Skip to main content
Log in

On the Performance of Managers and Controllers: A Polymatrix Game Approach for the Manager–Controller–Board of Directors’ Conflict

  • Published:
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this article, we focus on the conflict among the manager, the controller and the board of directors of a company. We model the problem as a three-player polymatrix game. Under a set of assumptions, we identify five potential Nash equilibria. We prove that the Nash equilibrium is unique, despite its changing structure. Next, we analyze the influence of the manager’s and controller’s bonuses and penalties on the Nash equilibria. Finally, we explain how the manager and the controller may decrease or maintain their performance, when their bonuses or penalties increase.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Elson, C.: The duty of care, compensation, and stock ownership. Univ. Cincinnati Law Rev. 63, 649–711 (1995)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Dalton, D., Certo, T., Daily, C.: Initial public offerings (IPOs) as a web of conflicts of interest: an empirical assessment. Bus. Ethics Q. 13, 289–314 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Bebchuk, L.A., Fried, J.M., Walker, D.I.: Managerial power and rent extraction in the design of executive compensation. Univ. Chicago Law Rev. 69, 751–846 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bebchuk, L.A., Fried, J.M.: Pay Without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  5. Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S.: Is there discretion in wage setting? A test using takeover legislation. RAND J. Econ. 30, 535–554 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S.: Agents with and without principals. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 203–208 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Almazan, A., Suarez, J.: Entrenchment and severance pay in optimal governance structures. J. Finance 58, 519–547 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Magee, R.P.: Regulation and the cost effectiveness of independent audits. In: Buckley, J.W., Weston, J.F. (eds.) Regulation and the Accounting Profession, pp. 163–177. Lifetime Learning, Belmont (1980)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Balachandran, B.V., Nagarajan, N.J.: Imperfect information, insurance, and auditors’ legal liability. Contemp. Account. Res. 3, 281–302 (1987)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Moore, G., Scott, W.R.: Auditor’s legal liability, collusion with management and investors’ loss. Contemp. Account. Res. 5, 754–774 (1989)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Fellingham, J.C., Newman, D.P.: Strategic considerations in auditing. Account. Rev. 60, 634–650 (1985)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Fandel, G., Trockel, J.: A game theoretical analysis of an extended manager–auditor-conflict. Z. für Betriebswirtschaft 4, 33–53 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Fandel, G., Trockel, J.: Avoiding non-optimal management decisions by applying a three-person inspection game. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 226, 85–93 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Holmstrom, B.: Moral hazard in teams. Bell J. Econ. 13, 324–340 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Lewis, T.R.: Bonuses and penalties in incentive contracting. Bell J. Econ. 11, 292–301 (1980)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Gaynor, M.: More on moral hazard in organizations: reply. Public Choice 74, 257–262 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Aron, D.J., Olivella, P.: Bonus and penalty schemes as equilibrium incentive devices, with application to manufacturing systems. J. Law Econ. Organ. 10, 1–34 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Humphery-Jenner, M., Lisic, L.L., Nanda, V., Silveri, S.D.: Executive overconfidence and compensation structure. J. Financ. Econ. 119, 533–558 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Cooper, M.J, Gulen, H., Rau, P.R.: Performance for pay? The relation between CEO incentive compensation and future stock price performance. (2016). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1572085 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1572085. Accessed 19 Dec 2017.

  20. Audet, C., Belhaiza, S., Hansen, P.: Enumeration of all extreme equilibria in game theory: bimatrix and polymatrix games. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 129, 349–372 (2006)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  21. Borch, K.: Insuring and auditing the auditor. In: Deistler, M., Fürst, E., Schwödiauer, G. (eds.) Games, Economic Dynamics, Time Series Analysis, pp. 117–126. Physica, Vienna (1982)

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  22. Neisser, U., Boodoo, G., Bouchard, T.J., Boykin, A.W., Brody, N., Ceci, S.J., Halpern, D.F., Loehlin, J.C., Perloff, R., Sternberg, R.J., Urbina, S.: Intelligence: knowns and unknowns. Am. Psychol. 51, 77–101 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Johnson-Laird, P.N., Byrne, R.M.J.: Deduction. Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, New Jersey (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  24. Simon, H.A.: Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Models of Man, Social and Rational: Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Social Setting. Wiley, New York (1957)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  25. Ben-David, I., Graham, J.R., Harvey, C.R.: Managerial miscalibration. Q. J. Econ. 128, 1547–1584 (2016)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Malmendier, U., Tate, G., Yan, J.: Overconfidence and early-life experiences: the effect of managerial traits on corporate financial policies. J. Finance 66, 1687–1733 (2011)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to S. Belhaiza.

Additional information

Communicated by Kyriakos G. Vamvoudakis.

Appendices

Appendix A

The detailed motivations of Assumptions 3.6 and 3.7 are as follows.

Motivation 3.6

Regardless of the strategy \(X_{\mathcal {C}}\) of \(\mathcal {C}\), \(\mathcal {B}\) acts rationally and chooses \(x_b=1,\) when she anticipates \(\mathcal {C}\) not to compile a precise report, because her gain would be larger than her gain if she does not inspect intensively. Therefore, it is reasonable to believe that she expects

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( \varPi - B_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}\right) x_m+\left( -\varDelta +P_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}\right) x_{nm}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc} +P_{\mathcal {C}}^{b} \\&\quad \ge \left( \varPi -B_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}\right) x_m+\left( -\varDelta +P_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}\right) x_{nm}+P_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(x_{nm}\) by \(1-x_m,\) collecting the \(x_m\) terms, and replacing \(P_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}+B_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}\) by \(E, \ P_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}+B_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}\) by \(F,\ P_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}-P_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}\) by J,  and \(P_{\mathcal {C}}^{b}-P_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}\) by I gives \((E-F) x_m \le -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J\). Assumption 3.1 indicates that \(E-F > 0.\) Thus, a rational \(\mathcal {B}\) expects

$$\begin{aligned} x_m \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{E-F}. \end{aligned}$$

Assumption 3.5 states that \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc} + I > 0\), whereas Assumption 3.1 indicates that \(J > 0.\) Therefore, \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J > 0.\) In addition, \(E-F>0.\) It follows that \(\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{E-F}>0\) is a valid upper bound for \(x_m.\)

Motivation 3.7

Regardless of the strategy \(X_{\mathcal {C}}\) of \(\mathcal {C}\), \(\mathcal {B}\) acts rationally and chooses \(x_{b}=1\), when she anticipates \(\mathcal {M}\) not to manage methodically, because her gain would be larger than her gain if she does not inspect intensively. Therefore, it is reasonable to believe that she expects

$$\begin{aligned} -\varDelta +P_{\mathcal {M}}^b-\left( K_{\mathcal {B}}^c+B_C^b\right) x_c+\left( -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+P_C^b\right) x_{nc} \ge -\varDelta +P_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}-B_C^{nb}x_c+P_C^{nb}x_{nc}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(x_{nc}\) by \(1-x_c,\ P_{\mathcal {M}}^b-P_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}\) by \(J,\ P_{\mathcal {C}}^b-P_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}\) by \(I,\ P_{\mathcal {C}}^b+B_{\mathcal {C}}^{b}\) by G,  and \(P_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}+B_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}\) by H,  and collecting the terms yields \(J+I-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc} \ge (K_{\mathcal {B}}^c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+G-H)x_c.\) Assumption 3.5 indicates that \(K_{\mathcal {B}}^c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+G-H >0.\) Therefore, a rational \(\mathcal {B}\) expects \(x_c \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+G-H}\). Assumption 3.5 shows that \(K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc} < I,\) which, in turn, implies that \(I-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}>0.\) Adding J to both sides gives \(I-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+J >J.\) Assumption 3.5 confirms that \(J>0.\) Thus, \(I-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+J >0.\) As both \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J>0\) and \(K_{\mathcal {B}}^c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+G-H>0\), their ratio \(\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+G-H} > 0\) is a valid upper bound for \(x_c.\)

Appendix B

The detailed proofs of Propositions 4.1 and 4.2 are as follows.

Proof of Proposition 4.1

\(\frac{\partial U_{\mathcal {M}}}{\partial x_m}=0\) sets \(x_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F}\) as a best response of \(\mathcal {B}\). Assumption 3.3 infers that \(\frac{L-F}{E-F} \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \). \(\frac{\partial U_{\mathcal {C}}}{\partial x_c}=0\) sets \(x_m = \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H+x_b(H-G)}{K_C^{nm}-K_C^{m}}\) as a best response of \(\mathcal {M}\). Two cases arise. First, if \(\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{m}-H}{G-H} \le \frac{L-F}{E-F} \le \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H},\) the unique best response of \(\mathcal {M}\) is \(x^*_m =\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H+x_b(H-G)}{K_C^{nm}-K_C^{m}} \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \). \(\frac{\partial U_{\mathcal {B}}}{\partial x_b}=0\) sets \(x_c=\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J+(F-E)x_m}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)}\) as a best response of \(\mathcal {C}\). Moreover, the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) would remain \(x_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F}\) if \(x_c \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J+(F-E)x^{*}_m}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)}\).

  • If \( \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F} \le x_m \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{E-F},\) then \(x^*_c = \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J+(F-E)x_m}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)} \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \) is the unique best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(x^*_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F}\) is the unique best response of \(\mathcal {B}\).

  • Else, the unique best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x^*_c = \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)},\) and the unique best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x^*_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F}\).

Second, if \(\frac{L-F}{E-F} < \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{m}-H}{G-H}\) and \(x^*_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F},\) the unique best response of \(\mathcal {M}\) is \(x^*_m=\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{E-F},\) and the unique best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x^*_c=0.\) \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4.2

The best responses of the players, when \(\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H}< \frac{L-F}{E-F}\) depend on the sign of \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J,\) which is the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \(U_{\mathcal {B}}\).

\(\underline{\hbox {Case}\ -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J < 0}\)

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(x_b < \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H}\), then \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m=0\) as her unique best response. Consequently, the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) \((G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} <0\), and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=0.\) This makes \(\mathcal {B}\) change its response to \(x_b=1\) because of the strictly positive coefficient \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J\) of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}.\) The coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is equal to \(G-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm},\) which is strictly greater than zero as shown in Assumption 3.5. Thus, the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=1\). It follows that the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \(U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \(F-E-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J = B_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}+B_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}-B_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}-B_{\mathcal {C}}^{b} -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}<0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=0\). Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses.

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H}< x_b < \frac{L-F}{E-F}\), \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m=0\) as her unique best response. The coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is \((G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} >0\). Therefore, the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=1\). The best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=0\), as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \(U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J <0.\) Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses.

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(x_b \ge \frac{L-F}{E-F},\) \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \). Consequently, the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is \(( K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}- K_{\mathcal {C}}^{m})x_m+(G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} >0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=1\). As a result, the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=0\) as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \(U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \((F-E)x_m-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G <0.\) Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses.

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(x_b=\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H},\) then \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m=0\) as her unique best response. Therefore, the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is 0,  and any value of \(x_c \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \) is a possible best response. As \(\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H} > 0,\) the coefficient \((K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G)x_c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J\) of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is positive as Assumption 3.6 infers. If \(x_c < \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=1\) as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is strictly positive. Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses. Because \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J<G-H,\ \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)} < 1\). The unique possible Nash equilibrium is \(x^*_c = \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)},\ x^*_b=\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H}\) and \(x^*_m=0\).

\(\underline{\hbox {Case} \ -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J \ge 0}\)

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(x_b < \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H}\), then \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m=0\) as her unique best response. Consequently, the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is \((G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} <0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=0.\) It follows that the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=1\) as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J > 0\). However, the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is \(G-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} >0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) becomes \(x_c=1\). The coefficient of \(x_b\) in \(U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \(F-E-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G+I+J = B_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}+B_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}-B_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}-B_{\mathcal {C}}^{b} -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}<0\). Thus, the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) changes to \(x_b=0\). Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses.

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \(\frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H} \le x_b <\frac{L-F}{E-F}\), then \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m=0\) as her unique best response. It follows that the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is \((G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} \ge 0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] .\) Assumption 3.6 asserts that \(x_c \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)}.\) Therefore, the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \((K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+H-G)x_c-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J \ge 0.\) The best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] .\) If \(x_c < \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=1\) as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is strictly positive. Similarly, if \(x_b > \frac{K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}-H}{G-H},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=1\) as the coefficient of \(x_c\) in \( U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is strictly positive. Hence, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses. Because \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J \ge G-H,\ \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+I+J}{K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{nc}+(G-H)} \ge 1\). If \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J > G-H,\) there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses. On the other hand, if \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J = G-H,\) then \(x_c = 1.\) Again, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses.

  • If \(\mathcal {B}\) sets \( x_b \ge \frac{L-F}{E-F},\) then \(\mathcal {M}\) sets \(x_m \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] \). The coefficient of \(x_c\) in \(U_{\mathcal {C}}\) is therefore \(( K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm}- K_{\mathcal {C}}^{m})x_m+(G-H)x_b+H-K_{\mathcal {C}}^{nm} >0,\) and the best response of \(\mathcal {C}\) is \(x_c=1\). The coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is \((F-E)x_m-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G.\) It is positive if \(x_m \le \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F}.\) Because \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J \ge G-H,\ \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F} \ge 0\). In addition, \(\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F} \le 1,\) as \(-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G-E+F= B_{\mathcal {M}}^{nb}+B_{\mathcal {C}}^{nb}-B_{\mathcal {M}}^{b}-B_{\mathcal {C}}^{b} -K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}<0.\) If \(x_m < \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b=1\) as the coefficient of \(x_b\) in \( U_{\mathcal {B}}\) is strictly positive. The best response of \(\mathcal {M}\) is \(x_m=1.\) But, there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {M}\), \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses. If \(x_m = \frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {B}\) is \(x_b \in \left[ 0, \ 1 \right] .\) If \(x_b > \frac{L-F}{E-F},\) the best response of \(\mathcal {M}\) is \(x_m=1\) and there is no Nash equilibrium as \(\mathcal {C}\) and \(\mathcal {B}\) keep changing their best responses. Subsequently, the unique possible Nash equilibrium is \(x^*_b=\frac{L-F}{E-F},\ x^*_m =\frac{-K_{\mathcal {B}}^{c}+I+J+H-G}{E-F}\) and \(x^*_c=1\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Belhaiza, S., Charrad, S. & M’Hallah, R. On the Performance of Managers and Controllers: A Polymatrix Game Approach for the Manager–Controller–Board of Directors’ Conflict. J Optim Theory Appl 177, 584–602 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-018-1273-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-018-1273-x

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation