Production, Manufacturing and Logistics
Bundling decisions in supply chains

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.06.026Get rights and content

Highlights

  • We examine bundling decisions in a two-tier supply chain consisting of a retailer and several suppliers.

  • If all parties coordinate a supply chain has more to gain from bundling relative to an integrated firm.

  • When the suppliers coordinate the bundling gain is higher than when the retailer bundles the products.

  • In this case of a supplier coalition the bundling gain can exceed the bundling gain of an integrated firm.

  • Supply chains choose bundling for products with high margins and similar valuations with low correlation.

Abstract

Firms often sell products in bundles to extract consumer surplus. While most bundling decisions studied in the literature are geared to integrated firms, we examine a decentralized supply chain where the suppliers retain decision rights. Using a generic distribution of customers’ reservation price we establish equilibrium solutions for three different bundling scenarios in a supply chain, and generate interesting insights for distributions with specific forms. We find that (i) in supply chain bundling the retailer’s margin equals the margin of each independent supplier, and it equals the combined margin when the suppliers are in a coalition, (ii) when the suppliers form a coalition to bundle their products the bundling gain in the supply chain is higher and retail price is lower than when the retailer bundles the products, (iii) the supply chain has more to gain from bundling relative to an integrated firm, (iv) the first-best supply chain bundling remains viable over a larger set of parameter values than those in the case of the integrated firm, (v) supplier led bundling is preferable to separate sales over a wider range of parameter values than if the retailer led the bundling, and (vi) if the reservation prices are uniformly distributed bundling can be profitable when the variable costs are low and valuations of the products are not significantly different from one another. For normally distributed reservation prices, we show that the bundling set is larger and the bundling gain is higher than that for a uniform distribution.

Introduction

Price bundling is the sale of two or more separate products in a single package (Stremersch & Tellis, 2002). SAP and Microsoft, for instance, offer their products as software suites comprising several different programs. This is an instance of pure bundling by an integrated firm where only the bundle is sold. In the TV industry pure bundles of information goods are offered in a supply chain setting, where channels aggregate content from a number of third-party firms. An example of pure bundling involving a classical retailer and independent suppliers is that German electronics retailer Conrad sells certain low-end electric guitars and low-end amplifiers only bundled together. On 22.02.2010, for instance, Conrad offered 20 low-end guitars on the website www.conrad.de with a mean price of €132.38, and 15 low-end amplifiers with a mean price of €111.51. Also 7 bundles consisting of a guitar and an amplifier that were not sold separately were offered. In most cases one of the suppliers conferred his brand name to the bundle and the mean bundle price was €194.71, i.e. on average a discount of 20.17% was given. Examples of mixed bundling in a supply chain are McDonald, who sells both drinks and burgers individually as well as in bundles at discounted prices, and Amazon, who offers its customers the choice of buying single books or books bundled with others at discounted prices.

Various explanations for bundling have been proposed in literature. The use of bundling for price discrimination by an integrated monopolist has been studied in Adams and Yellen, 1976, Bitran and Ferrer, 2007, Eckalbar, 2006, Fang and Norman, 2006, Hanson and Martin, 1990, Hubbard et al., 2007, McAffe et al., 1989, McCardle et al., 2007, Oldenrog and Skiera, 2000, Salinger, 1995, Schmalensee, 1984, Stremersch and Tellis, 2002. The assumptions of this stream of research are summarized in Oldenrog and Skiera (2000) as follows:

  • 1.

    The variable costs of the products are constant.

  • 2.

    The variable costs of a bundle is determined by the sum of the costs of the products that comprise the bundle.

  • 3.

    Consumers require only one unit of a product.

  • 4.

    The reservation price for the bundle is determined by the sum of the reservation prices for the products comprising the bundle.

We demonstrate the intuition behind pure bundling using the reservation prices shown in Table 1. We start out by assuming zero variable costs. In Example 1 the optimal prices for selling the items separately are clearly 90 for product 1 and 80 for product 2. It follows that the firm can sell each product to customers A and B, making a profit of 90 * 2 + 80 * 2 = 340. If the price for a pure bundle comprising both products is set at 180, both consumers buy the bundle and the firm can increase her profit by 20–180 * 2 = 360. To understand this phenomenon let us investigate the consumer surplus defined as the difference between the reservation price of the consumer and the price set by firm. In the separate sales case consumer A has a positive surplus of 100–90 = 10 for product 1 and consumer B of 100–80 = 20 for product 2, so that total consumer surplus is 30. If the firm bundles, only consumer B has a surplus of 190–180 = 10, i.e. profit has increased because the 10 units of difference to the average willingness to pay of 90 have been transferred from product 1 to 2 for consumer A. As can be seen, the variations in reservation prices by products and consumers are moderated significantly when the products are sold as bundles, creating a greater opportunity for extracting the consumer surplus. As shown in Example 2 of Table 1, this effect is stronger if the reservation prices are perfectly negatively correlated with a high variance and have a high mean valuation. Here, the optimal profit when selling separately is 60 * 4 = 240, while the optimal bundle profit is 160 * 2 = 320 and all consumer surplus is extracted. On the other hand, bundling is not beneficial in cases of positive correlation as the variance in reservation prices is not reduced. In Example 3, for instance, the optimal profit is 80 * 2 + 60 * 2 = 280 for both separate sales and bundling. Also, the bundling gain is reduced if the mean valuations of the products differ as the product with the smaller value limits the amount of willingness to pay that can be transferred between the products. In Example 4 in the separate sales it is optimal to sell Product 1 to consumer A only, resulting in a profit of 100 + 20 * 2 = 140. The bundling profit, on the other hand, is 40 * 2 = 80 only, as willingness to pay can only be transferred for consumer B. Bundling also looses its appeal for products with significant variable costs. Assuming variable costs of 85 in Example 1 results in a profit of 360  85 * 4 = 20 for the bundle. In the case of separate sales it is optimal to set the price per unit to 100 and to sell product 1 to consumer A and to sell product 2 to consumer B only, which results in a profit of 15 * 2 = 30. Thus, in the case of significant variable costs it is better to focus on the consumers with high valuations only, i.e. in our case it is better to sell two units for a margin of 100–85 = 15 instead of selling four units at a margin of 90–85 = 5.

Do these findings hold in a supply chain setting, too? In this paper we investigate the profitability of bundling if the maximization of the profit function of an integrated firm is replaced by the equilibrium of a game between a retailer and several suppliers. In particular we investigate situations where either all parties coordinate (first-best supply chain bundling), the suppliers coordinate (supplier led bundling) or the each party acts autonomously (retailer led bundling). While some of our findings are as expected, others are somewhat counter-intuitive. Our first finding that the retailer’s margin equals the supplier’s margin establishes that the equilibrium is Pareto optimal. The second finding that a supplier led bundling obtains higher gains in the supply chain than that of a retailer led bundling stems from the fact that in the later case profit must be divided equally between n + 1 parties (with n suppliers) whereas in the former case profit is divided equally between 2 parties, the retailer and the coalition of suppliers. The third finding that the supply chain has more to gain from bundling relative to an integrated firm may not appear intuitive but it follows from the fact that in the separate sales scenario the supply chain profit is smaller than that of the integrated firm (because of double marginalization), and in the first-best bundling scenario both profits are identical. Therefore the net change in profit in the supply chain exceeds the corresponding value in the integrated firm. The fourth finding that the first-best supply chain bundling remains viable over a larger set of parameter values follows from the third finding above in that the parameter values that cause the net change in profit to be negative in the integrated firm scenario may continue to generate a positive net change in the first-best supply chain scenario. The fifth finding that supplier led bundling is preferable to separate sales over a wider range of parameter values than if the retailer led the bundling follows from our second finding for reasons similar to that explained in the fourth finding. The sixth finding that bundling can be profitable when the variable costs are low and valuations of the products are not significantly different from one another is specific to the case when reservation prices are uniformly distributed. In this case the profit made with the bundle is higher for supplier led bundling than for the integrated firm if the valuations are about the same, but bundling remains viable over a smaller set of parameter values. For normally distributed reservation prices the bundling gain is always higher than that for the integrated firm and bundling is profitable for a larger set of parameters.

Oldenrog and Skiera (2000) start their investigation of the benefits of bundling strategies with the observation that the reservation price distribution for the bundle is obtained as the convolution of the reservation price distributions of the components (Assumption 4 above). The variance of this distribution is clearly dependent on the correlation between the reservation prices of the products comprising the bundle and, therefore, it may or may not exceed the variances of individual products. If, in addition, the correlation between the reservation prices of the items and the respective variable costs are low, a monopolist can extract more consumer surplus by offering the bundle instead of selling the items separately (see, e.g., Oldenrog & Skiera (2000)). Therefore bundling is especially attractive for information goods of which large numbers can be bundled conveniently (see Bakos & Brynjolfsson (1999)). In the case of independent symmetric log-concave reservation price distributions Fang and Norman (2006) derive conditions for the profitability of pure bundling.

Various methods have been used to arrive at these findings: McCardle et al., 2007, Eckalbar, 2010, for instance, employ uniformly distributed reservations prices to study bundling decisions involving two items. While interesting analytical results can be obtained using uniform distributions, modeling the impact of correlation and tackling bundles consisting of more than two products can still be cumbersome. For this reason researchers such as Oldenrog and Skiera, 2000, Schmalensee, 1984 employ simulation techniques with a normal distribution. The results obtained in Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) rely on Chebyshev bounds, while Fang and Norman (2006) use the notion of peakedness of distributions.

Note that Assumption 4 above is not valid if the items are complements or substitutes. In Venkatesh and Kamakura (2003) it is found that the willingness-to-pay distribution of the bundle is shifted upwards by product complementarity. Thus the bundle-discount narrows and the bundling set (defined as the set of variable costs and distribution-parameters of reservation price that ensure that bundling is profitable) becomes larger. On the other hand, substitutes are better sold unbundled. Also the existence of a bundle-price can influence consumers’ evaluation (see Johnson et al., 1999, Drumwright, 1992). As shown by Soman and Gourville (2001) the sunk cost nature of a bundle price can decrease a consumers likelihood of consuming a paid-for service. If a firm can achieve cost savings through bundling, Assumption 2 above is violated. Consolidators, for instance, can obtain operational cost savings, and module integrators can utilize scale economies and reduce coordination costs. Evans and Salinger (2005) show that such cost savings on the supply side can be substantial and a rationale for bundling per se.

Bundling can also be explained as a competitive strategy. As shown by Nalebuff (2004) an incumbent with a monopoly can deter entry by bundling two goods so that each one protects the monopoly of the other one. In Gal-Or (2004) the profitability of bundling is evaluated in the context of negotiations between a monopolist and intermediaries that sell its products to consumers. In such a setting, the monopolist can utilize bundling to block negotiations between the intermediaries and a rival firm, which competes against the monopolist in a complementary market. Bakos and Brynjolfsson (2000) show that in addition to the reduction of the variance of the willingness to pay distribution bundling offers a number of competitive advantages in information goods markets.

Several works deal with supply chain issues in the case of bundling from the viewpoint of procurement and inventory policy: Bulut, Gürler, and Se¸n (2009) look at revenue management of bundles, Gürler, Öztop, and Se¸n (2009) study optimal bundle formation and pricing of products with limited stock and supply. Rosenthal, Zydiak, and Chaudhry (1995) study vendor selection and bundling, and Ernst and Kouvelis (1999) investigate inventory control problems for mixed bundles. Other works study mechanisms to distribute the revenues obtained from selling a pure bundle among the contributing parties. For instance, Ginsburgh and Zang (2001) show that the equal distribution of the revenue from a museum pass among the museums actually visited by the particular card holder resembles the Shapely value of the respective cooperative game.

The distribution channel aspect of a supply chain has only recently been investigated. For the separate sales case it is well-known that an uncoordinated determination of margins leads to a suboptimal retail price, reduced volume and a lower profit for all parties (see, e.g., Jeuland and Shugan, 1983, Parakis and Roels, 2007). One therefore can speculate that this coordination problem becomes more severe in the case of bundling, as all supply chain members must jointly agree on a bundle price and margins, whereas a simple coordination between the retailer and each supplier suffices in the case of separate sales. Thus, potential gains of price discrimination might well be offset by losses if margins are set independently, leading to a decrease in the viability of bundling in a supply chain. Bhargava (2012) studies pure and mixed bundling in a vertical distribution channel with uniformly distributed valuations in the range [0, 1] where manufacturers set prices as Stackelberg leaders. He finds that this setting leads to overpricing by the manufacturers and that the bundle accounts for a smaller fraction of sales than would occur for the integrated firm in the case of mixed bundling. General aspects of the coordination of product, process and supply chain design are studied, e.g., in Petersen et al., 2005, Rungtusanatham and Forza, 2005.

In this paper we study the use of pure bundling for price discrimination in a two-tier supply chain with one retailer and several manufacturers, based on Assumptions 1–4 above. We assume that all supply chain partners are equally strong so that coordination is achieved via a Nash equilibrium of a one-shot game. We compare the bundling set and bundling gain when the production and retail functions are integrated in a single firm, with those of three supply chain scenarios with different levels of coordination. In the first-best scenario, bundle margins are determined so as to optimize the profit of the whole supply chain. At the other end of the spectrum is the scenario where the retailer gets each supplier to participate in the bundle, and a non-cooperative one-shot game between the retailer and the suppliers yields a positive retailer and supplier margin of the bundle. Between these two extremes, lies a scenario where the suppliers coordinate with one another to initiate bundling and enter, as a single party, into a two-party non-cooperative one-shot game with the retailer. In Section 2 we develop a characterization of the equilibrium solutions for each of these scenarios for the supply chain as well as the integrated firm, using generalized reservation price distributions. Then we investigate the application of these findings and quantify the loss of efficiency for a scenario with specific distributions of reservation prices. First, we analyze the case of uniform distribution of reservation prices in Section 3. This is followed by a study using the normal distribution that enables us to analyze the impact of correlated reservation prices in Section 4. We conclude by summarizing our main findings and proposing areas for further research in Section 5.

Section snippets

Overview

We consider a two-tier supply chain with one retailer and n manufacturers, each producing one product with constant variable costs cj  0, j = 1,  , n (see Assumption 1). According to Assumption 3, the expected demand for product j at price pj is given as d(pj) = S(1  Gj(pj)), where S is the market size (number of consumers) and Gj(pj) is the distribution function of the reservation prices of item j. We assume that Gj(pj) possesses the IGFR (increasing generalized failure rate) property. This property

Bundle demand and variable costs

We assume that the reservation price (willingness to pay) for product 1 is uniformly distributed in the range [0, r], r  1 and the reservation price of product 2 is uniformly distributed in the range [0, 1] (see Eckalbar (2010) for a similar setting). Thus, in the unbundling case G1(p1) = p1/r, g1(p1) = 1/r, G2(p2) = p2 and g2(p2) = 1 and the price elasticities of demand ju(pj)=pjgj(pj)/(1-Gj(pj)) are given as 1u(p1)=p1/(r-p1) and 2u(p2)=p2/(1-p2). As the optimal prices do not depend on the market

Normally distributed reservation prices

In order to study the influence of the correlation of reservation prices on the bundling region of the various scenarios we employ a normal distribution for Gj(pj), j = 1, 2 with μ = 1 and σ = 1. We then numerically solve (7), (8), (9), (10), (11) for different values of the correlation coefficient ρ and the two cost scenarios c1 = c2 = 0 and c1 = c2 = 1. The results for zero and positive cost scenarios are shown in Fig. 10, Fig. 11.

The lines parallel to the x-axis indicate the profit that can be realized if

Summary, managerial insights and extensions

In this paper we have investigated the influence of the level of cooperation in a supply chain on the usage of opportunities for increasing profit via bundling as a price discriminating device. We found that if the setting of bundle margins is not coordinated, bundling is adopted only in the case of very high negative correlation and low variable costs. On the other hand, the supply chain wide optimization of the bundle price significantly broadens the bundling set compared to that of the

References (33)

  • H.K. Bhargava

    Retailer-driven product bundling in a distribution channel

    Marketing Science

    (2012)
  • G.R. Bitran et al.

    On pricing and composition of bundles

    Production and Operations Management

    (2007)
  • M.E. Drumwright

    A demonstration of anomalies in evaluations of bundling

    Marketing Letters

    (1992)
  • J.C. Eckalbar

    Exploring bundling theory with geometry

    Journal of Economic Education, Winter

    (2006)
  • J.C. Eckalbar

    Closed-form solutions to bundling problems

    Journal of Economics and Management Strategy

    (2010)
  • R. Ernst et al.

    The effects of selling packaged goods on inventory decisions

    Management Science

    (1999)
  • Cited by (30)

    • Online retailer bundling strategy in a dual-channel supply chain

      2023, International Journal of Production Economics
    • Retailer's decoy strategy versus consumers' reference price effect in a retailer-Stackelberg supply chain

      2022, Journal of Retailing and Consumer Services
      Citation Excerpt :

      That is, when supply and demand are mismatching, bundling is a popular operational tool. The recent bundling related literature mainly focuses on complementary or substitutable products (Bakos and Brynjolfsson, 2000), bundling discount (Gökgür and Karabatı, 2019), supply chain management (Chakravarty et al., 2013), and vertically differentiated products (Ma and Mallik, 2017; Honhon and Pan, 2017). Gökgür and Karabatı (2019) examine the impact of bundle discount on revenue enhancements.

    • Manufacturer- versus retailer-initiated bundling: Implications for the supply chain

      2022, Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review
      Citation Excerpt :

      Our paper adds to the product bundling literature in operations management. Bhargava (2012) and Chakravarty et al. (2013) highlight how vertical or horizontal channel conflict affect bundling incentive. Banciu et al. (2010) and Honhon and Pan (2017) study bundling of horizontally or vertically differentiated products.

    • Bundling decisions in a two-product duopoly – Lead or follow?

      2020, European Journal of Operational Research
      Citation Excerpt :

      Zhou (2017) shows that bundling is anti-competitive when the number of competitors is higher than a threshold. Apart from those papers examining bundling decisions for horizontally competitive firms, Bhargava (2012), Chakravarty, Mild, and Taudes (2013), and Ma and Mallik (2016) research bundling decisions for vertically competitive firms in a supply chain. Matutes and Regibeau (1992), Anderson and Leruth (1993), Economides (1993), Kopalle, Krishna, and Assuncao (1999), and Reisinger (2004) all focus on a duopoly market, where both firms produce two components of a system that are perfect complements.

    • Pricing and Product-bundling Strategies for E-commerce Platforms with Competition

      2020, European Journal of Operational Research
      Citation Excerpt :

      In addition, some papers investigate the bundling problem in a supply chain without the network externality described above. For example, Chakravarty, Mild, and Taudes (2013) consider the problem of one retailer and multiple suppliers seeking to decide whether to bundle their products in a decentralized supply chain, and show that bundling can be profitable if the reservation prices are uniformly distributed under certain conditions. Further, Giri, Mondal, and Maiti (2017) consider a supply chain with two manufacturers selling two complementary products through a common retailer who decides whether to employ the pure-bundling strategy.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    Tel.: +1 617 373 3690.

    2

    Tel.: +43 1 31336 5612; fax: +43 1 31336 5610.

    View full text