Skip to main content
Log in

Pricing schemes in processor sharing systems

  • Published:
Telecommunication Systems Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we study charging schemes for bandwidth or server usage under the processor sharing discipline. Specifically, we analyze post-payment and pre-payment (or payment on arrival) schemes in three charging frameworks: fixed-rate charging, Vickrey–Clarke–Groves based charging, and congestion based charging for users with logarithmic utilities. We show that in the absence of QoS constraints, the network operator can earn unbounded profits and thus there is a need to devise schemes where users are only charged if they are given a minimum rate. We obtain explicit characterizations for mean user payments and the operator’s mean revenue for these frameworks. We also analyze charge volatility via the second moments of the above implementations of arrival-based payments and post-payments. The volatility reflects the confidence in mean revenue for the operator and expected charges for a user. We present conditions under which a pre-payment mechanism is preferable over a post-payment mechanism. We also show that the same analysis can be applied to a scenario with admission control where each entering user is guaranteed a minimum service rate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Lin, M., Wierman, A., Andrew, L. L., & Thereska, E. (2011). Online dynamic capacity provisioning in data centers. In 49th Annual allerton conference on communication, control, and computing (pp. 1159–1163).

  2. Garg, S., Sundaram, S., & Patel, H. D. (2011). Robust heterogeneous data center design: A principled approach. ACM SIGMETRICS Performance Evaluation Review, 39(3), 28–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Wilson, R. W. (1997). Nonlinear pricing. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Published in association with the Electric Power Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Schassberger, R. (1984). A new approach to the \(M/G/1\) processor-sharing queue. Advances in Applied Probability, 16(1), 202–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Kelly, F. P. (1997). Charging and rate control for elastic traffic. European Transactions on Telecommunications, 8, 33–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Yaiche, H., Mazumdar, R. R., & Rosenberg, C. P. (2000). A game theoretic framework for bandwidth allocation and pricing in broadband networks. IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking, 8(5), 667–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Stefanescu, A., & Stefanescu, M. V. (1984). The arbitrated solution for multi-objective convex-programming. Revue Roumaine de Mathematiques Pures et Appliquées, 29(7), 593–598.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Mazumdar, R. R., Mason, L. G., & Douligeris, C. (1991). Fairness in network optimal flow control: Optimality of product forms. IEEE Transactions on Communications, 39(5), 775–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Baccelli, F., & Brémaud, P. (2003). Elements of queueing theory: Palm martingale calculus and stochastic recurrences (2nd ed.). New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  10. Songhurst, D. (1999). Charging communication networks: From theory to practice. Science, BV: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  11. DaSilva, L. (2000). Pricing for qos-enabled networks: A survey. IEEE on Communications Surveys Tutorials, 3(2), 2–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Kelly, F. P., Maulloo, A. K., & Tan, D. K. H. (1998). Rate control for communication networks: Shadow prices, proportional fairness and stability. Journal of Operational Research Society, 49(3), 237–252.

  13. Yang, S., & Hajek, B. (2007). VCG-Kelly mechanisms for allocation of divisible goods: Adapting VCG mechanisms to one-dimensional signals. IEEE Journal on Selected Areas in Communications, 25(6), 1237–1243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Li, T., Iraqi, Y., & Boutaba, R. (2004). Pricing and admission control for qos-enabled internet. Journal of Computer Network, Special issue on Internet Economics, 46(1), 87–100.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Guillemin, F. M., & Mazumdar, R. R. (2015). Conditional sojourn times and applications to volatility of payment schemes in bandwidth sharing networks. Journal of Applied Probability, 52.4.

  16. Birmiwal, S., Mazumdar, R. R., & Sundaram, S. (2012). Processor sharing and pricing implications. In Proceedings of 24th international teletraffic congress.

  17. Bonald, T., & Proutiere, A. (2002). Insensitivity in processor-sharing networks. Performance Evaluation, 49(1/4), 193–209.

  18. Birmiwal, S., Mazumdar, R. R., & Sundaram, S. (2012). Predictable revenue under processor sharing. In Proceedings of CISS 2012.

  19. Vickrey, W. (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. Journal of Finance, 16, 8–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Rege, K. M., & Sengupta, B. (1994). A decomposition theorem and related results for the discriminatory processor sharing queue. Queueing Systems, 18, 333–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Horn, R. A., & Johnson, C. R. (1985). Matrix analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  22. Brémaud, P. (1993). A swiss army formula of palm calculus. Journal of Applied Probability, 30, 40–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Kelly, F. P. (1979). Reversibility and stochastic networks., Wiley Series in probability and mathematical statistics Chichester: Wiley.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ravi R. Mazumdar.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

We have that \(t(0) = \chi (\vec {0}) = \Phi (\vec {0})\). For \(n \ge 1,\)

$$\begin{aligned} t(n)&:=\sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} \chi (\vec {x}) = \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} \frac{1}{C} \sum _{m=1}^K \Phi (\vec {x} - \vec {e}_m) \vec {\alpha }^{\vec {x}}\\&= \sum _{m=1}^K \rho _m \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n-1} \Phi (\vec {x}) \vec {\alpha }^{\vec {x}} = \rho \cdot t(n-1) . \end{aligned}$$

Also, \(\sum _{\vec {x} } \chi (\vec {x}) = \sum _{n=0}^\infty t(n) = \frac{\Phi (\vec {0})}{1 - \rho }.\) \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

We start with

$$\begin{aligned} s_k(n)&= \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} \frac{x_k}{C} \sum _{m=1}^K \Phi (\vec {x} - \vec {e}_m) \vec {\alpha }^{\vec {x}} \nonumber \\&= \sum _{m=1}^K \rho _m \left[ \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n-1} x_k \chi (\vec {x}) + \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n-1} (\vec {e}_m)_k \chi (\vec {x}) \right] \nonumber \\&= \sum _{m=1}^K \rho _m s_k(n-1) + \sum _{m=1}^K \rho _m \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n-1} (\vec {e}_m)_k \chi (\vec {x}) \nonumber \\&= \rho s_k(n-1) + \rho _k t(n-1) \nonumber \\&= \rho s_k(n-1) + \rho _k \rho ^{n-1} \Phi (\vec {0}) , \end{aligned}$$
(29)

where the last step follows from Lemma 1. It is easily shown that the result is a solution to the recursion in (29), starting with \(s_k(0) = 0\). The first part of the result follows. Next,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{s}_k(n) = \rho _k \Phi (\vec {0}) \sum _{m>n} m \rho ^{m-1} = \rho _k \Phi (\vec {0}) \frac{\rho ^n}{1-\rho } \left( n + \frac{1}{1-\rho } \right) . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 3

We have

$$\begin{aligned} s_{i,j}(n)&= \sum _{m=1}^K \frac{\alpha _m}{C} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}|=n} x_i x_j \Phi (\vec {x} - \vec {e}_m) \vec {\alpha }^{\vec {x} - \vec {e}_m} \\&= \sum _{m=1}^K \rho _m \sum _{\vec {y} : |\vec {y}| = n-1} (\vec {y} + \vec {e}_m)_i (\vec {y} + \vec {e}_m)_j \Phi (\vec {y}) \vec {\alpha }^{\vec {y}} \\&= \rho s_{i,j}(n-1) + \rho _j s_i(n-1) + \rho _i s_j(n-1) \\&\quad + \mathbf 1_{(i=j)} \rho _i t(n-1) . \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(s_{i,j}(0) = 0\) for any ij and that \(s_{i,j}(1)=0\) if \(i \ne j\). The expression in (9) is the solution to this recursion. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 4

$$\begin{aligned} u(n)&= \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| > n} \left( |\vec {x}| - \frac{1}{2} \right) \pi (\vec {x}) = \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| > n} |\vec {x}| \pi (\vec {x}) - \frac{1}{2} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| > n} \pi (\vec {x})\\&= \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| > n} \frac{(x_1 + \dots + x_K)\chi (\vec {x})}{\sum _{\vec {y}}\chi (\vec {y})} - \frac{1}{2} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| > n} \frac{\chi (\vec {x})}{\sum _{\vec {y}}\chi (\vec {y})} . \end{aligned}$$

Using \(\sum _{\vec {x}} \chi (\vec {x}) = \sum _{n \ge 0} t(n)\),

$$\begin{aligned} u(n) = \frac{\sum _{k=1}^K \bar{s}_k(n)}{\sum _{m \ge 0} t(m)} - \frac{\sum _{m>n} t(m)}{2\sum _{m \ge 0} t(m)} . \end{aligned}$$

Using Lemma 1 and Lemma 2, we get

$$\begin{aligned} u(n) = \rho ^{n+1} \left( n + \frac{1}{1- \rho } \right) - \frac{\rho ^{n+1}}{2} . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 1

From (14), we have

$$\begin{aligned} R_V(\vec {x})&= |\vec {x}| ( |\vec {x}|-1)\sum _{n=1}^\infty \frac{1}{n|\vec {x}|^n} \\&= (|\vec {x}|-1)\left( 1 + \frac{1}{2|\vec {x}|} + \frac{1}{3|\vec {x}|^2} + \dots \right) \\&= |\vec {x}| - \frac{1}{2} - \sum _{m=2}^{\infty } \frac{1}{m (m+1) |\vec {x}|^{m-1} } < |\vec {x}| - \frac{1}{2}, \end{aligned}$$

which shows the required result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

Let the system be in state \(\vec {x}\). The mean revenue per unit time under fixed rate charging is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_F&= \sum _{\vec {x} : 1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*} \beta C \pi (\vec {x}) = \beta C \frac{1}{\sum _{\vec {x}} \chi (\vec {x})} \sum _{\vec {x} : 1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*} \chi (\vec {x})\\&= \beta C \frac{\sum _{n=1}^{n^*} t(n)}{\sum _{n=0}^\infty t(n)} . \end{aligned}$$

Using Lemma 1,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_F = \beta C \frac{1-\rho }{\Phi (\vec {0})} \frac{\Phi (\vec {0}) (\rho - \rho ^{n^*+1})}{1 - \rho } = \beta C \rho (1 - \rho ^{n^*}) . \end{aligned}$$

The mean revenue under VCG charging is

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_V&= \sum _{\vec {x} : 2 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*} \left( |\vec {x}| - \frac{1}{2}\right) \pi (\vec {x}) = u(1) - u(n^*) , \end{aligned}$$

where u(n) is given by Lemma 4. The result for \(\bar{R}_V\) follows by simplification.

The mean revenue under congestion-based charging is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_L&= \sum _{\vec {x} : 1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*} \frac{|\vec {x}|^2}{C} \pi (\vec {x}) = \frac{1}{C} \sum _{\vec {x} : 1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*} |\vec {x}|^2 \frac{\chi (\vec {x})}{\sum _{\vec {y}}\chi (\vec {y})}\\&= \frac{1}{C} \frac{\sum _{1 \le n \le n^*} v(n)}{\sum _{n \ge 0} t(n)} . \end{aligned}$$

Using \(v(n) = n^2 t(n)\) defined in (11) and Lemma 1,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_L = \frac{1-\rho }{C} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} n^2 \rho ^n . \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

To evaluate the mean payment by a class k user under fixed rate charging, consider the following integral where \(A_k\) is the arrival process for class k users and \(W_0^k\) is the random variable denoting the sojourn time of the class k arrival at time 0:

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^F = \mathbb E_{A_k} \left[ \int _0^{W_0^k} \frac{\beta C}{|\vec {x}(t)|} \mathbf 1_{(1 \le |\vec {x}(t)| \le n^*)} dt \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Applying the Swiss Army formula (see [22]), equation (12), and Lemma 2,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^F&= \frac{\beta C}{\lambda _k} \mathbb E\left[ \frac{x_k}{|\vec {x}|} \mathbf 1_{( 1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*)} \right] = \frac{\beta C}{\lambda _k} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} \frac{x_k}{n} \pi (\vec {x}) \\&= \frac{\beta C}{\lambda _k} \frac{1}{\sum _{n=0}^\infty t(n)} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} g_k(n) = \nu _k \beta \rho (1 - \rho ^{n^*} ) . \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, for VCG charging, the mean payment for a class k user is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^V = \mathbb E_{A_k} \left[ \int _0^{W_0^k} \left( 1 -\frac{1}{2 | \vec {x}(t) |} \right) \mathbf 1_{(2 \le |\vec {x}(t)| \le n^*)} dt \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Again, using the Swiss Army formula,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^V&= \frac{1}{\lambda _k} \mathbb E\left[ x_k \left( 1 - \frac{1}{2|\vec {x}|} \right) \mathbf 1_{(2 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*)}\right] \nonumber \\&= \frac{1}{\lambda _k} \mathbb E\big [ x_k \mathbf 1_{(2 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*)}\big ] - \frac{1}{\lambda _k} \mathbb E\left[ \frac{x_k}{2|\vec {x}|} \mathbf 1_{(2 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*)} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(30)

Let \(J_1\) and \(J_2\) be the first and the second term respectively in (30). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} J_1&= \frac{1}{\lambda _k} \sum _{n=2}^{n^*} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} x_k \pi (\vec {x}) = \frac{1-\rho }{\lambda _k \Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{n=2}^{n^*} s_k(n) \\&= \frac{\nu _k(1- \rho )}{C} \sum _{n=2}^{n^*} n \rho ^{n-1}, \end{aligned}$$

and,

$$\begin{aligned} J_2&= \frac{1}{2 \lambda _k} \sum _{n=2}^{n^*} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} \frac{x_k}{|\vec {x}|} \pi (\vec {x}) = \frac{1 - \rho }{2\Phi (\vec {0}) \lambda _k} \sum _{n=2}^{n^*} g_k(n)\\&= \frac{\nu _k \rho }{2C} (1 - \rho ^{n^*-1}). \end{aligned}$$

Using the identity

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{n=1}^m n \rho ^{n-1} = \frac{1 - \rho ^{m+1} - (m+1)(1 - \rho ) \rho ^m}{(1- \rho )^2}, \end{aligned}$$

and simplifying provides the required result. For congestion-based charging, the mean payment by a class k user is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^L = \mathbb E_{A_k} \left[ \int _0^{W_0^k} \frac{|\vec {x}(t)|}{C} \mathbf 1_{( 1 \le |\vec {x}(t)| \le n^*)} dt \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Applying the Swiss Army formula gives,

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{c}_k^L&= \frac{1}{\lambda _k C} \mathbb E [ x_k |\vec {x}| \mathbf 1_{(1 \le |\vec {x}| \le n^*)}] = \frac{1}{\lambda _k C} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} \sum _{\vec {x} : |\vec {x}| = n} x_k n \pi (\vec {x}) \\&= \frac{1-\rho }{\lambda _k C \Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} n s_k(n) = \frac{\nu _k ( 1 - \rho )}{C^2} \sum _{n=1}^{n^*} n^2 \rho ^{n-1} , \end{aligned}$$

which shows the required result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 6

Suppose a class k arrival sees the system state as \(\vec {x}\) on arrival. The fixed rate, pre-payment price is

$$\begin{aligned} p_k^F(\vec {x}) = \frac{\sigma _k^F}{|\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|} \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) . \end{aligned}$$

It is required that the mean payment by a class k user equal \(\bar{c}_k^F\), i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb E[ p_k^F(\vec {x})] = \bar{c}_k^F. \end{aligned}$$
(31)

Starting with the left hand side (LHS) of (31),

$$\begin{aligned} LHS&= \sum _{\vec {x}} \frac{\sigma _k^F}{|\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|} \pi (\vec {x}) \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) \\&= \sigma _k^F (1-\rho ) \left[ \frac{A_{k,0}}{\rho } \log \frac{1}{1-\rho } + \left( \frac{ \frac{\rho }{1-\rho } - \log \frac{1}{1-\rho } }{\rho ^2} \right) \right. \\&\quad \times \left. \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} \rho _m \right] . \end{aligned}$$

Equating this to \(\bar{c}_k^F\) gives \(\sigma _k^F\). Similarly, under VCG charging,

$$\begin{aligned} p_k^V(\vec {x}) = \sigma _k^V \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) , \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb E [p_k^V(\vec {x}) ]&= \sigma _k^V \sum _{\vec {x}} \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) \pi (\vec {x}) = \sigma _k^V \mathbb E[W_k] \\&= \sigma _k^V \frac{\nu _k}{C(1 - \rho )} . \end{aligned}$$

Equating this to \(\bar{c}_k^V\) gives \(\sigma _k^V\). Last, under congestion-based charging,

$$\begin{aligned} p_k^L (\vec {x}) = \sigma _k^L |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k| \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Taking the expectation gives

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb E[p_k^L(\vec {x}) ]&= \sigma _k^L \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k| \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) \pi (\vec {x}) \\&= \frac{\sigma _k^L}{1-\rho }\left[ A_{k,0} + \frac{2}{1-\rho } \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} \rho _m \right] , \end{aligned}$$

and equating this to \(\bar{c}_k^L\) gives \(\sigma _k^L\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 7

The steps for deriving the second moment under congestion-based charging are outlined here. The proof for the other two charging models is similar.

$$\begin{aligned}&\mathbb E\big [(p_k^L (\vec {x}) )^2 \big ] = \sum _{\vec {x}} (p_k^L(\vec {x}))^2 \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad = (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 \left( A_{k,0} + \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \right) ^2 \\&\qquad \times \,\pi (\vec {x}) (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 A_{k,0}^2 \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad \quad + (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m}^2 x_m^2 \pi (\vec {x}) + (\sigma _k^L)^2 2 \\&\quad \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 A_{k,0} \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad + (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 \sum _{i=1}^K \sum _{j=1 : j \ne i}^K A_{k,i} A_{k,j} x_i x_j \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad := S_1 + S_2 + S_3 + S_4\\ \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned}&S_1 = (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 A_{k,0}^2 \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad = \frac{(\sigma _k^L)^2 A_{k,0}^2 (1-\rho )}{\Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{\vec {x}} (|\vec {x}|+1)^2 \chi (\vec {x})\\&\quad = \frac{(\sigma _k^L)^2 A_{k,0}^2 (1+\rho )}{(1-\rho )^2} . \\&S_2 = (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m}^2 x_m^2 \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad = \frac{(\sigma _k^L)^2 (1-\rho )}{\Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m}^2 \sum _{n=0}^\infty (n+1)^2 s_{m,m}(n) \\&\quad = 2 (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m}^2 \frac{\rho _m(2 + 9\rho _m + 3 \rho _m \rho - \rho - \rho ^2)}{(1-\rho )^4} . \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned}&S_3 = (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 2 A_{k,0} \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} x_m \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad = \frac{2 A_{k,0} (\sigma _k^L)^2 (1-\rho )}{\Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} \sum _{n=0}^\infty (n^2+2n+1) s_m(n) \\&\quad = 2 A_{k,0} (\sigma _k^L)^2 \frac{(2\rho +4)}{(1-\rho )^3} \sum _{m=1}^K A_{k,m} \rho _m .\\&S_4 = (\sigma _k^L)^2 \sum _{\vec {x}} |\vec {x} + \vec {e}_k|^2 \sum _{i=1}^K \sum _{j=1 : j \ne i}^K A_{k,i} A_{k,j} x_i x_j \pi (\vec {x}) \\&\quad = \frac{(\sigma _k^L)^2 (1-\rho )}{\Phi (\vec {0})} \sum _{i=1}^K \sum _{j=1 : j \ne i}^K A_{k,i} A_{k,j} \sum _{n=0}^\infty (n+1)^2 s_{i,j}(n) \\&\quad = \frac{6 (\sigma _k^L)^2 (3+\rho )}{(1-\rho )^4} \sum _{i=1}^K \sum _{j=1 : j \ne i}^K A_{k,i} A_{k,j} \rho _i \rho _j . \end{aligned}$$

Combining \(S_1, S_2, S_3\) and \(S_4\) gives the result. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 8

Let \(\hat{\pi }(\vec {x})\) be the stationary distribution of the system under admission control. Noting that the underlying process is a truncation of a reversible process (see [23, Corollary 1.10]), the stationary distribution is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\pi }(\vec {x}) = \pi (\vec {x}) \frac{\sum _{\vec {y}} \pi (\vec {y})}{\sum _{\vec {y} : |\vec {y}| \le n^*} \pi (\vec {y}) } = \pi (\vec {x}) \left( \frac{1}{1-\rho ^{n^*+1}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

The mean revenue is calculated as in Proposition 2 under \(\hat{\pi }(\vec {x})\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 9

Let \(\hat{A}_k\) be the arrival process of class k users. Note that \(\hat{A}_k\) is Poisson distributed for \(|\vec {x}| < n^*\) and there is no new arrival if \(|\vec {x}| = n^*\). The mean payment under the admission control system is

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{c}_k^{(\cdot )} = \mathbb E_{\hat{A}_k} \left[ \int _0^{W_k} c_k^{(\cdot )}(\vec {x}(t)) dt \right] = \frac{1}{\hat{\lambda }_k} \mathbb E \left[ x_k c_k^{(\cdot )} (\vec {x}) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

The second expectation above is under \(\hat{\pi }\) instead of \(\pi \) in Proposition 3 and the stochastic intensity \(\hat{\lambda }_k\) of \(\hat{A}_k\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\lambda }_k = \sum _{n=0}^{n^*-1} \lambda _k \pi (|\vec {x}| = n) = \lambda _k \left( \frac{1-\rho ^{n^*}}{1-\rho ^{n^*+1}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the mean payment under admission control is

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{c}_k^{(\cdot )} = \frac{1-\rho ^{n^*+1}}{1-\rho ^{n^*}} \frac{1}{1-\rho ^{n^*+1}} \bar{c}_k^{(\cdot )}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 10

Let \(P_k^F(\vec {x})\) be the random variable denoting the mean payment made by a given class k user when the state is \(\vec {x}\). Let \(Y(\vec {x})\) be the random variable indicating the payment made by this user in state \(\vec {x}\) until the next event (arrival of a new user or departure of an existing user) occurs. Then,

$$\begin{aligned} P_k^F(\vec {x})&= \mathbf 1_{(\text {next event = arrival})} \sum _{m=1}^K \big [Y(\vec {x}) + P_k^F(\vec {x}+\vec {e}_m)\big ] \\&\quad + \,\mathbf 1_{(\text {next event = other user's departure})}\\&\quad \times \sum _{m=1}^K \big [Y(\vec {x}) + P_k^F(\vec {x} - \vec {e}_m)\big ] \\&\quad +\, \mathbf 1_{(\text {next event = tagged user's departure})} Y(\vec {x}) \\&\quad \text { for } |\vec {x}| < n^*. \end{aligned}$$

With a slight abuse of notation, let \(Y(p; \vec {x})\) and \(P_k^F(p; \vec {x})\) respectively denote the probability density function of \(Y(\vec {x})\) and \(P_k^F(\vec {x})\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} Y(p; \vec {x}) = \hat{\omega }(\vec {x}) \frac{|\vec {x}|}{\beta C} e^{- \hat{\omega }(\vec {x}) \frac{|\vec {x}|}{\beta C} p}, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} P_k^F(p; \vec {x})&= \sum _{m=1}^K \frac{\lambda _m}{\hat{\omega }(\vec {x})} \int _0^p Y(q; \vec {x}) P_k^F(p-q; \vec {x}+\vec {e}_m) dq \\&\quad + \sum _{m=1}^K \frac{(\vec {x} - \vec {e}_k)_m C}{|\vec {x}| \nu _m \hat{\omega }(\vec {x})} \int _0^p Y(q; \vec {x}) P_k^F\\&\quad \times (p-q; \vec {x} - \vec {e}_m) dq \\&\quad + \frac{C}{|\vec {x}| \nu _k \hat{\omega }(\vec {x})} Y(p; \vec {x}) , \quad \text { for } |\vec {x}| < n^*. \end{aligned}$$

Let \(P_k^F(s; \vec {x})\) be the Laplace–Stieltjis Transform (LST) of \(P_k^F(p; \vec {x})\). Then, taking the LST of the above gives

$$\begin{aligned} \beta C P_k^F(s; \vec {x})&= \frac{1}{s + \frac{\hat{\omega }(\vec {x}) |\vec {x}|}{\beta C} } \left[ \sum _{m=1}^K \lambda _m(\vec {x}) P(s; \vec {x} + \vec {e}_m) \right. \\&\left. \quad + \sum _{m=1}^K \frac{(\vec {x} - \vec {e}_k)_m C}{\nu _m} P(s; \vec {x} - \vec {e}_m) + \frac{C}{\nu _k} \right] , \end{aligned}$$

for \(|\vec {x}| < n^*\). Taking the derivative of the above once and twice and using

$$\begin{aligned}&\left. P_k^F(s; \vec {x}) \right| _{s=0} = 1, \left. -\left( P_k^F\right) '(s; \vec {x}) \right| _{s=0} = \eta _k^F(\vec {x}), \text { and }\\&\left. \left( P_k^F\right) ''(s; \vec {x})\right| _{s=0} = \xi _k^F(\vec {x}), \end{aligned}$$

gives (27) and (28). To obtain the second moment of payments by class k users, \(\mathbb E [\xi _k^F(\vec {x})]\) is evaluated. Note that the state before arrival is \((\vec {x} - \vec {e}_k)\) when a payment of \(P_k^F(\vec {x})\) is made.

For \(|\vec {x}| = n^*\), the equations are similar except for \(\lambda _m = 0\) since no arrivals take place in this state. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Birmiwal, S., Mazumdar, R.R. & Sundaram, S. Pricing schemes in processor sharing systems. Telecommun Syst 63, 421–435 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11235-015-0132-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11235-015-0132-4

Keywords

Navigation