Skip to main content
Log in

A distinctive early bird price in reward-based crowdfunding

  • Published:
Electronic Commerce Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many crowdfunding platforms allow creators maximum flexibility in terms of the prices and rewards offered in a project to gain sufficient capital. Early bird prices, with the original purpose of attracting more early consumers by providing a discounted price for the same product sold in traditional e-commerce retail, are widely used in crowdfunding worldwide and unexpectedly result in “overpay” behaviour. This research aims to explore whether and how creators can use this “overpay” behaviour through dynamic theory with incomplete information, verifying our point of view through empirical analysis. The results show that providing multiple prices for same product generally increases funding performance because backers will balance the surplus and the success rate of their payment decisions to maximize their expected surplus; however, when projects face the low heterogeneity of backer groups, providing a uniform price may be an optimal pricing decision. These findings have direct implications for launching crowdfunding projects that will be more effective in funding more capital by offering reasonable prices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This research focuses on reward-based crowdfunding, which will be referred to hereafter as crowdfunding.

  2. Information about price and the funding goal cannot be modified during the funding campaign. All price information is posted on campaign websites. The backer decides which price to pay.

  3. Scholars have proven that the behaviours of early backers, medium-term backers, and late backers differ to a large extent. We use three backers to simplify the problem, but the role of different backer behaviours at all stages should be considered.

  4. The actual funding is 3H because the campaign will succeed only if all three backers pay a high price when T ∈ (3L, 3H). For ease of display, the funding goal T is equal to the sum of the prices three backers promise to pay, expressed similarly hereinafter.

  5. For this example, we aim to give readers a clear understanding of how the mechanism works. For ease of understanding, we assume that there are two backers in this example.

References

  1. Mollick, E. (2014). The dynamics of crowdfunding: An exploratory study. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T., & Schwienbacher, A. (2014). Crowdfunding: Tapping the right crowd. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(5), 585–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Giudici, G., Guerini, M., & Rossi-Lamastra, C. (2018). Reward-based crowdfunding of entrepreneurial projects: The effect of local altruism and localized social capital on proponents’ success. Small Business Economics, 50(2), 307–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Allison, T. H., Davis, B. C., Short, J. C., & Webb, J. W. (2015). Crowdfunding in a prosocial microlending environment: Examining the role of intrinsic versus extrinsic cues. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 39(1), 53–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Gleasure, R., & Feller, J. (2016). Does heart or head rule donor behaviors in charitable crowdfunding markets? International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 20(4), 499–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Bretschneider, U., & Leimeister, J. M. (2017). Not just an ego-trip: Exploring backers’ motivation for funding in incentive-based crowdfunding. The Journal of Strategic Information Systems, 26(4), 246–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Kuppuswamy, V., & Bayus, B. L. (2018). Crowdfunding creative ideas: The dynamics of project backers. In D. Cumming & L. Hornuf (Eds.), The economics of crowdfunding (pp. 151–182). Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  8. Wessel, M., Thies, F., & Benlian, A. (2016). The emergence and effects of fake social information: Evidence from crowdfunding. Decision Support Systems, 90, 75–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Ahlers, G. K., Cumming, D., Günther, C., & Schweizer, D. (2015). Signaling in equity crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 39(4), 955–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Zheng, H., Li, D., Wu, J., & Xu, Y. (2014). The role of multidimensional social capital in crowdfunding: A comparative study in China and US. Information & Management, 51(4), 488–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Kuppuswamy, V., & Bayus, B. L. (2017). Does my contribution to your crowdfunding project matter? Journal of Business Venturing, 32(1), 72–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Skirnevskiy, V., Bendig, D., & Brettel, M. (2017). The influence of internal social capital on serial creators’ success in crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 41(2), 209–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Yuan, H., Lau, R. Y., & Xu, W. (2016). The determinants of crowdfunding success: A semantic text analytics approach. Decision Support Systems, 91, 67–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Anderson, K. B., & Saxton, G. D. (2016). Smiles, Babies, and Status Symbols: The persuasive effects of image choices in small-entrepreneur crowdfunding requests. International Journal of Communication, 10, 1764–1785.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Wang, Z., Mao, H., Li, Y. J., & Liu, F. (2016). Smile big or not? Effects of smile intensity on perceptions of warmth and competence. Journal of Consumer Research, 43(5), 787–805.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Parhankangas, A., & Renko, M. (2017). Linguistic style and crowdfunding success among social and commercial entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 32(2), 215–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Cho, M., & Kim, G. (2017). A cross-cultural comparative analysis of crowdfunding projects in the United States and South Korea. Computers in Human Behavior, 72, 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Josefy, M., Dean, T. J., Albert, L. S., & Fitza, M. A. (2017). The role of community in crowdfunding success: Evidence on cultural attributes in funding campaigns to “Save the local theater”. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 41(2), 161–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Agrawal, A. K., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2011). The geography of crowdfunding (No. w16820). National Bureau of Economic Research.

  20. Sorenson, O., Assenova, V., Li, G. C., Boada, J., & Fleming, L. (2016). Expand innovation finance via crowdfunding. Science, 354(6319), 1526–1528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Roma, P., Petruzzelli, A. M., & Perrone, G. (2017). From the crowd to the market: The role of reward-based crowdfunding performance in attracting professional investors. Research Policy, 46(9), 1606–1628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Stanko, M. A., & Henard, D. H. (2016). How Crowdfunding Influences Innovation. MIT Sloan Management Review, 57(3), 15–17.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Stanko, M. A., & Henard, D. H. (2017). Toward a better understanding of crowdfunding, openness and the consequences for innovation. Research Policy, 46(4), 784–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Nucciarelli, A., Li, F., Fernandes, K. J., Goumagias, N., Cabras, I., Devlin, S., et al. (2017). From value chains to technological platforms: The effects of crowdfunding in the digital game industry. Journal of Business Research, 78, 341–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Gerber, E. M., & Hui, J. (2013). Crowdfunding: Motivations and deterrents for participation. ACM Transactions on Computer–Human Interaction (TOCHI)., 20, 34. https://doi.org/10.1145/2530540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Harms, M. (2007). What drives motivation to participate financially in a crowdfunding community? http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2269242.

  27. Thomas, S. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: WW Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Chen, Y., Wang, Q., & Xie, J. (2011). Online social interactions: A natural experiment on word of mouth versus observational learning. Journal of Marketing Research, 48(2), 238–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Duan, W., Gu, B., & Whinston, A. B. (2009). Informational cascades and software adoption on the internet: An empirical investigation. MIS Quarterly, 33(1), 23–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Zhang, J., & Liu, P. (2012). Rational herding in microloan markets. Management Science, 58(5), 892–912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Colombo, M. G., Franzoni, C., & Rossi-Lamastra, C. (2015). Internal social capital and the attraction of early contributions in crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 39(1), 75–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2014). Some simple economics of crowdfunding. Innovation Policy and the Economy, 14(1), 63–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Lee, E., & Lee, B. (2012). Herding behavior in online P2P lending: An empirical investigation. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 11(5), 495–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Burtch, G., Ghose, A., & Wattal, S. (2013). An empirical examination of the antecedents and consequences of contribution patterns in crowd-funded markets. Information Systems Research, 24(3), 499–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Yum, H., Lee, B., & Chae, M. (2012). From the wisdom of crowds to my own judgment in microfinance through online peer-to-peer lending platforms. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 11(5), 469–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Mollick, E., & Nanda, R. (2015). Wisdom or madness? Comparing crowds with expert evaluation in funding the arts. Management Science, 62(6), 1533–1553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Hu, M., Li, X., & Shi, M. (2015). Product and pricing decisions in crowdfunding. Marketing Science, 34(3), 331–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Ji, Y., Wei, J., Wu, Z., Qu, S., & Zhang, B. (2018). Dynamic strategies on firm production and platform advertisement in crowdfunding considering investor’s perception. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society. https://doi.org/10.1155/2018/3726080.

  39. Morgenstern, O., & Von Neumann, J. (1953). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [71472172], and the China Postdoctoral Science Foundation [2016M602042].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chaoliang Ma.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Uniform pricing strategy

Uniform pricing strategy means that the creator provides one uniform price \(p\) for three backers. Given the two-point distribution of product valuations, price \(p\) should be \(p \le L\) or \(L < p \le H\), while funding goal \(T\) should be \(T \le 3p\).

1.1.1 \(p \le L\)

As a result of \(p \le L\), and \(T \le 3p\), the campaign must be successful because backers’ valuations are higher than price \(p\). Although funding goal \(T \le 3p\), the actual funding must be \(3p\). Hence, when \(p = L\), the maximum expected campaign revenue under this situation is \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = 3L\).

1.1.2 \(L < p \le H\)

Following the same logic, \(L < p \le H\), and \(T \le 3p\). In this scenario, the campaign will be successful as long as three backers are high-valuation; hence, the success rate is \(\alpha^{3}\). Although the funding goal is \(T \le 3p\), the actual funding must be \(3p\). Hence, when \(p = H\), the maximum expected revenue of a campaign under this situation is \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = 3\alpha^{3} H\).

1.2 Early bird pricing strategy

The early bird pricing strategy means that the creator provides two price options (\(P_{H} ,P_{L}\)) for the same product, and backers make their own decision about which price to pay. The effective prices should satisfy the following conditions: \(L < P_{H} \le H\), \(P_{L} \le L P_{S} < P_{H} \le LL < P_{S} < P_{H} \le H\). Moreover, funding goal \(T\) will be \(T \le 3P_{L}\), \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\), \(T \le P_{L} + 2P_{H}\) and \(T \le 3P_{H}\). As follows.

1.2.1 \(T \le 3P_{L}\)

Because of \(P_{L} \le L < P_{H} \le H\) and \(T \le 3P_{L}\), the same as the uniform pricing strategy with a low price, this approach must be successful with success rate 1. Although the funding goal is \(T \le 3P_{L}\), the actual funding must be \(3P_{L}\). Hence, when \(P_{L} = L\) and \(L < P_{H} \le H\) (condition ② of Fig. 4), the maximum expected revenue of the campaign under this situation is \(EP_{max} = 3L\).

Fig. 4
figure 4

The logic of backers’ decisions

1.2.2 \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\)

Because of \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\), the campaign will be successful as long as one backer pays high price \(P_{H}\); the figure above shows the behaviour logic under \(3P_{L} < T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\).

(1) Condition ③

Under \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) with probability \(\alpha\) will think that if \(B_{1}\) pays \(P_{H}\), the campaign must succeed with conditional success rate 1 and surplus \(H - P_{H}\), and therefore, the conditional expected surplus of paying high price \(P_{H}\) is \(H - P_{H}\); however, if \(B_{1}\) pay the low price \(P_{L}\), because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), as long as one of the remaining two backers is a high-valuation backer, the campaign will succeed, hence, the conditional success rate of paying low price is \(2\alpha - \alpha^{2}\), with surplus \(H - P_{L}\). Therefore, the conditional expected surplus of paying low price \(P_{L}\) is \(\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\); thus, under \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\) (feasible region DEF of Fig. 5), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) would pay the high price. In addition, if \(B_{1}\) pay the low price, because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), high-valuation backer \(B_{2}\) will also pay the high price. Moreover, if both \(B_{1}\) and \(B_{2}\) pay the low price, high-valuation backer \(B_{3}\) will pay the high price because \(H - P_{H} > 0\).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Analysis of optimal prices under \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\)

Therefore, for the creator, the conditional success rate of the creator’s price decision is \(\left( {3\upalpha - 3\alpha^{2} + \alpha^{3} } \right)\), and the conditional expected revenue of \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\) and \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\) is \(\left( {3\upalpha - 3\alpha^{2} + \alpha^{3} } \right)\left( {2P_{L} + P_{H} } \right)\). When the prices are \(P_{L} = L - \varepsilon ,P_{H} = \left( {1 -\upalpha} \right)^{2} H + \left( {2\upalpha - \alpha^{2} } \right){\text{L}} - \epsilon\), (see where \(\varepsilon\) and \(\epsilon\) are bigger than (but close to) 0, the expected revenue can be simplified as \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = \left( {3\alpha - 3\alpha^{2} + \alpha^{3} } \right)[\left( {1 - \alpha )^{2} H + \left( {2 + 2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)L} \right]\)).

(2) Condition ⑤

Under \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) < \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) with probability \(\alpha\) would think that if \(B_{1}\) pays \(P_{H}\), the campaign must succeed with conditional success rate 1 and surplus \(H - P_{H}\), therefore, the conditional expected surplus of paying high price \(P_{H}\) is \(H - P_{H}\); if \(B_{1}\) pays the low price \(P_{L}\), because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), as long as one of the remaining two backers is high valuation, the campaign will succeed, hence, the conditional success rate of paying the low price is \(2\alpha - \alpha^{2}\) with surplus \(H - P_{L}\); therefore, the conditional expected surplus of paying low price \(P_{L}\) is \(\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\). Accordingly, because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) < \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) will pay the low price, but for \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\) and \(H - P_{H} > 0\), the campaign will succeed as long as one of \(B_{2}\) and \(B_{3}\) is a high-valuation backer, hence; for the creator, the conditional success rate of the creator’s price decision is \(\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\) and the conditional expected revenue of \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\) and \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) < \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\) (feasible region CDFGI of Fig. 5) is \(\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {2P_{L} + P_{H} } \right)\). When the prices are \(P_{L} = L - \varepsilon\), \(P_{H} = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)H + \alpha {\text{L}} - \epsilon\), where \(\varepsilon\) and \(\epsilon\) are bigger than 0, but close to 0, the expected revenue can be simplified as \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = \left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left[ {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)H + \left( {2 + \alpha } \right)L} \right]\).

(3) Condition ⑦

Under \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {H - P_{H} > 0} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) < \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\), both \(B_{1}\) and \(B_{2}\) will not pay the high price and the campaign will succeed where only backer \(B_{3}\) is a high-valuation backer with success rate \(\alpha\). Hence, the conditional expected revenue of \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\) and \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {H - P_{H} > 0} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) < \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\) (feasible region ABCI) is \(\alpha\). When the prices are \(P_{L} = L - \varepsilon\), \(P_{H} = H - \epsilon\), where \(\varepsilon\) and \(\epsilon\) are bigger than 0, but close to 0, the expected revenue can be simplified as \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = \alpha \left( {H + 2L} \right)\).

1.2.3 \(T \le P_{L} + 2P_{H}\)

Because of \(T \le 2P_{L} + P_{H}\), the campaign will be successful at least two backers pay high price \(P_{H}\); the figure above shows the behaviour logic under \(P_{H} + 2P_{L} < T \le 2P_{H} + P_{L}\).

(1) Condition ④

Under \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha^{2} \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) with probability \(\alpha\) will think that if \(B_{1}\) pays the \(P_{H}\), because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), as long as one of the remaining two backers is high valuation, the campaign will succeed; hence, the conditional success rate of paying the low price is \(2\alpha - \alpha^{2}\), with surplus \(H - P_{H}\). However, if \(B_{1}\) pays the \(P_{L}\), the campaign will succeed only if both of the remaining backers are high valuation; hence, the conditional success rate of paying the low price is \(\alpha^{2}\), with surplus \(H - P_{L}\). Because of \(\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha^{2} \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) will pay the high price \(P_{H}\). In addition, if \(B_{1}\) pays the \(P_{H}\), because of \(\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)\), high-valuation backer \(B_{2}\) will also pay the high price \(P_{H}\). For the creator, the conditional success rate of \(\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\left( {2\alpha - \alpha^{2} } \right)\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha^{2} \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ {\left( {H - P_{H} } \right) \ge \alpha \left( {H - P_{L} } \right)} \\ \end{array} } \right.\) and \(P_{H} + 2P_{L} < T \le 2P_{H} + P_{L}\) (feasible region CDEF of Fig. 6 below) is \(3\alpha^{2} - 2\alpha^{3}\); Table 5 details our success rate analysis. When the prices are \(P_{L} = L - \varepsilon\), \(P_{H} = \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)H + \alpha {\text{L}} - \epsilon\), where \(\varepsilon\) and \(\epsilon\) are bigger than (but close to) 0, the expected revenue can be simplified as \(EP_{max} = \left( {3\alpha^{2} - 2\alpha^{3} } \right)\left[ {2\left( {1 -\upalpha} \right)H + \left( {2\upalpha + 1} \right){\text{L}}} \right]\).

Fig. 6
figure 6

Analysis of optimal price under \(T \le P_{L} + 2P_{H}\)

Table 5 Success rate

(2) Condition ⑥

If high-valuation backer \(B_{1}\) is willing to pay the high price (the feasible region ABCF of Fig. 6), for the creator, the success rate of the pricing decision is \(\alpha^{2}\), and the campaign will succeed only if both \(B_{2}\) and \(B_{3}\) are high valuation. Hence, when the prices are \(P_{L} = L - \varepsilon\), \(P_{H} = H - \epsilon\), where \(\varepsilon\) and \(\epsilon\) are bigger than (but close to) 0, the expected revenue can be simplified as \(EP_{\hbox{max} } =\upalpha\left[ {2H + L} \right]\).

1.2.4 \(T \le 3P_{H}\)

Because of \(P_{L} \le L < P_{H} \le H\) and \(P_{L} + 2P_{H} < T \le 3P_{H}\), the same as the uniform pricing strategy with the high price, the campaign will succeed when three backers are high-valuation with success rate \(\alpha^{3}\). Although the funding goal is \(T \le 3P_{L}\), the actual funding must be \(3P_{H}\). Hence, when \(P_{L} \le L\) and \(P_{H} = H\) (Condition ① of Fig. 4), the conditional expected revenue of the campaign under this situation is \(EP_{\hbox{max} } = 3\alpha^{3}\) (Table 6).

Table 6 The expected revenues and price(s) of different pricing strategies

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, M., Liu, Z., Ma, C. et al. A distinctive early bird price in reward-based crowdfunding. Electron Commer Res 21, 347–370 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-019-09356-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-019-09356-5

Keywords

Navigation