Interfaces with Other Disciplines
Macroeconomic environment, money demand and portfolio choice

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2018.09.039Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Does money demand trigger portfolio rebalancing for a long-term investor?

  • Money demand makes risk aversion time-varying.

  • Money demand reduces bond positions, having a negligible impact on stock allocation.

  • Expected inflation is the stronger macroeconomic determinant of optimal portfolio.

  • Risky asset positions and money demand negatively relate to expected inflation.

Abstract

We solve the portfolio choice problem of a long-term investor holding real balances, a stock index, multiple bonds and a remunerated money market account. We relate the factors driving the term structure and the equity premium to macroeconomic variables. When expected inflation decreases, the investor allocates more to the stock market, long-term bonds and unrewarded real balances, reducing short-maturity deposits. The optimal money demand: i) entails time variations in risk aversion; ii) reduces bond market positions when the importance of money in preferences increases, with little impact on the stock market participation; and iii) has quantitative implications in terms of horizon effects.

Introduction

During the Great Recession, modern economies witnessed a significant flight to safety and liquidity. While this phenomenon was mainly associated with a reallocation of portfolios from equities towards bonds, the latter lost some attractiveness because of the low interest rates and concerns of corporate/sovereign defaults. Conversely, physical currency and highly liquid deposits (such as checking accounts), typically held owing to the liquidity services they provide, became even more attractive to economic agents. These instruments entail an opportunity cost for the holders, as they usually do not bear interest. Fig. 1 shows the ratio between the U.S. M1 money stock aggregate, a monetary aggregate including currency, checking accounts and other very liquid means of money supply, and the index of U.S. personal consumption expenditures (PCE), against a proxy for its opportunity cost (3-month T-Bill rate) from 1959 to 2014. The negative correlation between the two is evident,1 as well as the fact that the ratio M1/PCE skyrocketed during the recent financial crisis.

In this context, it is not surprising to see the recent contributions by Acharya and Sahoo (2010), Lucas and Nicolini (2015), Belongia and Ireland (2015) and Teles, Uhlig, and Valle e Azevedo (2016), supporting a central role of monetary aggregates in the conduct of monetary policy. Disaggregated data provide more details on the holding of money by households. Humphrey (2004) reported that close to 75% of household consumption in 1995 in the U.S. was paid for by cash (currency and checks), and this figure was 46% in 2012 (Bagnall et al., 2016). Ragot (2014) found that large money holders in the U.S. tend to be households where the head of the household is relatively old, more educated, owning a house and participating in the stock market. Aoki, Michaelides, and Nikolov (2016) noted that Japanese households tend to hold more money than in the U.S., while Alvarez and Lippi (2009) identified a significant precautionary demand for currency by Italian households.

Despite sizable M1 and broader monetary aggregates, the quasi-totality of the portfolio choice literature ignores money, exclusively considering investments in interest-bearing money market accounts, stocks or bonds. The objective of this work is to analyze the money demand and portfolio choice of a long-term investor in a multi-asset universe, in relation to the macroeconomic environment. Since Merton (1971), it is well known that an investor with a long-term horizon operating in a stochastic environment, such as a household that needs to sustain a stream of consumption over time, wishes to hedge changes in the investment opportunity set. Financial assets, such as stocks or bonds, on top of their time-varying risk/return characteristics, provide also the investor with this opportunity. This implies that a myopic allocation is suboptimal, while the optimal dynamic portfolio strategy depends on the current state of the economy and on the residual investment horizon. Our investor has a horizon of up to 30 years and solves a dynamic portfolio choice problem under inflation, within a financial market where several bonds, a stock index and a money market account are traded. We implement a no-arbitrage affine term structure model, where the short-term rate and bond risk premia are allowed to be time-varying, along the lines of Dai and Singleton (2002) and Duffee (2002). Sangvinatsos and Wachter (2005) indeed show that investors, who trade bonds with different maturities and take advantage of the predictability of bond risk premia, benefit from significant utility gains. Differing from their empirical implementation, we also allow for a predictable time-varying equity premium.2

In order to include non-interest-bearing money in the investor’s portfolio, we follow the bulk of the monetary economics literature, assuming that preferences are defined over consumption and real balances, thus adopting the money-in-the-utility-function paradigm, introduced by Sidrauski (1967). Several works in monetary economics relied on this insight, such as the contributions by Roubini and Sala-i Martin (1995) and Van den Heuvel (2008). While the implications of this specification for asset prices are well understood, surprisingly much less is known about the portfolio reallocation caused by the presence of real balances.

Using U.S. data from 1952 to 2014 to estimate the model, we show that real balances play a key role in the composition of the optimal portfolio. One component of the portfolio can be associated exclusively with real balances, and we show that it hedges instantaneous changes in relative risk aversion. When the weight of real balances in the utility function increases: i) investors naturally hold a larger fraction of their wealth in real balances, and the more so the shorter their investment horizon; ii) there is a substantial reduction in bond positions; iii) intertemporal hedging demands, driven by the presence of real balances, are substantial; and iv) the stock market position is barely affected, and the impact on consumption is far less impressive than the impact on the real balances-to-wealth ratio.

An important contribution to the literature of portfolio choice under stochastic interest rates (Brennan, Xia, 2002, Campbell, Viceira, 2001, Koijen, Nijman, Werker, 2010, Sangvinatsos, Wachter, 2005) is that we relate the optimal allocation to specific macroeconomic variables, rather than referring to latent variables with little economic intuition. We do so by writing a Taylor rule for the short-term rate and relating the risk premia in the economy to expected inflation, output gap and monetary policy shocks. We show that the impact of the macroeconomic environment on the optimal portfolio positions and welfare is substantial. When expected inflation decreases, the investor increases the positions in the stock market and in long-term bonds, reduces short-maturity deposits and augments the demand for money balances. If the initial expected inflation changes from the long-run mean (3.38%) to 0%, ceteris paribus an investor with a 10-year horizon benefits from a 10% increase in certainty equivalent wealth. Conversely, when the initial expected inflation is doubled to 6.76%, the investor suffers a 2.5% loss. While the effects of changes in the output gap are qualitatively similar, they are smaller than for changes in the expected inflation. As pointed out by Clarida, Galí, and Gertler (1999), there has been a significant change in U.S. monetary policy corresponding to the beginning of Paul Volcker’s Fed chairmanship in 1979. Furthermore, in the years after the 2008 financial crisis, the interest rates were close to the zero lower bound, requiring unconventional monetary policy interventions. Because of this, we also verify the robustness of our findings repeating the analysis over a shorter sample (1979–2007), when inflation-targeting has been a key determinant of short-term rates.

While Bakshi and Chen (1996), Gu and Huang (2013) and Lioui and Maio (2014) convincingly showed that real balances matter for asset pricing, we complement their findings by showing that this can likely be rooted to their relevance at the household level. Some authors have already introduced money demand into portfolio choice frameworks, such as Ando and Shell (1975), or, more recently, Aoki, Michaelides, and Nikolov (2014) and Aoki et al. (2016). These last two works investigated money demand within a life-cycle portfolio choice problem with multiple assets, trying to explain the observed patterns in household portfolios. Our analysis differs along three dimensions. Firstly, in their work, asset classes are broadly defined as stocks and bonds, while we distinguish between bonds of multiple maturities. There is in fact no reason why a priori money should be a substitute for either short- or long-term bonds, without any distinction. When implementing a multi-factor dynamic term structure model, we observe that positions in short- and long-term bonds react in different ways when money is introduced in the economy. Secondly, they consider the bond and stock risk premia to be constant, while in our case they are stochastic. Finally, we establish a link relating optimal money demand, consumption and portfolio policy to the macroeconomic environment. An insight of our work is the linkage between money demand, interest rates and risk aversion, which provides a simple theoretical support to the evidence in Bekaert, Hoerova, and Lo Duca (2013) of a strong relationship between risk aversion and the stance of monetary policy.

Our work also contributes to the debate concerning the spanning of the macro variables and risk premia by bond yields. While many existing works assume that macroeconomic variables are spanned by yield factors, Joslin, Priebsch, and Singleton (2014) provided evidence that this assumption is far from being true. Bauer and Rudebusch (2016) revisited their findings, providing support to models based on the spanning assumption when more than three pricing factors are considered. We build an original setting, allowing for an imperfect spanning of macro variables and equity premium by bond yields, which describes the joint dynamics of nominal yields, stock returns and macroeconomic variables. Our specification preserves the nominal market completeness, being thus tractable in a portfolio choice framework, and provides reasonably implementable positions without imposing explicit portfolio constraints. We perform a comparison with a more standard model specification, where macroeconomic variables and risk premia are spanned by nominal yields, showing that our preferred model, while having comparable bond return predictive ability, better performs in describing the co-movements of risky asset returns, risk premia and macroeconomic variables. In this context, our work is related to the literature studying the effects of the macroeconomic environment and the monetary policy onto the term structure of sovereign (Ang, Piazzesi, 2003, Bikbov, Chernov, 2010, Recchioni, Tedeschi, 2017, Renne, 2016) and corporate (Curdia, Woodford, 2010, Takada, Sumita, 2011) bond yields.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we set up the economic framework and derive the optimal strategy. In Section 3, we describe the estimation methodology, present the dataset and discuss the parameter estimates, as well as the impulse response functions. In Section 4, we discuss the results of the optimal portfolio strategy in the base case, then assess the sensitivity to the preference parameters and, finally, the impact of the macroeconomic environment. Section 5 concludes. The technical details, a detailed model comparison and some additional empirical findings are relegated to the Appendix (available online, see the Section Supplementary material at the end of the article).

Section snippets

The optimal portfolio choice

In this section, we first describe the financial market where trading takes place, then the investor’s preferences and the budget constraint and the optimal portfolio strategy. Finally, we show how to include a Taylor rule in our framework and to establish a correspondence between the macroeconomic variables in the economy and the latent variables in the model. Following the asset allocation literature, our setting is cast in partial equilibrium and the investor is a price-taker.3

Estimation

In this section, we first describe the estimation methodology, proposing two different settings. The first, denoted by SM (Spanned Macro), imposes a perfect spanning of the macroeconomic variables and the equity risk premium by the bond yields, while the second, UM (Unspanned Macro), does not impose this condition. After describing the dataset used, for the sake of brevity, we report only the estimates for the setting UM, which we prefer to SM. We summarize the reasons for this choice,

Empirical findings

In this section, we present the empirical findings for the optimal portfolio strategy, consumption and money demand, as well as welfare effects, entailed by changes in the investor’s preferences and the macroeconomic environment. We report the findings only for the UM setting, because: i) it is the setting that seems to provide a better overall fit for the co-movements of asset returns and macroeconomic variables; and ii) because, being a more parsimonious model, it is less subject to the

Conclusions

An issue in the money demand literature, in the wake of the monetary development following the post-2008 financial crisis, is the storage value of money. The rising uncertainty in financial markets made traditional riskless assets, such as government bonds, instruments which are actually risky. A significant number of economic agents has been therefore looking for other “safe havens”, in the form of cash, commodities (e.g. gold) or even new asset classes (e.g. cryptocurrencies). In particular,

References (81)

  • R. Gürkaynak et al.

    The US Treasury yield curve: 1961 to the present

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2007)
  • H. He et al.

    Consumption and portfolio policies with incomplete markets and short-sale constraints: The infinite dimensional case

    Journal of Economic Theory

    (1991)
  • D. Humphrey

    Replacement of cash by cards in us consumer payments

    Journal of Economics and Business

    (2004)
  • P.N. Ireland

    Monetary policy, bond risk premia, and the economy

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2015)
  • S. Joslin et al.

    Risk premiums in dynamic term structure models with unspanned macro risks

    The Journal of Finance

    (2014)
  • S. Joslin et al.

    A new perspective on Gaussian dynamic term structure models

    Review of Financial Studies

    (2011)
  • I. Karatzas et al.

    Optimal portfolio and consumption decisions for a “small investor” on a finite horizon

    SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization

    (1987)
  • A. Lioui et al.

    Interest rate risk and the cross section of stock returns

    Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

    (2014)
  • R.E. Lucas et al.

    On the stability of money demand

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2015)
  • R. Merton

    Optimal portfolio and consumption rules in a continuous-time model

    Journal of Economic Theory

    (1971)
  • L. Pástor et al.

    Predictive systems: Living with imperfect predictors

    The Journal of Finance

    (2009)
  • X. Ragot

    The case for a financial approach to money demand

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2014)
  • J.-P. Renne

    A tractable interest rate model with explicit monetary policy rates

    European Journal of Operational Research

    (2016)
  • N. Roubini et al.

    A growth model of inflation, tax evasion, and financial repression

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (1995)
  • B. Sack et al.

    Interest-rate smoothing and optimal monetary policy: A review of recent empirical evidence

    Journal of Economics and Business

    (2000)
  • A. Sangvinatsos et al.

    Does the failure of the expectations hypothesis matter for long-term investors?

    The Journal of Finance

    (2005)
  • M. Sidrauski

    Rational choice and patterns of growth in a monetary economy

    The American Economic Review

    (1967)
  • H. Takada et al.

    Credit risk model with contagious default dependencies affected by macro-economic condition

    European Journal of Operational Research

    (2011)
  • S.J. Van den Heuvel

    The welfare cost of bank capital requirements

    Journal of Monetary Economics

    (2008)
  • J. Wachter

    Portfolio and consumption decisions under mean-reverting returns: An exact solution for complete markets

    Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

    (2002)
  • D. Acharya et al.

    An alternative approach to monetary aggregation in DEA

    European Journal of Operational Research

    (2010)
  • F. Alvarez et al.

    Financial innovation and the transactions demand for cash

    Econometrica

    (2009)
  • A. Ando et al.

    Demand for money in a general portfolio model in the presence of an asset that dominates money

    The Brookings Model: Perspective and Recent Development

    (1975)
  • A. Ang et al.

    Stock return predictability: Is it there?

    The Review of Financial Studies

    (2006)
  • A. Ang et al.

    Monetary policy shifts and the term structure

    The Review of Economic Studies

    (2011)
  • A. Ang et al.

    No-arbitrage Taylor rules

    Working paper

    (2007)
  • K. Aoki et al.

    Inflation, Money Demand and Portfolio Choice

    Working Paper

    (2014)
  • K. Aoki et al.

    Household portfolios in a secular stagnation world: Evidence from Japan

    Working Paper Series

    (2016)
  • L. Baele et al.

    The determinants of stock and bond return comovements

    Review of Financial Studies

    (2010)
  • J. Bagnall et al.

    Consumer cash usage: A cross-country comparison with payment diary survey data

    International Journal of Central Banking

    (2016)
  • Cited by (8)

    • Strategic trading with information acquisition and long-memory stochastic liquidity

      2023, European Journal of Operational Research
      Citation Excerpt :

      The trader can dynamically decide the amount spent on this private information, whose precision is proportional to the amount paid. We note that, in contrast to the literature concerning trading and investment decisions with an exogenously given asset price (e.g., Lioui & Tarelli (2019), Yan & Wong (2019), Jin, Liu, & Yang (2020), Bensoussan, Ma, Siu, & Yam (2022), Han, Ma, & Yam (2022b), Ma, Lu, & Cui (2022)), we consider an equilibrium asset pricing setting where the price is determined endogenously (e.g., Cheridito, Horst, Kupper, & Pirvu (2016), Fujii & Takahashi (2022), Mondria, Vives, & Yang (2022), Shi & Xiao (2021)). The information asymmetry between the strategic trader and the other market participants creates arbitrage opportunities for the former.

    • Real options for an entrepreneur with preferences for liquidity

      2021, Economics Letters
      Citation Excerpt :

      It should be taken into account in the utility function (Sidrauski, 1967). Henceforth, a large number of papers adopt the money-in-the-utility-function paradigm to build the models in order to examine the impacts of preferences for liquidity on asset pricing or consumption–portfolio decisions (see Balvers and Huang (2009), Gu and Huang (2013), Kraft and Weiss (2019) and Lioui and Tarelli (2019) among others). As far as we know, there are no paper to study the effects of liquidity preferences on entrepreneurs’ real option problems.

    • Money Illusion and TIPS Demand

      2023, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We would like to thank Federico Bandi, Giuseppe Bertola, Francesco Corielli, Carlo Favero, René Garcia, Fulvio Ortu, Alessandro Sbuelz, Luca Trapin, Raman Uppal, Pietro Veronesi and the participants at several seminars for useful comments. We would especially like to thank Mikhail Chernov for providing detailed comments and guidance on previous drafts of the paper. Four anonymous Referees and the Editor provided extensive comments and suggestions, which have been invaluable and led to a substantial improvement of the quality of the paper. We are solely responsible for any remaining errors.

    View full text