Skip to main content
Log in

Cooperative Advertising in a Dynamic Retail Market Oligopoly

  • Published:
Dynamic Games and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Cooperative advertising is a key incentive offered by a manufacturer to influence retailers’ promotional decisions. We study cooperative advertising in a dynamic retail oligopoly where a manufacturer sells his product through N competing retailers. We model the problem as a Stackelberg differential game in which the manufacturer announces his shares of advertising costs of the N retailers or his subsidy rates, and the retailers in response play a Nash differential game in choosing their optimal advertising efforts over time. We obtain the feedback equilibrium solution consisting of the optimal advertising policies of the retailers and manufacturer’s subsidy rates. We identify key drivers that influence the optimal subsidy rates and, in particular, obtain the conditions under which the manufacturer will not support the retailers. For the special case of two retailers we obtain insights on some key supply chain issues. First, we analyze its impact on profits of channel members and the extent to which it can coordinate the channel. Second, we investigate the case of an anti-discrimination act which restricts the manufacturer to offer equal subsidy rates to the two retailers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Basar T, Bensoussan A, Sethi SP (2010) Differential games with mixed leadership: the open-loop solution. Appl Math Comput 217(3):972–979

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Bensoussan A, Chen S, Sethi SP (2012, forthcoming) Linear-quadratic differential games with mixed leadership: the open-loop solution. Numer Algebra Control Optim. Special issue in honor of professor George Leitmann

  3. Berger PD (1972) Vertical cooperative advertising ventures. J Mark Res 9(3):309–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Chintagunta PK, Jain DC (1992) A dynamic model of channel member strategies for marketing expenditures. Mark Sci 11(2):168–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Chintagunta PK, Jain DC (1995) Empirical analysis of a dynamic duopoly model of competition. J Econ Manag Strategy 4(1):109–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Chutani A, Sethi SP (2012) Optimal advertising and pricing in a dynamic durable goods supply chain. J Optim Theory Appl 154(2):615–643

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  7. Dant RP, Berger PD (1996) Modeling cooperative advertising decisions in franchising. J Oper Res Soc 47(9):1120–1136

    Google Scholar 

  8. Deal KR (1979) Optimizing advertising expenditures in a dynamic duopoly. Oper Res 27:682–692

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Dutta S, Bergen M, John G, Rao A (1995) Variations in the contractual terms of cooperative advertising contracts: an empirical investigation. Mark Lett 6(1):15–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Erickson GM (2009) An oligopoly model of advertising competition. Eur J Oper Res 197(1):374–388

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Erickson GM (2009) Advertising competition in a dynamic oligopoly with multiple brands. Oper Res 57(5):1106–1113

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. He X, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2009) Cooperative advertising and pricing in a dynamic stochastic supply chain: feedback Stackelberg strategies. Prod Oper Manag 18(1):78–94

    Google Scholar 

  13. He X, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2011) Retail competition and cooperative advertising. Oper Res Lett 39(1):11–16

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. He X, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2012) Co-op advertising in dynamic retail oligopolies. Decis Sci 43(1):73–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Huang Z, Li SX, Mahajan V (2002) An analysis of manufacturer–retailer supply chain coordination in cooperative advertising. Decis Sci 33(3):469–494

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Jørgensen S, Sigué SP, Zaccour G (2000) Dynamic cooperative advertising in a channel. J Retail 76(1):71–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Jørgensen S, Taboubi S, Zaccour G (2001) Cooperative advertising in a marketing channel. J Optim Theory Appl 110(1):145–158

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  18. Jørgensen S, Taboubi S, Zaccour G (2003) Retail promotions with negative brand image effects: is cooperation possible? Eur J Oper Res 150(2):395–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Kali R (1998) Minimum advertised price. J Econ Manag Strategy 7(4):647–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Karray S, Zaccour G (2005) A differential game of advertising for national brand and store brands. In: Haurie A, Zaccour G (eds) Dynamic games: theory and applications. Springer, Berlin, pp 213–229

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  21. Nagler MG (2006) An exploratory analysis of the determinants of cooperative advertising participation rates. Mark Lett 17(2):91–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Naik PA, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2008) Building brand awareness in dynamic oligopoly markets. Manag Sci 54(1):129–138

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  23. Nerlove M, Arrow KJ (1962) Optimal advertising policy under dynamic conditions. Economica 29:129–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Prasad A, Sethi SP (2004) Competitive advertising under uncertainty: a stochastic differential game approach. J Optim Theory Appl 123(1):163–185

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  25. Prasad A, Sethi SP (2009) Integrated marketing communications in markets with uncertainty and competition. Automatica 45(3):601–610

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  26. Sethi SP (1983) Deterministic and stochastic optimization of a dynamic advertising model. Optim Control Appl Methods 4(2):179–184

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  27. Sorger G (1989) Competitive dynamic advertising, a modification of the case game. J Econ Dyn Control 13:55–80

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  28. Vidale ML, Wolfe HB (1957) An operations research study of sales response to advertising. Oper Res 5(3):370–381

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anshuman Chutani.

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivation of P i ,i=1,2,…,N, for N Identical Retailers

For N identical retailers, with \(\theta^{*}_{i} = 0, \forall i = 1, 2,\ldots, N\), by subtracting (17) from (16), we get \(\gamma_{ij} = \beta_{i} - \frac{m}{(r+\delta)}, i = 1, 2, \ldots, N, j = i = 1, 2, \ldots, N, j \neq i\). Since the retailers are identical, it is not surprising that γ ij is same for all j’s, where i=1,2,…,N,j=i=1,2,…,N,ji. Using this relation in (16), we can rewrite (16) as

$$ 4(r+\delta) \beta_i = 4m - \rho^2 \beta^2_i - 2\rho^2 \sum_{k\neq i}{\beta_k \biggl[\beta_i - \frac{m}{(r+\delta)} \biggr]}, \quad i = 1, 2,\ldots, N. $$

From the above equation we can say that β 1=β 2=⋯=β N =β, which is intuitive as the retailers are identical. With this we get a quadratic equation in β which gives two roots, one negative and one positive. Clearly it makes sense to have the value function of retailer i, i.e., V i (X), increase with his own market share x i . Therefore, we expect β i =∂V i (X)/∂x i >0. Thus, we ignore the negative root and get for i=1,2,…N,

$$ \beta_i = \beta= \frac{(n-1)m\rho^2 - 2(r+\delta)^2 + \sqrt {4(r+\delta)^4 + 4nm\rho^2(r+\delta)^2 + (n-1)^4m^2\rho^4}}{(2n-1)\rho^2(r+\delta)^2}. $$
(43)

Using (43) in (19) we solve for B i ,i=1,2,…N, and then using (21) we get (22).

Appendix B: Uniqueness of Optimal Solution in the Case of Two Symmetric Retailers

The uniqueness of an optimal solution to the problem defined by (6), (7), (9)–(11) is guaranteed by a unique solution of the system of equations (15)–(20). It appears to be difficult to prove the uniqueness in the general case. However, in the special case of symmetric retailers (M 1=M 2=M,m 1=m 2=m,δ 1=δ 2=δ and ρ 1=ρ 2), we can establish the result as follows.

We first look at the signs of α i ,β i and γ i ,i=1,2. It is expected that β i >0. Now consider γ i , which can be expressed in terms of β 1 and β 2 by using Eq. (17):

$$\gamma_i = \frac{\beta_i^2(-1+\theta^*_{3-i})\rho_i^2}{2(-1+\theta^*_i)((r+\delta_{3-i})(-1+\theta^*_{3-i}) - \beta_{3-i} \rho_{3-i}^2)}, \quad i = 1,2. $$

Since β i >0 and \(\theta^{*}_{i} < 1, i = 1,2\), we have \(\gamma_{i} = V_{ix_{3-i}} < 0\), as intuition would suggest on account of the competition between the retailers. We can also use (16) and (17) to write

$$ \gamma_i = \frac{-m_i + \beta_i(r+\delta_i)}{(r+\delta_{3-i})}. $$
(44)

Since γ i <0, we must have

$$ \beta_i < \frac{m_i}{(r+\delta_i)}. $$
(45)

Now consider α i , which is retailer i’s value function when the initial market is zero for both retailers. We now show that this value is positive. By adding (15) and (17), we can conclude that α i =−γ i (r+δ 3−i )/r, which is positive since γ i <0. Thus,

$$ \alpha_i = \frac{m_i - \beta_i(r+\delta_i)}{r} > 0. $$
(46)

Moreover, using (44) in Eq. (15), we can write α i in terms of β 1 and β 2, and then rewrite (46) as

$$ \alpha_i = \frac{1}{4r} \biggl[\frac{2\beta_{3-i}(m_i-\beta_i(r+\delta_i))\rho_{3-i}^2}{(r+\delta_{3-i})(-1+\theta_{3-i})} - \frac{\beta_i^2\rho_i^2}{(-1+\theta_i)} \biggr] > 0, \quad i = 1, 2. $$
(47)

Clearly, in the symmetric case, we will have α 1=α 2=α,β 1=β 2=β, γ 1=γ 2=γ, B 1=B 2=B, and hence \(\theta^{*}_{1} = \theta^{*}_{2} = \theta^{*}\). We can thus rewrite (47) as

$$\frac{\beta(2m-3\beta(r+\delta))\rho^2}{2r(r+\delta)(-1+\theta)} > 0. $$

This, along with β>0 and θ<1, gives us

$$ \beta> \frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}. $$
(48)

From (45) and (48), we have

$$ \frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)} < \beta< \frac{m}{(r+\delta)}. $$
(49)

To prove a unique solution to Eqs. (15)–(20), we reduce them into one equation of a single variable β, and then aim for the unique solution of β. We will separately consider the cases of a cooperative equilibrium where θ >0 and a non-cooperative equilibrium where θ =0.

Case I: Cooperative equilibrium (θ >0)

Since β 1=β 2=β and B 1=B 2=B in the symmetric case, (20) reduces to θ =(2Bβ)/(2B+β). Using this, (44), and (46), we can reduce Eqs. (15)–(20) to two equations in variables β and B, i.e.,

(50)
(51)

Using (50), (51) and (14) in (21) and setting P 1=P 2=P on account of the case being symmetric, we obtain the participation threshold function

$$ P = 2B - \beta= \frac{8(r+\delta)(-m+2M+(\beta-2B)\delta) - (\beta +2B)(2m-(\beta-4B)(r+\delta))\rho^2}{8r(r+\delta)}. $$
(52)

Using (50), we can write B in terms of β as follows:

$$ B = \frac{-2m(4(r+\delta)+\beta\rho^2) + \beta(r+\delta)(8(r+\delta)+3\beta\rho^2)}{2(2m-3\beta(r+\delta ))\rho^2}. $$
(53)

Now using (52) and (53), we can rewrite P in terms of β only, and then write the condition of the cooperative equilibrium as

$$ P = \frac{-4m((r+\delta)^2+\beta\rho^2) + 2\beta(r+\delta)(4(r+\delta)+3\beta\rho^2)}{(2m-3\beta(r+\delta ))\rho^2} > 0. $$
(54)

Next, we find the values of β for which the inequality in (54) holds. In order to see how P varies with β, we first find the roots of the equation P=0. The numerator is quadratic in β with the roots denoted as η 1 and η 2:

Clearly, η 1>0 and η 2<0. Also, the denominator (2m−3β(r+δ))ρ 2 of (54) changes sign at β=2m/3(r+δ); the denominator is strictly positive when β<2m/3(r+δ) and strictly negative when β>2m/3(r+δ).

We will now compare the value of η 1 with m/(r+δ) and 2m/3(r+δ). We can see that the difference

$$\eta_1 - \frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)} = \frac{-2(r+\delta)^2 - m\rho^2 + \sqrt{4(r+\delta)^4 + 8m(r+\delta)^2\rho^2 + m^2\rho^4}}{3(r+\delta)\rho^2} > 0, $$

and thus η 1>2m/3(r+δ). Furthermore,

$$\eta_1 - \frac{m}{(r+\delta)} = \frac{-2(r+\delta)^2 - 2m\rho^2 + \sqrt{4(r+\delta)^4 + 8m(r+\delta)^2\rho^2 + m^2\rho^4}}{3(r+\delta)\rho^2} < 0, $$

and thus we have

$$ \frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)} < \eta_1 < \frac{m}{(r+\delta)}. $$
(55)

We can then conclude from (54) that P>0 is satisfied when

$$ \beta\in(-\infty, -\eta_2) \quad \mbox{or} \quad \beta\in\biggl( \frac {2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \eta_1\biggr). $$
(56)

Therefore, the conditions (49), (55) and (56) along with the fact that β>0 give us the desirable range of the solution for β, i.e.,

(57)

Now using (53) in (51), we can write a single equation in β. After some steps of algebra, for the symmetric retailer case with positive cooperation, this single equation for β can be written as

$$ F(\beta) = \frac{8\beta(r+\delta)^3(m-\beta(r+\delta))-(2m-3\beta(r+\delta ))^2(2M+\beta(r+\delta))\rho^2}{(2m-3\beta(r+\delta))^2\rho^2} = 0. $$

Thus, a unique cooperative solution in the symmetric retailer case is guaranteed when exactly one root of the equation F(β)=0 lies in the range given by (57). The numerator of the above expression, denoted as N(β), is cubic in β. Thus, we can rewrite the equation for β as

$$ N(\beta) = a\beta^3 + b \beta^2 + c\beta+ d = 0, $$
(58)

where

Since the denominator of F(β) is positive for all values of β except 2m/3(r+δ), the sign of F(β) is the same as that of N(β). In what follows, we perform a simple sign analysis of N(β) to draw inference about the roots of (58). After a few steps of algebra with the help of Mathematica, the following observations can be made:

These observations make it clear that the equation N(β)=0 has three real roots in the following intervals:

$$(-\infty, 0),\quad \biggl(0, \frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}\biggr) \quad \mbox{and}\quad \biggl(\frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \frac{m}{(r+\delta)}\biggr). $$

Moreover, from (55) and (57), we see that there should be exactly one root in the desired interval \((\frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \eta_{1})\) for there to be cooperation in the equilibrium solution. In fact, the location of the third root in the interval \((\frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \frac{m}{(r+\delta)})\) w.r.t. η 1 determines whether we will have a cooperative or non-cooperative equilibrium. Figure 14 shows the curve N(β) when β>0. This curve gives us an idea of when exactly one of the two positive roots of the equation N(β)=0 would be in the interval \((\frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \eta_{1})\). Note that one root of this equation is negative and is not shown in the figure. It can be easily seen that to attain exactly one root in the interval \((\frac{2m}{3(r+\delta)}, \eta_{1})\) and thereby to have a cooperative equilibrium, we must have

$$ F(\beta)|_{\beta=\eta_1} < 0, $$
(59)

which, when using β=η 1 in F(β), gives us

(60)

After a few steps of algebra, one can see that the condition (60) has just the opposite sign to the one that ensures a non-cooperative solution in the case of symmetric retailers, which can be obtained by simply using M 1=M 2=M in Proposition 3. In other words, when the parameters m,M,r,δ, and ρ are such that the inequality (60) is not satisfied, then the third root of the equation N(β)=0 will be greater than or equal to η 1, and the optimal solution will be a non-cooperative one. Thus, a unique cooperative equilibrium is guaranteed when (60) is satisfied.

Fig. 14
figure 14

Subsidy rates vs. M 1

Case II: Non-cooperative Equilibrium

We now consider the non-cooperative equilibrium (θ =0) in the symmetric retailer case. As illustrated in Appendix A, the system of equations (15)–(20) can be solved explicitly in the non-cooperative case to get a unique positive solution of β 1 and β 2, given by (43). Since the symmetric retailer case is a further simplification of the case of identical retailers, i.e., with M 1=M 2=M, the solution of β is unique and is given by (43). Note that this value of β equals η 1.

Appendix C: Proof of Proposition 7

As defined in Sect. 7, \(V^{c}_{r}\) is the combined value function of the two retailers in the cooperative scenario and \(V^{n}_{r}\) is the same in the non-cooperative scenario. We can write γ i and α i in terms of β i from (44) and (46), respectively. Recall that in the case of symmetric retailers, α 1=α 2=α,β 1=β 2=β, and γ 1=γ 2=γ. Furthermore, when there is no cooperation, β=η, and its value is given by (43). Using β=η, (44), and (46), we can find \(V^{n}_{r}\) by adding computing (12) for i=1,2, and adding the two. After a few steps of algebra, we get

$$ V^n_r = \frac{2(x_1+x_2)(m(r+2\delta)-2\delta(r+\delta)\eta_1)+(-1+x_1+x_2)\eta_1(2m-3(r+\delta)\eta_1)\rho^2}{2r(r+\delta)}. $$
(61)

In the case of symmetric retailers with cooperation, using (44) and (46) from Appendix B, and using the fact that α 1=α 2=α,β 1=β 2=β and γ 1=γ 2=γ, we get

$$ V^c_r=\frac{4(x_1+x_2)(m(r+2\delta) - 2\beta\delta(r+\delta ))-(\beta+2B)(1-x_1-x_2)(2m-3\beta(r+\delta))\rho^2}{4r(r+\delta)}. $$
(62)

Clearly, \(V^{n}_{r}\) and \(V^{c}_{r}\) depend only on the sum (x 1+x 2), and this proves the first statement of Proposition 7. Next, we define \(\Delta V_{r} = V^{c}_{r}-V^{n}_{r}\), which can be computed as follows:

$$\mbox{\fontsize{9.0}{11.0}\selectfont$\displaystyle \Delta V_r \hspace{-0.5pt}= \hspace{-0.5pt} \frac{-8x\delta(r+\delta)(\beta-\eta_1)\hspace{-0.5pt}+\hspace{-0.5pt}(-1+x)(2m(\beta+2B-2\eta_1)\hspace{-0.5pt}-\hspace{-0.5pt}3(r+\delta)(\beta^2+2B\beta-2\eta_1^2))\rho^2}{4r(r+\delta)} $}, $$

where x=x 1+x 2. ΔV r is linear in x, and we will write it as ΔV r (x). We can see that ΔV r (1)=2δ(η 1β)/r>0. This is because we know from (57) that to sustain a cooperative equilibrium, the parameters (m,M,r,δ,ρ) should be such that β<η 1.

Now consider

$$\Delta V_r(0) = \frac{(-2m(\beta+2B-2\eta_1)+3(r+\delta)(\beta^2+2B\beta_2-2\eta_1^2))\rho^2}{4r(r+\delta)}. $$

Substituting the value of B in terms of β (from (53)) in the above expression, we can write

$$ \Delta V_r(0) = \frac{4(r+\delta)(m-\beta(r+\delta))+\eta(2m-3(r+\delta)\eta )}{2r(r+\delta)}. $$
(63)

It is clear by (63) that a decrease in the value of β (caused by changes in parameters) also decreases the value of ΔV r (0). We know that for a cooperative equilibrium, β<η 1, and so a lower bound for ΔV r (0) can be obtained by using β=η 1 in (63). This lower bound is

$$\frac{4m(r+\delta)+2m\eta\rho^2-(r+\delta)\eta(4(r+\delta)+3\eta \rho^2)}{2r(r+\delta)}. $$

By using the value of η 1 from Appendix B, and after a few steps of algebra, we can see that the above expression reduces to zero. Therefore, ΔV r (0)>0.

Because ΔV r (x) is linear in x, \(\Delta V_{r}(0) \hspace{-0.5pt}>\hspace{-0.5pt} 0\), and \(\Delta V_{r}(1) \hspace{-0.5pt}>\hspace{-0.5pt} 0\), we can say that \(\Delta V_{r}(x) \hspace{-0.5pt}>\hspace{-0.5pt} 0, \forall x \in [0,1]\). Thus, \(V^{c}_{r}(x) > V^{n}_{r}(x)\), ∀x∈[0,1]. The equality holds when β=η 1, i.e., when non-cooperation is optimal for the manufacturer.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Chutani, A., Sethi, S.P. Cooperative Advertising in a Dynamic Retail Market Oligopoly. Dyn Games Appl 2, 347–375 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-012-0053-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-012-0053-8

Keywords

Navigation