Skip to main content
Log in

Intergroup Cooperation in Common Pool Resource Dilemmas

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Science and Engineering Ethics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Fundamental problems of environmental sustainability, including climate change and fisheries management, require collective action on a scale that transcends the political and cultural boundaries of the nation-state. Rational, self-interested neoclassical economic theories of human behavior predict tragedy in the absence of third party enforcement of agreements and practical difficulties that prevent privatization. Evolutionary biology offers a theory of cooperation, but more often than not in a context of discrimination against other groups. That is, in-group boundaries are necessarily defined by those excluded as members of out-groups. However, in some settings human’s exhibit behavior that is inconsistent with both rational economic and group driven cooperation of evolutionary biological theory. This paper reports the results of a non-cooperative game-theoretic exercise that models a tragedy of the commons problem in which groups of players may advance their own positions only at the expense of other groups. Students enrolled from multiple universities and assigned to different multi-university identity groups participated in experiments that repeatedly resulted in cooperative outcomes despite intergroup conflicts and expressions of group identity. We offer three possible explanations: (1) students were cooperative because they were in an academic setting; (2) students may have viewed their instructors as the out-group; or (3) the emergence of a small number of influential, ethical leaders is sufficient to ensure cooperation amongst the larger groups. From our data and analysis, we draw out lessons that may help to inform approaches for institutional design and policy negotiations, particularly in climate change management.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “Non-cooperative” is a technical term in game theory, which means that players make choices independently and any cooperation or contracts must be self enforcing (as opposed to enforced by a third-party).

  2. For evidence in animals and humans see Wilson (2004, 2012a, b). For plants see Bhatt et al. (2011), Biernaskie (2011), Dudley and File (2007), Murphy and Dudley (2009). For amoebas and bacteria see Cremer et al. (2012), Gilbert et al. (2007), Mehdiabadi et al. (2006), Ostrowski (2008), Rainey and Rainey (2003).

  3. Evidence for parochial altruism comes from studies involving: people playing various economic games with each other (Abbink et al. 2011; Bernhard et al. 2006; De Dreu et al. 2010, 2011; Ruffle and Sosis 2006); agent-based modeling (Choi and Bowles 2007); and evolutionary theory (Boehm 2012; Bowles 2006, 2012; Putterman 2010; Ruse 1993, 2009).

  4. In both studies, the game took place in the context of a university course module centered on sustainability ethics and Tragedy of the Commons. While the participants in each study were different, the relative homogeneity across participants in terms of age and life-style is a limitation in these types of studies. Information about the framing of the course and the reading material that preceded the game can be found in: Sadowski et al. (2013); an instructor’s guide uploaded to a digital repository found here: http://hdl.handle.net/2286/1oejg1ves5e; and in a blog post found here: http://sustainabilityethics.com/2012/09/25/ted-talks-on-morality/.

  5. Individual rationality leading to group irrationality is a characteristic of almost all collective action problems. Hardin (1968) describes this type of behavior in Tragedy of the Commons dilemmas. Whereas, Ostrom (1990), Ostrom et al. (1999) explains how common-pool resources can be successfully managed through collective action (i.e. group rationality).

  6. Zodiac birth dates are based on the Earth’s position in its orbit around the Sun. There are twelve sets of birth dates, one for each of the 30° sectors in the orbit. Each set of birth dates is named for a constellation that appears in the night sky during that time period (e.g. Aries, Taurus, Capricorn, etc.).

  7. Coincidentally, a recent paper describes what the authors call “The Joker Effect” (a name that was also inspired by The Dark Knight). They used modeling to demonstrate that a destructive or “evil agent” can actually enhance cooperation between other agents (Arenas et al. 2001). It appears that the events of the present game paralleled the Joker Effect.

References

  • Abbink, K., Brandts, J., Herrmann, B., & Orzen, H. (2011). Parochial altruism in intergroup conflicts. Economic Letters, 117, 45–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allenby, B. (2006). Macroethical systems and sustainability science. Sustainability Science, 1, 7–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arenas, A., Camacho, J., Cuesta, J., & Requejo, R. (2001). The Joker effect: Cooperation driven by destructive agents. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 279, 113–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnhart, L. (1998). Darwinian natural right: The biological ethics of human nature. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R., & Dion, D. (1988). The further evolution of cooperation. Science, 242, 1385–1390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 211, 1390–1396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R., Riolo, R., & Cohen, M. (2002). Beyond geography: Cooperation with persistent links in the absence of clustered neighborhoods. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 6(4), 341–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnosky, A. D., et al. (2012). Approaching a state shift in the earth’s biosphere. Nature, 486, 52–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2011). Avoiding disastrous climate change is possible but not inevitable. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science of the United States of America, 108, 11733–11734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernhard, H., Fischbacher, U., & Fehr, E. (2006). Parochial altruism in humans. Nature, 442, 912–915.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatt, M. V., Khandelwal, A., & Dudley, S. A. (2011). Kin recognition, not competitive interactions, predicts root allocation in young Cakile Edentula seedling pairs. New Phytologist, 189, 1135–1142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biernaskie, J. M. (2011). Evidence for competition and cooperation among climbing plants. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 278(1714), 1989–1996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boehm, C. (2012). Moral origins: The evolution of virtue, altruism, and shame. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. American Economic Review, 90(1), 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bornstein, G. (2003). Intergroup conflict: Individual, group and collective interests. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 7, 129–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2006). Group competition, reproductive leveling, and the evolution of human altruism. Science, 314, 1569–1572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (2012). Warriors, levelers, and the role of conflict in human social evolution. Science, 336, 848–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, R. (1985). Social psychology (2nd ed.). New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M. E., & Trevino, L. K. (2006). Ethical leadership: A review and future directions. The Leadership Quarterly, 17, 595–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M. E., Trevino, L. K., & Harrison, D. A. (2005). Ethical leadership: A social learning perspective for construct development and testing. Organizational Behavior and Human Decisions Processes, 97, 117–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burns, J. M. (1979). Leadership. New York: Harper Perennial.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canary, D. J., & Seibold, D. R. (2010). Origins and development of the conversational argument coding scheme. Communication Methods and Measures, 4, 7–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J. C. (2003). Real wealth and experimental cooperation: Experiments in the field lab. Journal of Development Economics, 70(2), 263–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J., & Cardenas, J. C. (2011). An intercultural examination of cooperation in the commons. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(4), 632–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J.-K., & Bowles, S. (2007). The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science, 318, 636–640.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collins, H. (2010). Tacit and explicit knowledge. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cremer, J., Melbinger, A., & Frey, E. (2012). Growth dynamics and the evolution of cooperation in microbial populations. Scientific Reports, 2(281), 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Darwin, C. (1871). The descent of man. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Dreu, C. K. W., Greer, L. L., Van Kleef, G. A., Shalvi, S., & Handgraaf, M. J. J. (2011). Oxytocin promotes human ethnocentrism. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science of the United States of America, 108, 1262–1266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Dreu, C. K. W., et al. (2010). The neuropeptide oxytocin regulates parochial altruism in intergroup conflict among humans. Science, 328, 1408–1411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dietz, T., Ostrom, E., & Stern, P. C. (2003). The struggle to govern the commons. Science, 302, 1907–1912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dudley, S. A., & File, A. (2007). Kin recognition in an annual plant. Biology Letters, 3, 435–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellemers, N. (2012). The group self. Science, 336, 876–879.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). On the nature of fair behavior. Economic Inquiry, 41(1), 20–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gachter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90(4), 980–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gachter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature, 415, 137–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, O. M., et al. (2007). High relatedness maintains multicellular cooperation in a social amoeba by controlling cheater mutants. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science of the United States of America, 104(21), 8913–8917.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gino, F., & Galinsky, A. D. (2012). Vicarious dishonesty: When psychological closeness creates distance from one’s moral compass. Organizational Behavior and Human Decisions Processes, 119(1), 15–26.

  • Gladwell, M. (2000). The tipping point: How little things can make a big difference. New York: Back Bay Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gowdy, J. M. (2008). Behavioral economics and climate change policy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68, 632–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannah, S. T., Avolio, B. J., & Walumbwa, F. O. (2011). Relationship between authentic leadership, moral courage, ethical and pro-social behaviors. Business Ethics Quarterly, 21(4), 555–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamieson, D. (2010). Climate change, responsibility, and justice. Science and Engineering Ethics, 16(3), 431–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, R. (2007). Global warming is changing the world. Science, 316, 188–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lester, P. B., Vogelgesang, G., Hannah, S. T., & Kimmey, T. (2009). Developing courage in followers: Theoretical and applied perspectives. In C. Pury & S. Lopez (Eds.), The psychology of courage: Modern research on an ancient virtue. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine, D. K. (1998). Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Review of Economic Dynamics, 1(3), 593–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marowitz, E. M., & Shariff, A. F. (2012). Climate change and moral judgement. Nature Climate Change, 2, 243–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, D. M., Kuenzi, M., Greenbaum, R., Bardes, M., & Salvador, R. (2009). How low does ethical leadership flow? Test of the trickle-down model. Organizational Behavior and Human Decisions Processes, 108, 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehdiabadi, N. J., et al. (2006). Social evolution: Kin preference in a social microbe. Nature, 442, 881–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H. J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature, 415, 424–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Krambeck, H.-J., & Marotzke, J. (2008). The collective-risk social dilemma and the prevention of simulated dangerous climate change. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 105, 2291–2294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., et al. (2006). Stabilizing the earth’s climate is not a losing game: Supporting evidence from public goods experiments. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 103, 3994–3998.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, G. P., & Dudley, S. A. (2009). Kin recognition: Competition and cooperation in impatiens (Balsaminaceae). American Journal of Botany, 96(11), 1990–1996.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nash, J. (1951). Non-cooperative games. The Annals of Mathematics, 54(2), 286–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newman, M. E. J. (2005). Power laws, Pareto distributions, and Zipf’s law. Contemporary Physics, 46, 323–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2006). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314, 1560–1563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2012). Evolving cooperation. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 299, 1–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups (Revised Ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010a). A multi-scale approach to coping with climate change and other collective action problems. Solutions, 1(2), 27–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010b). Analyzing collective action. Agricultural Economics, 41, 155–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Burger, J., Field, C. B., Norgaard, R. B., & Policansky, D. (1999). Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science, 284, 278–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrowski, E. A. (2008). Kin discrimination increases with genetic distance in a social amoeba. PLoS Biology, 6(11), e287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (2010). Cooperation and punishment. Science, 328, 578–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rainey, P. B., & Rainey, K. (2003). Evolution of cooperation and conflict in experimental bacterial populations. Nature, 425, 72–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruffle, B. J., & Sosis, R. (2006). Cooperation and the in-group-out-group bias: A field test on Israeli kibbutz members and city residents. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60, 147–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruse, M. (1993). The significance of evolution. In P. Singer (Ed.), A companion to ethics. Wiley: Malden, MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruse, M. (2009). Charles Darwin on human evolution. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71, 10–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sadowski, J. (2011). Experimental analysis of the gap between moral beliefs and moral actions. B.S. thesis, Rochester Institute of Technology, USA.

  • Sadowski, J., Seager, T. P., Selinger, E., Spierre, S. G., & Whyte, K. P. (2013). An experiential, game-theoretic pedagogy for sustainability ethics. Science and Engineering Ethics, 19(3), 1323–1339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sadowski, J., Selinger, E., & Seager, T. P. (2012). Climate change and intergroup cooperation. Evolution: This View of Life. Retrieved on July 25, 2012, from http://www.thisviewoflife.com/index.php/magazine/articles/climate-change-and-inter-group-cooperation.

  • Schmidtz, D. (2006). The elements of justice. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Seager, T. P., Selinger, E., & Spierre, S. G. (2011). Determining moral responsibility for CO2 emissions: A reply to Nolt. Ethics, Policy and Environment, 14(1), 39–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seager, T. P., Selinger, E., Whiddon, D., Schwartz, D., Spierre, S., & Berardy, A. (2010). Debunking the fallacy of the individual decision-maker: An experiential pedagogy of sustainability ethics. In Proceedings of the 2010 IEEE international symposium on sustainable systems and technology, Washington DC, May 16–18.

  • Seager, T. P., Selinger, E., & Wiek, A. (2012). Sustainable engineering science for resolving wicked problems. Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics, 25(4), 467–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seibold, D. R., & Meyers, R. A. (2007). Group argument: A structuration perspective and research program. Small Group Research, 38, 312–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shankar, A., & Pavitt, C. (2002). Resource and public goods dilemmas: A new issue for communication research. Review of Communication, 2(3), 251–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shirky, C. (2008). Here comes everybody: The power of organizing without organizations. New York: Penguin Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. (2005). Interdependent preferences and reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(2), 392–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spierre, S., Seager, T. P., Selinger, E., & Sadowski, J. (2011). Using non-cooperative games to simulate ethical tensions in climate policy negotiations. In Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE international symposium on sustainable systems and technology, Chicago, IL, May 16–18.

  • Spierre, S. G., et al. (2012). An experiential pedagogy for sustainability ethics. In American Society of Engineering education annual conference, San Antonio TX, June 10–13.

  • Stockholm Resilience. (2009). Sustainable development and the tragedy of commons. Retrieved June 21, 2012, from http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ByXM47Ri1Kc.

  • Tavoni, A., Dannenberg, A., Kallis, G., & Löschel, A. (2011). Inequality, communication, and the avoidance of disastrous climate change in a public goods game. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 108, 11825–11829.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, P. B. (2010). Sustainability as resource sufficiency, functional integrity and social stability. In R. Raffaelle, W. Robison, & E. Selinger (Eds.), Sustainability ethics: 5 questions. Birkerød, Denmark: Automatic Press/VIP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velez, M. A., Stranlund, J. K., & Murphy, J. J. (2009). What motivates common pool resource users? Experimental evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70(3), 485–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walker, L. J., & Henning, K. H. (2004). Differing conceptions of moral exemplarity: Just, brave, and caring. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 86, 629–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, S. (2005). Cooperation costs, governance choice, and alliance evolution. Journal of Management Studies, 42(7), 1383–1412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (2004). On human nature (Revised Ed.). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Wilson, D. S. (2011). The neighborhood project: Using evolution to improve my city, one block at a time. New York: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (2012a). Biologist E.O. Wilson on why humans, like ants, need a tribe. Newsweek Magazine. Retrieved April 30, 2012, from http://www.thedailybeast.com/newsweek/2012/04/01/biologist-e-o-wilson-on-why-humans-like-ants-need-a-tribe.html.

  • Wilson, E. O. (2012b). The social conquest of earth. New York: Liveright.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S., & Gowdy, J. (2013). Evolution as a general theoretical framework for economics and public policy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 90(suppl), S3–S10.

  • Wilson, D. S., Ostrom, E., & Cox, M. E. (2012). Generlizing the core design principles for the efficacy of groups. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 90(suppl), S21–S32.

  • Wilson, D. S., & Wilson, E. O. (2007). Rethinking the theoretical foundation of sociobiology. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 82(4), 327–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P. J. (2012). The moral molecule: The source of love and prosperity. New York: Dutton Adult.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimbardo, P. (2007). The Lucifer effect: Understanding how good people turn evil. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This material is based upon work supported by the National Science Foundation under Grant No. 1134943. The Global Institute for Sustainability at ASU also provided support. We thank Shirley Augustin for coding the data for Fig. 1 and Albert Stanton for research assistance. Two anonymous reviewers provided comments that strengthened the whole article. We’re indebted to David S. Wilson for invaluable feedback on this manuscript as well as to an editor at the magazine Evolution: This View of Life who provided comments on a previous article that explored similar themes. For fruitful conversation we thank: Kyle P. Whyte, Ben Hale, Robb Eason, Larry Nies, Bill Guschwan, Bert Cohen, Jay Banna, Scott McClintock, and Nicholas Hohman.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jathan Sadowski.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sadowski, J., Spierre, S.G., Selinger, E. et al. Intergroup Cooperation in Common Pool Resource Dilemmas. Sci Eng Ethics 21, 1197–1215 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11948-014-9575-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11948-014-9575-3

Keywords

Navigation