Y. Optimal recovery strategy of manufacturers: Remanufacturing products or recycling materials?. Ann Oper Res 290, 463–489 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2929-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-2929-5

Keywords

Navigation