Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Impact of power structures in a subcontracting assembly system

  • S.I.: RealCaseOR
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We investigate the impact of power structures on the production and pricing strategies in a decentralized subcontracting assembly system consisting of two suppliers (key supplier and subcontractor) and one manufacturer (assembler). The key supplier, who is also the general contractor, negotiates with the manufacturer and assigns partial component production to the subcontractor. We first identify a single power regime (SPR), in which either the key supplier or the manufacturer determines the wholesale price or the order/production quantity. Under SPR, we consider three power structures, namely, KSA, KAS, and SKA. We find that the assembly system will substantially benefit under KAS. Results show that the subcontracting mechanism between the two suppliers can increase each firm’s profit and disperse the bargaining power. Such a decentralization of powers can weaken the horizontal decentralization between the suppliers and improve the system’s performance, thereby achieving a win–win situation. Furthermore, we extend our analysis to a dual power regime (DPR), in which the key supplier or the manufacturer decides on price and quantity. We show that the proposed assembly system performs optimally under DPR. Moreover, the system will benefit if the firm that is substantially near the end market makes the centralization decision. Compared with the classical pull and push contract model, the proposed assembly system provides the best performance under DPR.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the Xiamen King Long United Automotive Industry, see http://www.king-long.com.

  2. For the Cummins (China) Investment Co., Ltd., see http://www.cummins.com.cn.

  3. Cummins Emission Solutions, a wholly owned subsidiary of Cummins, Inc., is the largest world integration provider in after-treatment technology and emission solutions for the commercial on and off highway engine market.

  4. For the Beijing Hongzhi Huitong Industrial Co., Ltd, see http://www.9540880.1024sj.com.

  5. For the Beijing Support Power Technology Co., Ltd, see http://www.Support.cn.

  6. For the Beijing Anchuang Zhongke Room Equipment, see http://www.anchuang.com.cn.

  7. Note that under the push contract, the key supplier determines the wholesale price first and requires the manufacturer thereafter to decide the order quantity and bear the inventory risk before the demand realization. Under the pull contract, the manufacturer first decides the wholesale price, after which the key supplier decides the production quantity in advance of the selling season.

  8. We use the aforementioned case (King Long, Cummins, Inc, and Cummins Emission Solutions) to derive and verify our main findings. The details of real case data will be elaborated in Sect. 6.3.

References

  • Bernstein, F., & Decroix, G. A. (2004). Decentralized pricing and capacity decisions in a multitier system with modular assembly. Management Science,50(9), 1293–1308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butala, P., & Mpofu, K. (2015). Assembly systems. Springer: CIRP Encyclopedia of Production Engineering.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P. (2004). The allocation of inventory risk in a supply chain: Push, pull, and advance-purchase discount contracts. Management Science,50(2), 222–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cachon, G. P., & Lariviere, M. A. (2005). Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: Strengths and limitations. Management Science,51(1), 30–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, L. G., Ding, D., & Ou, J. (2014). Power structure and profitability in assembly supply chains. Production and Operations Management,23(9), 1599–1616.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M., Cheng, T. C. E., & Zhao, X. (2016). Multi-methodological research in operations management. Production and Operations Management,25(3), 379–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chu, H., Wang, J., Jin, Y., & Suo, H. (2006). Decentralized inventory control in a two-component assembly system. International Journal of Production Economics,102(2), 255–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. (2002). Modern political analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennis, Z. Y., Cheong, T., & Sun, D. (2017). Impact of supply chain power and drop-shipping on a manufacturer’s optimal distribution channel strategy. European Journal of Operational Research,259, 554–563.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edirisinghe, N. C. P., Bichescu, B., & Shi, X. (2011). Equilibrium analysis of supply chain structures under power imbalance. European Journal of Operational Research,214(3), 568–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang, X., So, K. C., & Wang, Y. (2008). Component procurement strategies in decentralized assemble-to-order systems with time-dependent pricing. Management Science,54(12), 1997–2011.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feng, Y., Li, G., & Sethi, S. P. (2018). Pull and push contracts in a decentralised assembly system with random component yields. International Journal of Production Research. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2018.1471237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerchak, Y., & Wang, Y. (2004). Revenue-sharing vs. wholesale-price contracts in assembly systems with random demand. Production and Operations Management,13(1), 23–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gou, Q. L., Sethi, S. P., Yue, J. F., & Zhang, J. (2016). Push and pull contracts in a local supply chain with an outside market. Decision Sciences,47(6), 1150–1177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granot, D., & Yin, S. (2008). Competition and cooperation in decentralized push and pull assembly systems. Management Science,54(4), 733–747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., Li, G., & Sethi, S. P. (2016a). The implication of vendor inventory liability period in a decentralised assembly system. International Journal of Production Research,54(17), 5029–5044.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., Li, G., & Yin, Z. (2016b). The implication of time-based payment contract in the decentralized assembly system. Annals of Operations Research,240(2), 641–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guan, X., Ma, S., & Yin, Z. (2015). The impact of hybrid push–pull contract in a decentralized assembly system. Omega,50, 70–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurnani, H., & Gerchak, Y. (2007). Coordination in decentralized assembly systems with uncertain component yields. European Journal of Operational Research,176(3), 1559–1576.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, L. (2015). Managing supplier competition and sourcing sequence for component manufacturing. Production and Operations Management,24(2), 287–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, L., & Wang, Y. (2010). Supplier competition in decentralized assembly systems with price-sensitive and uncertain demand. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management,12(1), 93–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M. I., & Li, L. (1990). Subcontracting, coordination, flexibility, and production smoothing in aggregate planning. Management Science,36(11), 1352–1363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, B. (2003). Dynamic outsourcing to contract manufacturers with different capabilities of reducing the supply cost. International Journal of Production Economics,86(1), 63–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kouvelis, P., & Milner, J. M. (2002). Supply chain capacity and outsourcing decisions: The dynamic interplay of demand and supply uncertainty. IIE Transactions,34(8), 717–728.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kyparisis, G. J., & Koulamas, C. (2016). Assembly systems with sequential supplier decisions and uncertain demand. Production and Operations Management,25(8), 1404–1414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J. N., & Kim, Y. G. (1999). Effect of partnership quality on IS outsourcing success: Conceptual framework and empirical validation. Journal of Management Information Systems,15(4), 29–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leng, M., & Parlar, M. (2010). Game-theoretic analyses of decentralized assembly supply chains: Non-cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with cost-sharing contracts. European Journal of Operational Research,204(1), 96–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Guan, X., & Mukhopadhyay, S. K. (2016a). The impact of decision timing on the suppliers’ interactions: Simultaneous moves versus sequential moves. Journal of the Operational Research Society,67(2), 248–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Li, L., Zhou, Y., & Guan, X. (2017a). Capacity restoration in a decentralized assembly system with supply disruption risks. International Transactions in Operational Research,24(4), 763–782.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Liu, M. Q., & Guan, X. (2017b). Diversity of payment contracts in a decentralized assembly system. Annals of Operations Research,257, 613–639.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Mao, H., & Xiao, L. (2017c). Impacts of leader–follower structure on pricing and production strategies in a decentralized assembly system. Asia-Pacific Journal of Operational Research,34(1), 1740003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Zhang, L., Guan, X., & Zheng, J. (2016b). Impact of power structure on reliability enhancement with supply disruption risks. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review,90, 25–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, X., Li, Y., & Cai, X. (2013). Double marginalization and coordination in the supply chain with uncertain supply. European Journal of Operational Research,226(2), 228–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman, M. B., & Montgomery, D. B. (1988). First-mover advantages. Strategic Management Journal,9(S1), 41–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luo, Z., Chen, X., Chen, J., & Wang, X. (2017). Optimal pricing policies for differentiated brands under different supply chain power structures. European Journal of Operational Research,259(2), 437–451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lv, F., Ma, S., & Guan, X. (2015). The implication of capacity reservation contracts in assembly system with asymmetric demand information. International Journal of Production Research,53(18), 5564–5591.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan, M., & Bassok, Y. (2008). A bargaining framework in supply chains: The assembly problem. Management Science,54(8), 1482–1496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagarajan, M., & Sošić, G. (2009). Coalition stability in assembly models. Operations Research,57(1), 131–145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pan, W., & So, K. C. (2010). Technical note-Optimal product pricing and component production quantities for an assembly system under supply uncertainty. Operations Research,58(6), 1792–1797.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pun, H., & Heese, H. S. (2015). Controlling a supplier’s subcontracting decisions through contractual enforcement or economic incentives. International Journal of Production Research,53(1), 127–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, P., & Jenamani, M. (2016). Sourcing decision under disruption risk with supply and demand uncertainty: A newsvendor approach. Annals of Operations Research,237(1–2), 237–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saouma, R. (2008). Optimal second-stage outsourcing. Management Science,54(6), 1147–1159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shi, R., Zhang, J., & Ru, J. (2013). Impacts of power structure on supply chains with uncertain demand. Production and Operations Management,22(5), 1232–1249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, A. K., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2016). Dual index production and subcontracting policies for assemble-to-order systems. IIE Transactions,48(5), 415–427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Y., & Gerchak, Y. (2003). Capacity games in assembly systems with uncertain demand. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management,5(3), 252–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Y., Niu, B., & Guo, P. (2014). The comparison of two vertical outsourcing structures under push and pull contracts. Production and Operations Management,23(4), 610–625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, X., Huo, B., Flynn, B. B., & Yeung, J. H. Y. (2008). The impact of power and relationship commitment on the integration between manufacturers and customers in a supply chain. Journal of Operations Management,26(3), 368–388.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors sincerely thank the editors and anonymous reviewers for their insightful comments and suggestions. This research is partially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under the Grant nos. 91746110, 71372019, 71871091, 71471057, 71521002, and 71642004; the National Basic Research Program of China (973 Program); the Special Items Fund of Beijing Municipal Commission of Education.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mengqi Liu.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof for Lemma 1

Note that a critical condition \( k = \frac{{c_{2} }}{w} \) guarantees the subcontractor’s profit positive. That is, the optimal subcontracting price ratio is \( \frac{{c_{2} }}{w} \). We calculate the first and second derivatives of Eq. (5) on \( q_{ksa} \) to obtain \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{ksa} }} = \left\{ {p[1 - g(q_{ksa} )] - \frac{{c_{1} + c_{2} }}{{\bar{F}(q_{ksa} )}}} \right\}\bar{F}(q_{ksa} ) \) and \( \frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{{_{ksa} }}^{2} }} = - 2\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ksa} )g(q_{ksa} ) < 0 \), where \( g(x) = \frac{xf(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \). Thus, the supply chain’s equilibrium production quantity satisfies \( p[1 - g(q_{ksa} )] = \frac{{c_{1} + c_{2} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ksa} )}} \). In addition, the optimal wholesale price and subcontracting price ratio are \( w^{*} = \frac{{c_{1} + c_{2} }}{{1 - g(q_{ksa} )}} \) and \( k^{*} = \frac{{c_{2} }}{{c_{1} + c_{2} }}[1 - g(q_{ksa} )] \), respectively.

1.2 Proof of Lemma 2

Note that the two suppliers’ optimal strategy has a unique Nash equilibrium as follows:

$$ {\prod}_{S1} (k,q_{1} ) = w(1 - k)E\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ,q_{2} ) - c_{1} q_{1} $$
(A1)
$$ {\prod}_{S2} (q_{2} ) = kwE\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ,q_{2} ) - c_{2} q_{2} . $$
(A2)

We combine Eqs. (A1) and (A2). If \( q_{1} < q_{2} \), then we obtain the following equations:

$$ {\prod}_{S1} (k,q_{1} ) = w(1 - k)E\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ) - c_{1} q_{1} $$
(A3)

and

$$ {\prod}_{S2} (q_{2} ) = kwE\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ) - c_{2} q_{2} . $$
(A4)

We consider the first and second derivatives of Eqs. (A3) and (A4) to obtain \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{1} }} = w(1 - k)[1 - F(q_{1} )] - c_{1} ,\;and\;{\kern 1pt} \frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{1}^{2} }} = - w(1 - k)f(q_{1} ) < 0. \) In addition, \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{2} }} = - c_{2} \; < 0 \). Thus, the two suppliers’ optimal production quantity is \( q_{1} \wedge q_{2} \) and \( q_{1}^{{}} = \bar{F}^{ - 1} \left( {\frac{{c_{1} }}{w(1 - k)}} \right) \).

If \( q_{1} > q_{2} \), then we obtain the following equations:

$$ {\prod}_{S1} (k,q_{1} ) = w(1 - k)E\hbox{min} (D,q_{2} ) - c_{1} q_{1} $$
(A5)

and

$$ {\prod}_{S2} (q_{2} ) = kwE\hbox{min} (D,q_{2} ) - c_{2} q_{2} . $$
(A6)

When the first and second derivatives of Eqs. (A5) and (6) are calculated, we obtain \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{2} }} = kw[1 - F(q_{2} )] - c_{2} ,\;and\;\frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{2}^{2} }} = - kwf(q_{2} ) < 0 \).

In equilibrium, the two suppliers’ optimal production quantity is \( q_{1} \wedge q_{2} \) and \( q_{2}^{{}} = \bar{F}^{ - 1} \left( {\frac{{c_{2} }}{kw}} \right) \). Thus, we use Eqs. (A4) and (A5) to solve for \( q_{1} \) and \( q_{2} \) in terms of \( w \) and \( k \). Accordingly, \( q_{1}^{{}} = \bar{F}^{ - 1} \left( {\frac{{c_{1} }}{w(1 - k)}} \right) \) and \( q_{2}^{{}} = \bar{F}^{ - 1} \left( {\frac{{c_{2} }}{kw}} \right) \). Thereafter, we obtain \( w = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{1}^{{}} )}} + \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{2}^{{}} )}} \) and \( k = \frac{{c_{2} }}{{w\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{2}^{{}} )}} \). Thus, the equilibrium production quantity of the KAS mode is defined by \( q_{kas} = q_{1} \wedge q_{2} \). Moreover, the integrated system shares the same principle with this Lemma.

1.3 Proof of Lemma 3

When the manufacturer’s profit function in Eq. (10) is used, if \( q_{1} \ge q_{2} \), then we obtain the following equation:

$$ {\prod}_{M} (q_{1} ,q_{2} ) = \left[ {p - \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{1} )}} - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{2} )}}} \right]E\hbox{min} (D,q_{2} ), $$
(A7)

which is evidently decreasing in \( q_{1} \). In addition, the optimal \( q_{1} \) equals the threshold \( q_{2} \). If \( q_{1} \le q_{2} \), then we obtain the following equation:

$$ {\prod}_{M} (q_{1} ,q_{2} ) = \left[ {p - \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{1} )}} - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{2} )}}} \right]E\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ). $$
(A8)

When the first and second derivatives of Eq. (A8) are calculated, we can obtain \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{M} }}{{\partial q_{1} }} = \left[ {p - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\bar{F}(q_{2} )}}} \right]\bar{F}(q_{1} ) - c_{1} [1 + j(q_{1} )h(q_{1} )] \), and \( \frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{M} }}{{\partial q_{1}^{2} }} = - \left[ {p - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\bar{F}(q_{2} )}}} \right]f(q_{1} ) - c_{1} [j(q_{1} )h(q_{1} )]^{'} < 0 \), where \( j(x) = \frac{S(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \) and \( h(x) = \frac{f(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \).

Hence, Eq. (A8) is concave in \( q_{1} \) and \( q_{1}^{*} = \hbox{min} (q_{1} ,q_{2} ) \). From \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{M} }}{{\partial q_{1} }} = 0 \), we can obtain \( \frac{{\bar{F}(q_{1} )}}{{1 + j(q_{1} )h(q_{1} )}} = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{p - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\bar{F}(q_{2} )}}}} \). Thus, the key supplier’s profit function can be written in terms of \( q_{1}^{*} \) as \( \prod_{S1} (q_{1}^{*} ) = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{1}^{*} )}}E\hbox{min} (D,q_{1}^{*} ,q_{2} ) - c_{1} q_{1}^{*} \). If \( q_{1} \ge q_{2} \), there is \( \prod_{S1} (q_{2} ) = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{2} )}}E\hbox{min} (D,q_{2} ) - c_{1} q_{2} \). Given that \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{2} }} = \frac{{f(q_{2} )S(q_{2} )}}{{\bar{F}^{2} (q_{2} )}}c_{1} > 0 \), \( \prod_{S1} \) is decreasing in \( q_{2} \). Thus, the optimal \( q_{2} \) equals \( q_{1} \). If \( q_{1} \le q_{2} \), there is \( \prod_{S1} (q_{2} ) = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{1} )}}E\hbox{min} (D,q_{1} ) - c_{1} q_{1} \). Given that \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{2} }} = \frac{{f(q_{1} )S(q_{1} )}}{{\bar{F}^{2} (q_{1} )}}\frac{{\partial q_{1} }}{{\partial q_{2} }}c_{1} < 0 \), \( \prod_{S1} \) is decreasing in \( q_{2} \). Thus, the optimal \( q_{2} \) equals \( q_{1} \).

In equilibrium, the optimal production quantity satisfies \( q_{kas} = q_{1} = q_{2} \) and \( \frac{{\bar{F}(q_{kas} )}}{{1 + j(q_{kas} )h(q_{kas} )}} = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{p - \frac{{c_{2} }}{{\bar{F}(q_{kas} )}}}} \). The optimal wholesale price and subcontracting price ratio are defined by \( w^{*} = \frac{{c_{1} + c_{2} }}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{kas} )}} \) and \( k^{*} = \frac{{c_{2} }}{{c_{1} + c_{2} }} \), respectively, where \( j(x) = \frac{S(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \) and \( h(x) = \frac{f(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \).

1.4 Proof of Lemma 4

We use backward induction and start from the third stage, when the manufacturer decides the order quantity from the two suppliers. Given the manufacturer’s profit function in Eq. (8), solving the first and second orders condition of \( \prod_{M} \) will yield \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{M} }}{{\partial q_{m} }} = p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{m} ) - w \) and \( \frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{M} }}{{\partial q_{m}^{2} }} = - pf(q_{m} ) < 0 \). Thereafter, the optimal order quantity satisfies \( q_{ska} = \bar{F}^{ - 1} \left( {\frac{w}{p}} \right) \). That is,

$$ w(q_{ska} ) = p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} ). $$
(A9)

Thus, Eq. (9) is used to write the key supplier’s profit in terms of \( q_{ska} \). Hence,

$$ {\prod}_{S1} (q_{ska} ) = [(1 - k)p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} ) - c_{1} ]q_{ska} . $$
(A10)

When the first and second derivatives of Eq. (A10) are calculated, we can obtain that \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{ska} }} = p(1 - k)[\bar{F}(q_{ska} ) - q_{ska} f(q_{ska} )] - c_{1} \) and \( \frac{{\partial^{2} \prod_{S1} }}{{\partial q_{ska}^{2} }} = - 2p(1 - k)f(q_{ska} ) < 0 \). Thereafter, Eq. (A10) is concave in \( q_{ska} \) and the optimal order quantity \( q_{ska} \) satisfies \( p(1 - k)\bar{F}(q_{ska} )[1 - g(q_{ska} )] = c_{1} \), where \( g(x) = \frac{xf(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \). Thereafter, substituting Eq. (A9) into the subcontractor’s profit function will yield as follows:

$$ {\prod}_{S2} (q_{ska} ) = \left[ {p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} ) - \frac{{c_{1} }}{{1 - g(q_{ska} )}} - c_{2} } \right]q_{ska} . $$
(A11)

Similarly, the derivative of Eq. (A11) yields \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{ska} }} = p\bar{F}(q_{ska} )[1 - g(q_{ska} )] - \frac{{c_{1} }}{{1 - g(q_{ska} )}} - c_{2} - q_{ska} \frac{{c_{1} g^{'} (q_{ska} )}}{{[1 - g(q_{ska} )]^{2} }} \). Given that \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{ska} }}\left| {{}_{{q_{ska} = 0}}} \right. = p - c_{1} - c_{2} > 0 \), \( \frac{{\partial \prod_{S2} }}{{\partial q_{ska} }}\left| {{}_{{q_{ska} = \infty }}} \right. < 0 \), and \( \prod_{S2} \) is continuous, there exists a maximum \( q_{ska} \) at least to maximize \( \prod_{S2} \). Moreover, the maximum \( q_{ska} \) satisfies \( p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} )[1 - g(q_{ska} )] - q_{ska} \frac{{c_{1} g^{'} (q_{ska} )}}{{[1 - g(q_{ska} )]^{2} }} = \frac{{c_{1} }}{{1 - g(q_{ska} )}} + c_{2} \). Subsequently, the optimal wholesale price and subcontracting price ratio are defined by \( w^{*} = p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} ) \) and \( k^{*} = 1 - \frac{{c_{1} }}{{p\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (q_{ska} )[1 - g(q_{ska} )]}} \), where \( g(x) = \frac{xf(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \) and \( h(x) = \frac{f(x)}{{\mathop F\limits^{\_\_} (x)}} \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Li, G., Li, L., Liu, M. et al. Impact of power structures in a subcontracting assembly system. Ann Oper Res 291, 475–498 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-3041-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-018-3041-6

Keywords

Navigation