Bundling, product choice, and efficiency: Should cable television networks be offered à la carte?

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.infoecopol.2007.06.005Get rights and content

Abstract

We conduct a numerical analysis of bundling’s impact on a monopolist’s pricing and product choices and assess the implications for consumer welfare in cable television markets. Existing theory is ambiguous: for a given set of products, bundling likely transfers surplus from consumers to firms but also encourages products to be offered that might not be under à la carte pricing. Simulation of “Full À La Carte” for an economic environment calibrated to an average cable television system suggests that consumers would likely benefit from à la carte sales. If all networks continued to be offered, the average household’s surplus is predicted to increase by $6.80 (65.6%) under à la carte sales (despite a total bundle price that almost doubles) and reduced network profits would have to be such that 41 of 50 offered cable networks have to exit the market to make her indifferent. Simulation of a “Theme Tier” scenario provides intermediate benefits. The incremental marginal costs to cable systems of à la carte sales and its impact in the advertising market and on competition are important factors in determining consumer benefits.

Introduction

Bundling is a common feature in many imperfectly competitive product markets. Firms in the telecommunications, financial services, health care, and information industries frequently offer products in bundles. While often innocuous, recent research has identified settings in which bundling can be used by firms to price discriminate among consumers or to extend market power into related product markets (Adams and Yellen, 1976, Bakos and Brynjolfsson, 1999, Nalebuff, 2004).

We conduct a numerical analysis of bundling’s impact on the prices and networks offered by a “typical” US cable television system and assess the consequences of these choices for consumer, producer, and total welfare. We do so to speak to the current public policy debate about bundling in cable markets. Motivated by consumer dis-satisfaction over ever-increasing cable prices, law- and policy-makers are looking at unbundling – or “à la carte” pricing – as a possible policy solution.1 Most cable television systems and the networks provided on them are strongly opposed to the idea, in part claiming that doing so would (possibly dramatically) reduce the number of (especially smaller) networks that can survive in an à la carte environment (Booz Allen Hamilton, 2004).2

Existing theory bears out both of these views. On bundling and pricing, a substantial theoretical literature suggests that bundling may be used to sort consumers in a manner similar to second-degree price discrimination (Stigler, 1968, Adams and Yellen, 1976, McAfee et al., 1989, Bakos and Brynjolfsson, 1999, Armstrong, 1999). When consumers have heterogeneous tastes for several products, bundling reduces that heterogeneity, allowing the firm to earn greater profit than would be possible with component (unbundled) prices. While firms clearly benefit in this case, consumer welfare generally falls, particularly when bundling requires consumers to purchase products in which they have little interest.

Less well established are the implications of bundling on the products offered by firms. It is well known that a single-product monopolist will not offer some products that increase social welfare because of the non-appropriability of total surplus (e.g. Tirole, 1988, Chapter 2). A key factor in the extent of the distortion is the shape of consumer preferences; all else equal, products with more elastic demand are more likely to be offered as the monopolist can better appropriate surplus for such goods. In the multi-product case, theory is ambiguous: under-provision due to non-appropriability is still a problem, but if products are substitutes, monopoly pricing on one good may increase demand for a second enough to encourage its (inefficient) offering. In this (multi-product) case, bundling can also influence the calculus of product choice. Because bundling aggregates preferences for bundle components, it makes tastes more homogenous, increasing the elasticity of demand (Bakos and Brynjolfsson, 1999, Crawford, 2006). If marginal costs for bundle components are zero, Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999) show that as bundle size increases without bound, the product choice problem is solved; bundle profit converges to total surplus and both the monopolist and social planner will offer the same portfolio of goods.

When marginal costs are not zero, however, bundling can work too well. Because bundling requires all consumers purchase all goods, some sales may arise to consumers that value components at less then their cost. This is particularly problematic when there is strong negative correlation in tastes. Bundling is especially profitable in such settings (Adams and Yellen, 1976, Schmalensee, 1984) and the profit gains from correlation may outweigh the profit losses from below-cost sales. If so, the bundling monopolist may offer products that actually reduce total welfare. Even if not, consumer welfare may be lower from bundling; while some consumers will benefit from a new product, these gains may be outweighed by losses to existing consumers of the bundle.3

What are the implications of these results for the à la carte debate in cable markets? The first branch of the literature strongly suggests that, for a given set of networks, bundling reduces consumer welfare to the benefit of firms. The second branch, however, suggests that by providing stronger incentives to offer new products, bundling may increase consumer (and total) welfare. The natural solution is to attempt to address this question empirically, a topic of related work in progress (Crawford and Yurukoglu, 2007). In this paper, we take a numerical approach. We make assumptions about households’ willingness-to-pay (WTP) and firms’ costs for television networks. We then calibrate these assumptions to replicate the offerings of an “average” 2004 cable system (California Cable of Monterey, CA) and simulate the profit and welfare consequences of alternative à la carte policy proposals. We do not consider the impact of à la carte on competition and the advertising market (two important caveats), but we do consider the consequence of increased marginal costs to cable systems of à la carte offerings.

Several interesting results emerge from our numerical simulations. We consider two à la carte scenarios: “Full À La Carte” and “Theme Tiers”. As expected, if all networks continue to be offered, consumers gain and firms lose from Full À La Carte: average per-household consumers surplus is estimated to increase by $6.80 (a 65.6% increase), gross firm profit is estimated to fall by $9.08 (a 44.2% decrease), and gross total surplus is estimated to fall by $2.28 (a 7.4% decrease). These impacts almost surely outweigh any compensating benefit of à la carte to enhance incentives to offer networks: we estimate that 41 of the 50 offered cable networks in Monterey would have to exit for consumers surplus under Full À La Carte to be no higher than that under bundling. Theme tiers offer similar, though smaller, effects (a 14.2% increase in consumers surplus, a 15.7% decrease in profit, a 5.7% decrease in total surplus, and 24 networks needed to exit to equate consumer benefits). These results suggest consumers might well benefit from à la carte sales of cable networks.

Section snippets

The welfare effects of bundling

In this section we illustrate the welfare effects of bundling by a multi-product monopolist. In the first subsection, we illustrate the discriminatory effects of bundling for a given set of products. In the second, we extend this result to consider the impact of bundling on the set of offered products.

Bundling, product choice, and welfare in cable television markets

The previous section demonstrated that bundling generally transfers surplus from consumers to firms, but can also encourage the introduction of products that would not otherwise be offered. This section applies these ideas to the cable television industry. Cable television systems choose a portfolio of television networks, bundle them into services, and offer these services to consumers in local, geographically separate, cable markets. The three main types of program networks offered on cable

Conclusions

In this paper, we conduct a numerical analysis of bundling’s impact on a monopolist’s pricing and product choice and assess the implications for consumer welfare in cable television markets. Since theoretical models are ambiguous about the net impact of bundling on welfare, we take a numerical approach. We calibrate a model of the pricing decisions of an average monopoly cable system and assess the implications of the model for consumer welfare in cable television markets.

We have three main

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Leslie Marx, Scott Wallsten, and Ken Wilbur for helpful comments.

References (42)

  • C. Doyle

    Programming in a competitive broadcasting market: entry, welfare and regulation

    Information Economics and Policy

    (1998)
  • W. Adams et al.

    Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly

    Quarterly Journal of Economics

    (1976)
  • S. Anderson et al.

    Market provision of broadcasting: a welfare analysis

    Review of Economic Studies

    (2005)
  • M. Armstrong

    Multiproduct non-linear pricing

    Econometrica

    (1996)
  • M. Armstrong

    Price discrimination by a multi-product firm

    Review of Economic Studies

    (1999)
  • Y. Bakos et al.

    Bundling information goods: pricing, profits, and efficiency

    Management Science

    (1999)
  • S. Berry et al.

    Free entry and social inefficiency in radio broadcasting

    Rand Journal of Economics

    (1999)
  • Booz Allen Hamilton (2004). The À-La-Carte Paradox: Higher Consumer Costs and Reduced Programming Diversity, Discussion...
  • C.S. Chu

    “The Effects of Satellite Entry on Product Quality for Cable Television”, mimeo

    (2006)
  • C.S. Chu et al.

    “Incomplex Alternatives to Mixed Bundling”, mimeo

    (2006)
  • G. Crawford

    “The Discriminatory Incentives to Bundle in the Cable Television Industry”, mimeo

    (2006)
  • G. Crawford et al.

    “Demand, Pricing, and Bundling in Subscription Television Markets”, mimeo

    (2007)
  • D.S. Evans et al.

    Why do firms bundle and tie? Evidence from competitive markets and implications for Tying Law

    Yale Journal on Regulation

    (2005)
  • H. Fang et al.

    “To Bundle or Not To Bundle”, mimeo

    (2005)
  • FCC, 2003. 2002 Report on Cable Industry Prices”, Discussion paper, Federal Communications Commission. Available at...
  • FCC, 2004. Report on the Packaging and Sale of Video Programming to the Public, Discussion paper, Federal...
  • FCC, 2005a. 2004 Report on Cable Industry Prices, Discussion paper, Federal Communications Commission. Available at...
  • FCC, 2005b. Eleventh Annual Report on the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming...
  • FCC, 2006. Further Report on the Packaging and Sale of Video Programming to the Public, Discussion paper, Federal...
  • Halfon, J., 2003. The failure of cable deregulation: a blueprint for creating a competitive, pro-consumer cable...
  • Kagan Media Research, 2005. À La Carte Pricing Makes Great Theory, But TV Channel Bundling Tough to Beat, Discussion...
  • Cited by (27)

    • The news hour: Welfare estimation in the market for local television news

      2024, International Journal of Industrial Organization
    • Bagging bundle benefits in broadband and media mergers: Lessons from Sky/Vodafone for antitrust analysis

      2019, Telecommunications Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      As bundling can be used as a strategic means to maintain market power in existing markets as much as a means of leveraging it into new markets, then competition authorities may have to find new tools to assist in understanding the dynamic interaction between all participants, on both the supply and demand sides, when examining the effects of bundling on market outcomes. Bundling can lead to the leverage of market power via exclusionary practices (Whinston, 1990), reduction of competition through differentiation (Carbajo, de Meza, & Seidman, 1990; Chen, 1997) and reduction of heterogeneity in consumers’ valuations enabling firms with market power to extract more surplus from consumers (Adams & Yellen, 1976; Schmalensee, 1982; McAfee, McMillan, & Whinston, 1989; Stole, 2007; Crawford, 2006; Crawford & Cullen, 2007). This is clearly detrimental to consumer welfare (for some but not necessarily for all individuals) when consumers are required to purchase products of little or no interest to them (Armstrong, 1996; Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 1999).

    • Inter-firm price coordination in a two-sided market

      2016, International Journal of Industrial Organization
    • Numerical investigation on mixed bundling and pricing of information products

      2013, International Journal of Production Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      However, this bundling scheme is not fit for information goods with sophisticated functions, high prices, and non-negligible marginal costs in a market of heterogeneous customers. Crawford and Cullena (2007) used numerical computation to analyze the impact of bundling on product choice and pricing of a monopolist as well as consumer welfare in cable television service. Given the limitation of theoretical bundling models, numerical simulation helped calibrate the price decision of bundling service and assess its impact on customers’ benefit and behaviors.

    • The economics of online television: Industry development, aggregation, and "tV Everywhere"

      2013, Telecommunications Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      They show that Internet aggregation (essentially product bundling) has the efficiency characteristic of averaging consumers' demands over a great many different products at once, enabling more accurate pricing. Conceptually, their model is similar to the empirically-based explanations by Crawford and Cullen (2007) and Crawford and Yurukoglu (2012) for why cable and other multi-channel TV operators bundle programming into various packages for different prices; Bakos and Brynjolfsson's version depends on the extremely low marginal carriage or capacity costs of Internet distribution. Their model, however, appears to presume a collection of products sold at one price, such as AOL and other ISPs offered in early days of the Internet.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text