Skip to main content

Human Behavior, Dynamics of

  • Reference work entry
Encyclopedia of Complexity and Systems Science

Definition of the Subject

Dynamics of human behavior (abbreviations DHB, HB, HD) deals with the effects of multiple causal forces in human behavior, including networkinteractions, groups, social movements, and historical transitions, among many other concerns. Description of movement and change distinguishes kinematicsfrom statics, while dynamics considers causes of movement and change. Pearl [95] summarizes issuesof causality with two fundamental questions: (1) What empirical evidence is required for legitimate inference of cause‐effect relationships? (2)Given that we are willing to accept causal information about a phenomenon, what inferences can we draw from such information, and how? Policy issuesentail beliefs about causation and open a second framework for evaluating beliefs about causality [28,112]. HB dynamics is a field replete with newdiscoveries—and applications of methods derived from problems and principles that apply across disciplines. Insights transfer across...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 3,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Abbreviations

Connectivity-k (k‑connected, k‑cohesive , structural co hesion, cohesive.blocks):

refer to the Menger (1927) theorem for structure/traversal isomorphism in graph theory , as explained in the text, where k‑components are the largest possible expansion (maximal group) that preserve structural k‑cohesion. Computation is provided by cohesive.blocks in the igraph R package.

Scale-free network :

where the probability that a node i in the network connects with k other nodes is inversely proportional to the number of k's links (see: power law), more generally, \( { p_{i} (k) \sim k^{-\gamma} } \), with \( { \lambda =1 } \) for scale-free.

Nonindependence:

is characteristic of complex phenomena with built-in interdependencies, where distributions of attributes or relations should not be not directly subject to statistical inference using the null hypothesis of independence, as in structural measures sampled from networks, and autocorrelated time series or autocorrelated spatial distributions.

Sufficient statistic:

sufficient statistic for a statistical model is one that captures the information relevant to statistical inference within the context of the model, including the size and composition of the units of study. Let \( { X_{1},\dots, X_{M} } \) be a random sample, governed by the density or probability mass function \( { f(x\vert \theta) } \). The statistic T(x) is sufficient for θ if the conditional distribution of x, given \( { T(x)=t } \), is independent of θ. Equivalently, the functional form of \( { f_{\theta \vert x}(x) } \) does not involve θ, and the Fisher–Neyman factorization theorem may be used to help spot sufficient statistics. The likelihood ratio test can often be reduced to a sufficient statistic of the data for hypothesis testing. The minimum variance unbiased estimator of a parameter θ can be characterized in parameter estimation by sufficient statistics and the Rao–Blackwell Theorem. See Scharf Statistical Signal Processing [107]. A sufficient unit is one for which a random sample of aggregate statistics are sufficient.

Aggregate (“sufficient unit”) equation modeling:

assumes that causality can be found with quantitative equation models that use sufficient statistics , which implies that the aggregate units studied have cohesive mass or entitivity for causal interactions to act on their aggregate characteristics. See Sect. “Aggregate (“Sufficient Unit”) Equation‐based Modeling”.

NP-complete:

(NPC) algorithms require an order of non‐deterministic polynomial time (NP) but are exceptionally difficult: if a deterministic polynomial time solution can be found for any of them, it would provide a solution to every other problem in NP and empty out the class of NPC.

Dictator game:

where the first player proposes a split of some endowment and the second, entirely passive, receives the remainder. Not formally a game at all (as the term is used in game theory , where every player's outcome must depend on the actions of others), it is used in decision theory to test the homo economicus model of individual behavior, where selfishness would dictate allocation entirely to oneself. Henrich et al. [50] discovered in a 15‐society cross cultural study that people do allocate a share of the endowment to others. Skyrms [113] gives the dynamics of an evolutionary game theory variant.

Concentration indices:

such as the Laakso–Taagepera Index \( { 1/\Sigma _{i}p_{i} } \), where p i is an effective proportion weighting for each unit, are used for problems such as “what are the effective numbers of political parties self‐weighted by their membership (for polities: by their population or area)”, e. g., US party proportions {.49, .49, .02} would have an effective number of 2.08 while France with 101 parties (each weighted by its number of members) might have effective party number of 22.1.

Power law:

is a Pareto distribution where probability \( { p(x) \sim x^{-\alpha} } \), as for example: “multifractals have tails that follow a power law” (p. 209 in [75]) in how the frequency of similar units at different scales varies with the scale; see multifractal. Power laws tend to become ubiquitous when what is studied involves dimensional constraints. Power-law growth is expressed as \( { N = K/(t_{0}-t)^{k} } \) where K is an initial constant, t is calendrical time, and t 0 is the calendrical singularity date at which \( { K/(t_{0}-t)=K/0 } \), where division by zero produces dynamical instability as \( { K/(t_{0}-t)\to \infty } \).

Fractal:

is a pattern or object (e. g. geometrical) whose parts echo the whole, only scaled down, i. e., scale invariant; invariant at any scale of magnification or reduction. Fractal prices occur when positive and negative changes in prices (daily, weekly, monthly, yearly) follow a power law. “To improve almost any fractal model it is a good idea to replace it with a multifractal one” (p. 209 in [75]). A multifractal (with root and generator) is a composite pattern that begins with an initial root (e. g., a straight line) that is successively replaced with a generator (e. g., a zagged line) that replaces every instance of the initial element. See power law.

Causality :

is a relation holding between two variables such that manipulation of one of the variables (the potential cause) is reliably associated with variation in the other (the response), for some configuration of the values of other potential causes of the response. Estimation includes classical structural equations approaches [74], the treatment effects framework [102,103], the directed acyclic graph (DAG) probabilistic approach [95], and the settable system probabilistic approach that unifies all three [141]. Another aspect of causation is probabilistic evaluation and decision theory, in which case the effect of evidence in revising beliefs about causation can be studied in a Bayesian framework [28,112]. Probability of causation is not causation of probability, although there are probabilistic causative models.

Bibliography

  1. Adamic L, Lukose RM, Huberman BA (2002) Local search in unstructurednetworks. In: Bornholdt S, Schuster HG (eds) Handbook of graphs and networks: From the genome to the internet. Wiley-VCH,Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  2. Akerlof GA (2007) Book commentary on Avner Greif (2007a) Institutions and thePath to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Amazon.com editorial review

    Google Scholar 

  3. Algaze G (2005) The Sumerian takeoff. Struct Dyn1(1):2

    Google Scholar 

  4. Arthur B (1994) Increasing returns and path dependence in theeconomy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  5. Avin C, Shpitser I, Pearl J, Identifiability of path-specific effects. UCLACognitive Systems Laboratory, Technical Report (R-321), June 2005. In: Proceedings of International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence,Edinburgh, August 2005

    Google Scholar 

  6. Bachelier L (1900) Théorie de la Spéculation, 1900, Annales de l'Ecolenormale superiure (trans. Random Character of Stock Market Prices)

    Google Scholar 

  7. Bandy MS (2004) Fissioning, scalar stress, and social evolution in early villagesocieties. Am Anthropol 106(2):322–333

    Google Scholar 

  8. Barabási A-L (2002) Linked: The New Science of networks. PerseusPublishing, Cambridge. http://www.nd.edu/%7Enetworks/linked

  9. Barfield TJ (1989) The perilous frontier: Nomadic empires and China. Blackwell,Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  10. Bearman PS, Burns L (1998) Adolescents, health and school: Early findings fromthe national longitudinal study of adolescent health. NASSP Bull 82:601–23

    Google Scholar 

  11. Bernoulli D (1738) Exposition of a new theory on the Measurement of Risk(trans. 1954). Econometrica 22:123–136

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Boehm C (1983) Montenegrin social organization and values: Politicalethnography of a refuge area tribal adaption. AMS Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  13. Boehm C (1993) Egalitarian behavior and reverse dominance hierarchy. CurrAnthropol 34:227–254

    Google Scholar 

  14. Boehm C (1999) Hierarchy in the forest: Egalitarian society and the evolutionof democratic politics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  15. Bowles S, Gintis H (2008) Cooperation. In: Blume LE, Durlauf SN (eds) Newpalgrave encyclopedia of economics, 2nd edn. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke, http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_C00059789=GintisAopicid=result_number=2

    Google Scholar 

  16. Box GEP, Jenkins G (1976) Time series analysis: Forecasting andcontrol. Holden‐Day, San Francisco

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Brudner LA, White DR (1997) Class, property and structural endogamy:Visualizing networked histories. Theory Soc 26:161–208

    Google Scholar 

  18. Bruggeman J (2008) Social networks: An introduction. Routledge, New York

    Google Scholar 

  19. Burt RS (2001) Bandwidth and echo: Trust, information, and gossip in socialnetworks, In: Casella A, Rauch JE (eds) Networks and markets. Russell Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  20. Carhart MM, Carpenter JN, Lynch AW, Musto DK (2002) Mutual fundsurvivorship. Rev Financ Stud 15:1439–1463

    Google Scholar 

  21. Carvalho R, Iori G (2007) Socioeconomic networks with long-rangeinteractions. ECCS 2007, European Conference on Complex Systems 2007—Dresden. Paper#334. http://arxiv.org/abs/0706.0024

  22. Cliodynamics (harvested 2006), Web site of Peter Turchin,http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/people/turchin/Clio.htm

  23. Colson E (1953) The Makah indians. Manchester University Press, Manchester,University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis

    Google Scholar 

  24. Coser L (1967) Continuities in the study of social conflict. The Free Press,New York

    Google Scholar 

  25. Couzin I (2007) Collective minds. Nature 445:715

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  26. Couzin I et al (2005) Effective leadership and decision making in animalgroups on the move. Nature 433:513–516

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  27. Earle TK (1977) A reappraisal of redistribution: Complex Hawaiianchiefdoms. In: Earle TK, Ericson J (eds) Exchange Systems in Prehistory. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  28. Eells E, Skyrms B (eds) (1994) Probability and conditionals, Belief revisionand rational decision. In: Cambridge studies in probability, induction, and decision theory. Cambridge University Press,Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  29. Encyclopedia Brittannica (2007) Ibn‐Khaldun. Harvested December 8.http://www.britannica.com/eb/article-225307/Ibn-Khaldun

  30. Erikson E, Bearman PS (2006) Routes into networks: The structure of EnglishEast Indian trade, 1600–1831. Am J Sociol 112(1):195–230

    Google Scholar 

  31. Evans T, Knappett C, Rivers R (2008) Using statistical physics to understandrelational space: A case study from mediterranean prehistory. In: Lane D, Pumain D, van der Leeuw S, West G (eds) Complexity perspectives oninnovation and social change. Springer Methodos series, in press,http://www3.imperial.ac.uk/pls/portallive/docs/1/7292491.PDF

  32. Farmer JD, Patelli P, Zovko II (2005) The predictive power of zerointelligence in financial markets. PNASUSA 102(11):2254–2259,http://www.santafe.edu/%7Ejdf/papers/zero.pdf

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  33. Flack JC, Krakauer DC (2006) Encoding power in communication networks. Am Nat168:97–102

    Google Scholar 

  34. Flack JC, de Waal FBM, Krakauer DC (2005) Social structure, robustness, andpolicing cost in a cognitively sophisticated species. Am Nat 165:E126–E139

    Google Scholar 

  35. Flack JC et al (2006) Policing stabilizes construction of social niches inprimates. Nature 439:426–429

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  36. Garcia J, van den Bergh J (2007) Evolution of parochialism requires groupselection. ECCS 2007, European Conference on Complex Systems 2006, Oxford. Paper #120

    Google Scholar 

  37. Gluckman M (1963) Gossip and scandal. Curr Anthropol4:307–315

    Google Scholar 

  38. Goldstone JA (1991) Revolution and rebellion in the early modernworld. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  39. Granovetter M (1973) The strength of weak ties. Am J Sociol78:1360–1380

    Google Scholar 

  40. Greif A (1997) On the social foundations and historical development ofinstitutions that facilitate impersonal exchange: From the community responsibility system to individual legal responsibility in pre‐modern europe,Working Papers 97016, Stanford University, Department ofEconomics. http://www-econ.stanford.edu/faculty/workp/swp97016.pdf

  41. Greif A (2007) Commitment, coercion and markets: The nature and dynamics ofinstitutions supporting exchange. In: Ménard C, Shirley MM (eds) Handbook of new institutional economics. Springer, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  42. Greif A (2007) Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons frommedieval trade. In: Political economy of institutions and decisions. Stanford University Press, Palo Alto

    Google Scholar 

  43. Griffin AF, Stanish C (2007) An agent-based model of prehistoric settlementpatterns and political consolidation in the lake Titicaca basin of Peru and Bolivia. Struct Dyn 1(1):2

    Google Scholar 

  44. Hamberger K, Houseman M, Daillant I, White DR, Barry L (2004) Matrimonial ringstructures. Mathématiques et sciences humaines 43(168):83–121

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  45. Hammond M (2002) Review of [15]. Canad J Sociol Online Nov–Dec2002

    Google Scholar 

  46. Hardin G (1968) The tragedy of the commons. Science162(3859):1243–1248

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  47. Henrich J, Gil-White F (2001) The Evolution of prestige: freely conferredstatus as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evol Hum Behav 22:1–32

    Google Scholar 

  48. Henrich J, Henrich N (2006) Culture, evolution and the puzzle of humancooperation. Cogn Syst Res 7:221–245

    Google Scholar 

  49. Henrich J, McElreath R (2003) The evolution of cultural evolution. EvolAnthropol 12:123–135

    Google Scholar 

  50. Henrich J et al (2005) Economic man in cross‐cultural perspective:Ethnography and experiments from 15 small-scale societies. Behav Brain Sci 28:795–855

    Google Scholar 

  51. Henrich J et al (2006) Costly punishment across human societies. Science312:1767–1770.http://www.sciencemag.org/cgi/content/full/312/5781/1767

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  52. Henrich N, Henrich J (2007) Why humans cooperate. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  53. Henry A (1906, 1918) The education of Henry Adams. Houghton Mifflin,Boston

    Google Scholar 

  54. Hess NH, Hagen EH (2006) Psychological adaptations for assessing gossipveracity. Hum Nat 17:337–354

    Google Scholar 

  55. Hruschka D, Henrich J (2006) Friendship, cliquishness, and the emergence ofcooperation. J Theor Biol 239:1–15

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  56. Jackson MO, Wolinsky A (1996) A strategic model of social and economicnetworks. J Econ Theory 71:44–74

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  57. Johnson N, LANL scientist, Personal communication

    Google Scholar 

  58. Jorion PJ (2007) Reasons vs. causes: Emergence as experienced by the humanagent. Struct Dyn 2(1):1–6

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  59. Jost J (2005) Formal aspects of the emergence of institutions. Struct Dyn1(2):2

    Google Scholar 

  60. Khaldun I (1958) [c.1379] The Muqaddimah: An introduction to history,(trans. from the Arabic by Rosenthal F). Pantheon books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  61. Kahneman D, Tversky A (2003) Maps of bounded rationality: A perspectiveon intuitive judgment and choice. In: Frangsmyr T (ed) Les Prix Nobel 2002. Almquist & Wiksell International, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  62. Kimbrough E, Smith VL, Wilson B (2006) Historical property rights, sociality,and the emergence of impersonal exchange in long‐distance trade, Am Econ Rev (forthcoming) Interdisciplinary Center for Economic Science workingpaper at http://www.ices-gmu.net/article.php/433.html

  63. Kirman A (1999) Aggregate activity and economic organisation. Revueeuropéenne des sciences sociales 37(113):189–230

    Google Scholar 

  64. Kleiman MAR (2008) When brute force fails: Strategy for crime control (inprogress)

    Google Scholar 

  65. Kohler TA, Cole S, Ciupe S (2008) Population and warfare: A test of theTurchin model in Pueblo societies. In: Shennan S (ed) Pattern and process in cultural evolution. University of California Press, Santa Fe, inpress Institute Working Paper 06-06-018):http://www.santafe.edu/research/publications/wpabstract/200606018

  66. Korotayev A, Malkov A, Khaltourina D (2006) Introduction to socialmacrodynamics: Secular cycles and millennial trends. URSS, Moscow

    Google Scholar 

  67. Kosowski R, Timmermann A, White H, Wermers R (2006) Can mutual fund“stars” really pick stocks? New evidence from a bootstrap analysis. J Financ61(6):2551–2595. http://weber.ucsd.edu/%7Embacci/white/pub_files/hwcv-101.pdf

  68. Krakauer D (2007) Self‐description of work in progress, SFI web site,Harvested 12/11

    Google Scholar 

  69. Kremer M (1993) Population growth and technological change: One million BC to(1990). Q J Econ 108(3):681–716

    Google Scholar 

  70. Leaf M (2007) Empirical formalism. Structure and Dynamics2(1):2

    Google Scholar 

  71. Lévi‐Strauss C (1949, 1969) The elementary structures ofkinship. Beacon, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  72. Lim M, Metzler R, Bar-Yam Y (2007) Global pattern formation andethnic/cultural violence. Science 317:1540–1544

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  73. Machalek R (1992) The evolution of macrosociety: Why are large societies rare?In: Freese L (ed) Advances in human ecology, vol 1. JAI Press, Greenwich, pp 33–64

    Google Scholar 

  74. Malinvaud E (1985) Econometric methodology at the Cowles commission: Rise andmaturity. Abstracted from the Cowles fiftieth anniversaryvolume. http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/archive/reprints/50th-malinvaud.htm

  75. Mandelbrot B (1963) The variation of certain speculative prices. J Bus36:394–419

    Google Scholar 

  76. Mandelbrot B, Hunter RL (2004) The (mis)behavior of markets: A fractalview of risk, ruin, and reward. Basic Books, Hudson

    Google Scholar 

  77. Marwell G, Oliver P (1993) The critical mass in collective action:A micro‐social theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  78. Maryanski AR (1987) African ape social structure: Is there strength in weakties? Soc Netw 9:191–215

    Google Scholar 

  79. McNeill WH (1963) The Rise of the west. New American Library, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  80. Menger K (1927) Zur allgemeinen Kurventheorie. Fundamenta Mathematicae10:96–115

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  81. Milo R et al (2002) Network motifs: Simple building blocks of complexnetworks. Science 298:824–827

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  82. Modelski G, Thompson WR (1996) Leading sectors and world power: Thecoevolution of global politics and economics. University of South Carolina, Columbia

    Google Scholar 

  83. Moody J, White DR (2003) Structural cohesion and embeddedness. Am Sociol Rev69:103–127

    Google Scholar 

  84. Newman MEJ (2004) Detecting community structure in networks. Eur Phys J B(38):321–330

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  85. Newman MEJ (2006) Modularity and community structure in networks. Proceedingsof the National Academy of Sciences 103:8577–8582

    Google Scholar 

  86. Newman MEJ (2006) Finding community structure in networks using theeigenvectors of matrices. Phys Rev E 74:036104

    MathSciNet  ADS  Google Scholar 

  87. Newman MEJ, Girvan M (2004) Finding and evaluating community structure innetworks. Phys Rev E 69:026113

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  88. North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economicperformance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  89. Nowak MA (2006) Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science314:1560–1563

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  90. Oliver P, Marwell G, Teixeira R (1985) A theory of the critical mass,I. interdependence, group heterogeneity, and the production of collective goods. Am J Sociol 91:522–556

    Google Scholar 

  91. Oliver PE, Marwell G (1988) The paradox of group size in collective action:A theory of the critical mass. II. Am Sociol Rev 53(February):1–8

    Google Scholar 

  92. Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press,Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  93. Page SE (2007) The difference: How the power of diversity creates bettergroups, firms, schools, and societies. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  94. Pande, Rohini and Christopher Udry. Institutions and development: A viewfrom below. Economic Growth Center, Discussion Paper No. 928, Yale University. http://www.econ.yal.edu/growth_pdf/cdp928.pdf

  95. Pearl J (2000) Causality: Models, reasoning and inference. Press MIT,Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  96. Peebles C, Kus S (1977) Some archaeological correlates of ranked societies. AmAntiq 42:421–448

    Google Scholar 

  97. Powell WW, White DR, Koput KW, Owen-Smith J (2005) Network dynamics and fieldevolution: The growth of interorganizational collaboration in the life sciences. Am J Sociol 110(4):1132–1205

    Google Scholar 

  98. Pryor LP, Graburn NH (1980) The myth of reciprocity. In: Gergen KJ, GreenbergMS, Willis RH (eds) Social exchange: Advances in theory and research. Plenum Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  99. Read D, Behrens C (1990) KAES: An expert system for the algebraic analysis ofkinship terminologies. J Quant Anthropol 2:353–393

    Google Scholar 

  100. Reichardt J, White DR (2007) Role models for complex networks. Eur Phys J B60:217–224

    ADS  MATH  Google Scholar 

  101. Richardson LF (1960) Statistics of deadly quarrels. Boxwood Press, PacificGrove. http://shakti.trincoll.edu/%7Epbrown/armsrace.html

  102. Rosenbaum P, Rubin D (1983) The central role of the propensity score inobservational studies for causal effects, Biometrika 70:41–55

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  103. Rubin D (1974) Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized andnonrandomized studies. J Educal Psychol 66:688–701

    Google Scholar 

  104. Ruths DA, Nakhleh L, Iyengar SM, Reddy SAG, Ram PT (2006) Hypothesisgeneration in signaling networks. J Comput Biol 13(9):1546–1557

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  105. Sampson RJ, Raudenbush SW, Earls F (1997) Neighborhoods and violent crime:A multilevel study of collective efficacy. Science 277:918–924

    Google Scholar 

  106. Sampson RJ, Morenoff JD, Earls F (1999) Beyond social capital: Spatialdynamics of collective efficacy for children. Am Sociol Rev 64:633–660

    Google Scholar 

  107. Scharf L (1991) Statistical signal processing: Detection, estimation, andtime series analysis. Addison‐Wesley, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  108. Schelling T (1960) The strategy ofconflict. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Schelling_point

  109. Schelling T (1978) Micromotives and macrobehavior. W.W. Norton, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  110. Service ER (1962) Primitive social organization: An evolutionaryperspective. Random House, New York

    Google Scholar 

  111. Simmel G (1890) The sociology of Georg Simmel (trans: 1950). Free Press, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  112. Skyrms B (1988) Probability and causation. J Economet39(1-2):53–68

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  113. Skyrms B (1996) Evolution of the social contract. Cambridge UniversityPress, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  114. Sommerfeld RD et al (2007) Gossip as an alternative for direct observationin games of indirect reciprocity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104:17435–17440

    Google Scholar 

  115. Spencer C (2004) Primary state formation in Mesoamerica. Annu Rev Anthropol33:173–199

    Google Scholar 

  116. Taagepera R (1997) Expansion and contraction patterns of large polities:Context for Russia? Int Stud Q 41:482–504

    Google Scholar 

  117. Tambayong L (2007) Dynamics of network formation processes in theco‐author model. J Artif Soc Soc Simul 10(3):2

    Google Scholar 

  118. Trivers RL (1971) The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q Rev Biol46:35–57

    Google Scholar 

  119. Tsallis C (2008) Entropy. Encyclopedia of complexity and systemsscience. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  120. Turchin P (2003) Complex population dynamics. Princeton University Press,Princeton

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  121. Turchin P (2003) Historical dynamics. Princeton University Press,Princeton

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  122. Turchin P (2004) Dynamic maps of evolution of the state system andmetaethnic frontiers in Europe during the two millennia. http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/people/turchin/Clio.htm

  123. Turchin P (2005) A primer on statistical analysis of dynamical systemsin historical social sciences (with a particular emphasis on secular cycles). Struct Dyn 1(1):4

    Google Scholar 

  124. Turchin P (2005) Dynamical feedbacks between population growth andsociopolitical instability in agrarian states. Struct Dyn 1(1):3

    Google Scholar 

  125. Turchin P, Korotayev A (2003) Population dynamics and internal warfare:a reconsideration. Soc Evolut Hist 5(2):112–147

    Google Scholar 

  126. Turchin P, Nefedov S (2008) Secular cycles. Princeton University Press,Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  127. Turner JH (1921) The frontier in american history. H. Holt and Company, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  128. Turner JH (2002) Face to face: toward a sociological theory ofinterpersonal behavior. Stanford University Press, Palo Alto

    Google Scholar 

  129. von Foerster H, Mora PM, Amiot LW (1960) Doomsday: Friday, 13 November,A.D., (2026). Science 132:1291–1295

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  130. West J (1945) Plainsville. Columbia University Press, NewYork

    Google Scholar 

  131. White DR (1974) Mathematical anthropology. In: Honigmann JJ (ed) Handbook ofsocial and cultural anthropology. Rand McNally, Chicago,pp 369–446. http://eclectic.ss.uci.edu/%7Edrwhite/pub/MathAnth74-1.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  132. White DR (2004) Ring cohesion theory in marriage and socialnetworks. Mathématiques et sciences humaines 43(168):5–28

    Google Scholar 

  133. White DR (2008) Innovation in the context of networks, hierarchies, andcohesion. In: Lane D, Pumain D, van der Leeuw S, West G (eds) Complexity perspectives on innovation and social change. Springer Methodos series, in press. http://eclectic.ss.uci.edu/%7Edrwhite/pub/ch5revMay-20.pdf

  134. White DR, Harary F (2001) The cohesiveness of blocks in social networks:Node connectivity and conditional density. Sociolog Methodol 31:305–359

    Google Scholar 

  135. White DR, Houseman M (2002) The navigability of strong ties: small worlds,tie strength and network topology. Complexity8(1):72–81. http://eclectic.ss.uci.edu/%7Edrwhite/Complexity/K&C-a.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  136. White DR, Johansen U (2005) Network analysis and ethnographic problems:Process models of a Turkish nomad clan. Lexington, Oxford. A summary is athttp://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Network_Analysis_and_Ethnographic_Problems

  137. White DR, Kejžar N, Tsallis C, Farmer D, White S (2006)A generative model for feedback networks. Phys Rev E 11:016119

    Google Scholar 

  138. White DR, Owen-Smith J, Moody J, Powell WW (2004) Comput Math Organ Theory 10(1):95–117

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  139. White DR, Tambayong L, Kejžar N (2008) Oscillatory dynamics ofcity-size distributions in world historical systems. In: Modelski G, Devezas T, Thompson W (eds) Globalization as evolutionary process: Modeling,simulating, and forecasting global change. Routledge, London, pp 190–225

    Google Scholar 

  140. White H (2009) Settable systems: An extension of Pearl's causal model withoptimization, equilibrium, and learning. Submitted to J Machine Learn Res. http://eclectic.ss.uci.edu/%7Edrwhite/center/ppt_pdf/A_Comparison_of_Pearl_s_Causal_Models_and_Settable_Systems.pdf

  141. White H, Chalak K (2006). A unified framework for defining andidentifying causal effects. Department UCSD of Economics Discussion Paperhttp://www.economics.ucr.edu/seminars/spring06/econometrics/HalWhite_Lect_6-2-06.pdf

  142. White H, Chalak K (2007) Independence and conditional independence in causalsystems. http://eclectic.ss.uci.edu/%7Edrwhite/center/ppt_pdf/Independence_and_Conditional_Independence_in_Causal_Systems.pdf

  143. Wright HT (2000) Instability, collapse, and the transformation to stateorganization. System shocks‐system resilience. Workshop Paper, Abisko, Sweden, May 20–23:2000

    Google Scholar 

  144. Wright HT (2006) Atlas of Chiefdoms and Early States. Structure andDynamics: 1(4)1

    Google Scholar 

  145. Zuckerman EW (2003) On Networks and Markets by Rauch and Casella (eds). J Econ Lit 41:545–565

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

As a Santa Fe Institute external faculty member, the author greatly appreciates SFI support andthe benefits of interactions with scores of SFI researchers, visitors, and staff. Special thanks to JeroenBruggeman for sharing his prepublication book manuscript and the cross‐fertilization of ideas presented inSect. “ Cooperation, Connectivity-k and“Critical Mass” in Collective Action”, to Henry Wright for detailed commentary andsuggestions, Eric Smith for comments on the coalescence of the argument, Peter Turchin for sharing historicaldata, and to Bruggeman, Turchin, Art Griffin, Charles Stanish, and Emily Erikson for suggestions on thediscussions of their findings, to Lilyan Brudner‐White for many editorial suggestions, and to D. Eric Smithand many other colleagues at SFI for discussions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag

About this entry

Cite this entry

White, D.R. (2009). Human Behavior, Dynamics of. In: Meyers, R. (eds) Encyclopedia of Complexity and Systems Science. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-30440-3_272

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics