Skip to main content

Climate Change, Economic Costs of

  • Reference work entry
Encyclopedia of Complexity and Systems Science
  • 156 Accesses

Definition of the Subject

The economic costs of climate change include all positive and negative impacts of the enhanced greenhouse effect and the resulting changes in theatmosphere and ocean on all human consumers and producers. Total costs refer to the difference in human welfare between a scenario with climatechange and a scenario without climate change. Marginal costs refer to the difference in human welfare between two scenarios with a slightlydifferent climate, normalized by the amount of greenhouse gas emissions that would induce that difference. Estimates of the economic costs of climatechange are important to assess the size of the climate problem relative to other problems, and to compare the costs of climate change to the costs ofgreenhouse gas emission reduction.

Introduction

Calls for greenhouse gas emission reduction are often phrased as a moral imperative. While tempting, this is wrong. Firstly, there is no moralagreement. Emission reduction could save polar bears but it...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 3,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Abbreviations

Direct costs:

The direct cost equals quantity times price.

Discount factor:

The discount factor t years into the future equals one over one plus the discount rate, raised to the power t.

Discount rate:

The discount rate is the annual rate of decline of the value of consumption. It is roughly equal to the rate of interest, or the opportunity cost of capital. The discount rate consists of two components: the rate at which consumers get better off, and the rate of pure time preference (or impatience). The discount rate is not related to the rate of inflation, which is the annual rate of decline of the value of money.

Economics:

Economics is the social science which studies human behavior with regard to the relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.

Equity weights:

Equity weights are applied to aggregate national impacts to a global total. Equity weights are often set to unity, but sometimes equity weights equal the ratio of nationally average per capita income over global average per capita income.

Indirect costs:

The indirect costs equal all costs that are not direct costs. This includes the price change induced by the change in quantity (partial equilibrium effects), the changes in other markets (general equilibrium effects), and the changes at later times (dynamic effects).

Marginal costs:

The marginal cost of greenhouse gas emissions equals the first partial derivative of the net present value of the total costs of climate change to emissions.

Monetary valuation:

Monetary valuation is a set of techniques and their application that attempts to express in monetary terms the value to humans of changes in environmental goods and services. Negative impacts are typically expressed as an income loss that would give an equivalent loss in welfare.

Neo‐classical economics:

Although historians would refer to neo‐classical economics as the dominant form of economic research between 1860 and 1910, common usage has neo‐classical economics as a synonym for mainstream or orthodox economics. In that sense, neo‐classical economics is a style of research, characterized by empirical rigour, mathematical rigour, and micro‐founded macro‐relationships.

Net present value:

The net present value is the sum of all future costs and benefits, weighted by the discount factor.

Total costs:

The total cost of climate change equals the direct and the indirect costs of climate change, that is, the difference in welfare between a scenario with climate and a scenario without.

Bibliography

  1. Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2001) The colonial origins of comparativedevelopment: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91:1369–1401

    Google Scholar 

  2. Adger WN (2006) Vulnerability. Glob Environ Chang16:268–281

    Google Scholar 

  3. Arrow KJ, Cline WR, Maeler KG, Munasinghe M, Squitieri R, Stiglitz JE (1996)Intertemporal equity, discounting, and economic efficiency. In: Bruce JP, Lee H, Haites EF (eds) Climate change 1995: economic and socialdimensions – contribution of working group iii to the second assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge, pp 125–144

    Google Scholar 

  4. Ashley RM, Balmfort DJ, Saul AJ, Blanskby JD (2005) Flooding in thefuture – predicting climate change, risks and responses in urban areas. Water Sci Technol 52(5):265–273

    Google Scholar 

  5. Ayres RU, Walter J (1991) The greenhouse effect: damages, costs and abatement.Environ Resour Econ 1:237–270

    Google Scholar 

  6. Azar C, Sterner T (1996) Discounting and distributional considerations in thecontext of global warming. Ecol Econ 19:169–184

    Google Scholar 

  7. Berrens RP, Bohara AK, Jenkins-Smith HC, Silva CL, Weimer DL (2004) Informationand effort in contingent valuation surveys: application to global climate change using national internet samples. J Environ Econ Manag47:331–363

    Google Scholar 

  8. Berrittella M, Bigano A, Roson R, Tol RSJ (2006) A general equilibrium analysisof climate change impacts on tourism. Tour Manag 27(5):913–924

    Google Scholar 

  9. Bosello F, Roson R, Tol RSJ (2006) Economy-wide estimates of the implications ofclimate change: human health. Ecol Econ 58:579–591

    Google Scholar 

  10. Bosello F, Roson R, Tol RSJ (2007) Economy-wide estimates of the implicationsof climate change: sea level rise. Environ Resour Econ 37:549–571

    Google Scholar 

  11. Breslow PB, Sailor DJ (2002) Vulnerability of wind power resources to climatechange in the continental united states. Renew Energy 27(4):585–598

    Google Scholar 

  12. Broome J (1992) Counting the cost of global warming. White Horse Press,Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  13. Burkett VR, Wilcox DA, Stottlemyer R, Barrow W, Fagre D, Baron J, Price J,Nielson JL, Allen CD, Peterson DL, Ruggerone G, Doyle T (2005) Nonlinear dynamics in ecosystem response to climate change: case studies and policyimplications. Ecol Complex 2(4):357–394

    Google Scholar 

  14. Burton I, Kates RW, White GF (1993) The environment as hazard, 2nd edn. TheGuilford Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  15. Carmichael CG, Gallus Jr WA, Temeyer BR, Bryden MK (2004) A winter weatherindex for estimating winter road maintenance costs in the midwest. J Appl Meteorol 43(11):1783–90

    Google Scholar 

  16. CBO (2005) Uncertainty in analyzing climate change: policy implications.congress of the united states. Congressional Budget Office, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  17. CEC (2005) Winning the battle agains global climate change –background paper. Commission of the European Communities, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  18. Champ PA, Boyle KJ, Brown TC (eds) (2003) A primer on nonmarket valuation.Kluwer, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  19. Chichilnisky G (1996) An axiomatic approach to sustainable development. SocChoice Welf 13(2):219–248

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  20. Clarkson R, Deyes K (2002) Estimating the social cost of carbonemissions. Working Paper 140. The Public Enquiry Unit – HM Treasury, London

    Google Scholar 

  21. Cline WR (1992) The economics of global warming. Institute for InternationalEconomics, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  22. Cropper ML, Aydede SK, Portney PR (1992) Rates of time preference for savinglives. Am Econ Rev 82(2):469–472

    Google Scholar 

  23. Darwin RF (1999) A FARMer’s view of the ricardian approach to measuringagricultural effects of climatic change. Clim Chang 41(3–4):371–411

    Google Scholar 

  24. Dasgupta P (2007) Commentary: The stern review’s economics of climate change.Natl Inst Econ Rev 199:4–7

    Google Scholar 

  25. Dasgupta P, Maskin E (2005) Uncertainty and hyperbolic discounting. Am EconRev 95(4):1290–1299

    Google Scholar 

  26. Davidson MD (2006) A social discount rate for climate damage to futuregenerations based on regulatory law. Clim Chang 76:55–72

    Google Scholar 

  27. Dorland C, Tol RSJ, Palutikof JP (1999) Vulnerability of the netherlands andnorthwest europe to storm damage under climate change. Clim Chang 43:513–535

    Google Scholar 

  28. Easterly W, Levine R (2003) Tropics, germs, and crops: how endowmentsinfluence economic development. J Monet Econ 50:3–39

    Google Scholar 

  29. Elsasser H, Buerki R (2002) Climate change as a threat to tourism in the alps.Clim Res 20(3):253–257

    Google Scholar 

  30. Ennos AR (1997) Wind as an ecological factor. Trends Ecol Evol12(3):108–111

    Google Scholar 

  31. Evans DJ, Sezer H (2004) Social discount rates for six major countries. ApplEcon Lett 11:557–560

    Google Scholar 

  32. Fankhauser S (1994) The economic costs of global warming damage: a survey.Glob Environ Chang 4(4):301–309

    Google Scholar 

  33. Fankhauser S (1995) Valuing climate change – the economics of thegreenhouse, 1st edn. EarthScan, London

    Google Scholar 

  34. Fankhauser S, Tol RSJ (1996) Recent advancements in the economic assessment ofclimate change costs. Energy Policy 24(7):665–673

    Google Scholar 

  35. Fankhauser S, Tol RSJ (2005) On climate change and economic growth. ResourEnergy Econ 27:1–17

    Google Scholar 

  36. Fankhauser S, Tol RSJ, Pearce DW (1997) The aggregation of climate changedamages: a welfare theoretic approach. Environ Resour Econ 10:249–266

    Google Scholar 

  37. Gardiner SM (2006) A perfect moral storm: climate change, intergenerationalethics and the problem of moral corruption. Environ Values 15:397–413

    Google Scholar 

  38. Gerlagh R, Keyzer MA (2001) Sustainability and the intergenerationaldistribution of natural resource entitlements. J Public Econ 79:315–341

    Google Scholar 

  39. Gollier C (2002) Discounting an uncertain future. J Public Econ85:149–166

    Google Scholar 

  40. Gollier C (2002) Time horizon and the discount rate. J Econ Theor107:463–473

    Google Scholar 

  41. Guo JK, Hepburn C, Tol RSJ, Anthoff D (2006) Discounting and the social costof carbon: a closer look at uncertainty. Environ Sci Policy 9(5):203–216

    Google Scholar 

  42. Hamilton JM, Maddison DJ, Tol RSJ (2005) Climate change and internationaltourism: a simulation study. Glob Environ Chang 15(3):253–266

    Google Scholar 

  43. Hamilton JM, Maddison DJ, Tol RSJ (2005) The effects of climate change oninternational tourism. Clim Res 29:255–268

    Google Scholar 

  44. Harrison GP, Wallace AR (2005) Sensitivity of wave energy to climate change.IEEE Trans Energy Convers 20(4):870–877

    Google Scholar 

  45. Harvey D, Huang Z (1995) Evaluation of the potential impact of methaneclathrate destabilization on future global warming. J Geophys Res 100:2905–2926

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  46. Hersch J, Viscusi WK (2006) The generational divide in support forenvironmental policies: european evidence. Clim Chang 77:121–136

    Google Scholar 

  47. Hitz S, Smith JB (2004) Estimating global impacts from climate change. GlobEnviron Chang 14:201–218

    Google Scholar 

  48. Hohmeyer O, Gaertner M (1992) The costs of climate change – a roughestimate of orders of magnitude. Fraunhofer-Institut fur Systemtechnik und Innovationsforschung, Karlsruhe

    Google Scholar 

  49. Homer-Dixon TF (1994) Environmental scarcities and violent conflict: evidencefrom cases. Int Secur 19(1):5–40

    Google Scholar 

  50. Hope CW (2006) The marginal impact of co2 from PAGE2002: an integratedassessment model incorporating the IPCC’s five reasons for concern. Integr Assess J 6(1):19–56

    Google Scholar 

  51. Hope CW, Maul P (1996) Valuing the impact of CO2emissions. Energy Policy 24(3):211–219

    Google Scholar 

  52. Kikkawa T, Kita J, Ishumatsu A (2004) Comparison of the lethal effect ofCO2 and acidification on red sea bream (pagrus major) during the early developmental stages. Marine Pollut Bull48(1–2):108–110

    Google Scholar 

  53. Kundzewicz ZW, Gracyk D, Maurer T, Pinskwar I, Radziejewski M, Svensson C,Szwed M (2005) Trend detection in river flow series: 1, annual maximum flow. Hydrol Sci J 50(5):797–810

    Google Scholar 

  54. Li H Berrens RP, Bohara AK, Jenkins-Smith HC, Silva CL, Weimer DL (2004)Exploring the beta model using proportional budget information in a contingent valuation study. Ecol Econ 28:329–343

    Google Scholar 

  55. Lind RC, Schuler RE (1998) Equity and discounting in climate change decisions.In: Nordhaus WD (ed) Economics and policy issues in climate change. Resources for the Future, Washington,pp 59–96

    Google Scholar 

  56. Lind RC (1995) Intergenerational equity, discounting, and the role ofcost-benefit analysis in evaluating global climate policy. Energy Policy 23(4/5):379–389

    Google Scholar 

  57. Link PM, Tol RSJ (2004) Possible economic impacts of a shutdown of thethermohaline circulation: an application of FUND. Port Econ J 3:99–114

    Google Scholar 

  58. Long SP, Ainsworth EA, Leakey ADB, Noesberger J, Ort DR (2006) Food forthought: lower-than-expected crop yield stimulation with rising CO2 concentrations. Science 312:1918–1921

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  59. Maddison DJ (2003) The amenity value of the climate: the household productionfunction approach. Resour Energy Econ 25:155–175

    Google Scholar 

  60. Manne AS, Richels RG (2004) US rejection of the kyoto protocol: the impact oncompliance costs and CO2 emissions. Energy Policy 32:447–454

    Google Scholar 

  61. Marotzke J (2000) Abrupt climate change and thermohaline circulation:mechanisms and predictability. Proc Natl Acad Sci 97:1347–1350

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  62. Masters WA, McMillan MS (2001) Climate and scale in economic growth. J EconGrowth 6:167–186

    Google Scholar 

  63. McDonald RE, Bleaken DG, Cresswell DR, Pope VD, Senior CA (2005) Tropicalstorms: representation and diagnosis in climate models and the impacts of climate change. Clim Dyn 25(1):19–36

    Google Scholar 

  64. McLeman R, Smit B (2006) Migration as an adaptation to climate change. ClimChang 76:31–53

    Google Scholar 

  65. Mendelsohn RO (2006) A critique of the stern report. Regulation (Winter2006–2007):42–46

    Google Scholar 

  66. Mendelsohn RO, Morrison W, Schlesinger ME, Andronova NG (2000)Country-specific market impacts of climate change. Clim Chang 45:553–569

    Google Scholar 

  67. Mendelsohn RO, Nordhaus WD, Shaw D (1994) The impact of climate onagriculture: a ricardian analysis. Am Econ Rev 84(4):753–771

    Google Scholar 

  68. Mendelsohn RO, Schlesinger ME, Williams LJ (2000) Comparing impacts acrossclimate models. Int Assess 1:37–48

    Google Scholar 

  69. Mulcahy M (2004) Weathering the storms: hurricanes and risk in the britishgreater caribbean. Bus Hist Rev 78(4):635–663

    Google Scholar 

  70. Nakicenovic N, Swart RJ (eds) (2001) IPCC special report on emissionsscenarios. Cambrigde University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  71. Newell RG, Pizer WA (2003) Discounting the distant future: how much douncertain rates increase valuations? J Environ Econ Manag 46:52–71

    Google Scholar 

  72. Nicholls RJ, Tol RSJ (2006) Impacts and responses to sea-level rise: a globalanalysis of the SRES scenarios over the 21st Century. Phil Trans Royal Soc A Math Phys Eng Sci361(1841):1073–1095

    Google Scholar 

  73. Nordhaus WD (1982) How fast should we graze the global commons? Am Econ Rev72(2):242–246

    Google Scholar 

  74. Nordhaus WD (1991) To Slow or Not to Slow: The economics of the greenhouseeffect. Econ J 101:920–937

    Google Scholar 

  75. Nordhaus WD (1993) Rolling the ‘DICE’: An optimal transition pathfor controlling greenhouse gases. Resour Energy Econ 15:27–50

    Google Scholar 

  76. Nordhaus WD (1994) Managing the global commons: the economics of climatechange. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  77. Nordhaus WD (1994) Expert opinion on climate change. Am Sci 82(1):45–51

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  78. Nordhaus WD (2006) Geography and macroeconomics: new data and new findings.Proc Natl Acad Sci 103(10):3510–3517. www.pnas.org/cgi/doi/10.1073/pnas.0509842103

    ADS  Google Scholar 

  79. Nordhaus WD (2007) Critical assumptions in the stern review on climate change.Science 317:201–202

    Google Scholar 

  80. Nordhaus WD (2007) A review of the stern review on the economics of climatechange. J Econ Lit 45(3):686–702

    Google Scholar 

  81. Nordhaus WD, Boyer JG (2000) Warming the world: economic models of globalwarming. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  82. Nordhaus WD, Yang Z (1996) RICE: A regional dynamic general equilibrium modelof optimal climate-change policy. Am Econ Rev 86(4):741–765

    Google Scholar 

  83. O’Brien KL, Sygna L, Haugen JE (2004) Vulnerable or resilient? A multi-scaleassessment of climate impacts and vulnerability in norway. Clim Chang 64:193–225

    Google Scholar 

  84. Oppenheimer M, Alley RB (2005) Ice sheets, global warming, and article 2 ofthe UNFCCC. Clim Chang 68:257–267

    Google Scholar 

  85. Paavola J, Adger WN (2006) Fair adaptation to climate change. Ecol Econ56:594–609

    Google Scholar 

  86. Pearce DW (2003) The social cost of carbon and its policy implications.Oxford Rev Econ Policy 19(3):1–32

    Google Scholar 

  87. Pearce DW, Cline WR, Achanta AN, Fankhauser S, Pachauri RK, Tol RSJ, VellingaP (1996) The social costs of climate change: greenhouse damage and the benefits of control. In: Bruce JP, Lee H, Haites EF (eds) Climate Change 1995:Economic and Social Dimensions – Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on ClimateChange. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 179–224

    Google Scholar 

  88. Pearce DW, Moran D (1994) The economic value of biodiversity. EarthScan,London

    Google Scholar 

  89. Pielke Jr RA, Landsea C, Mayfield M, Laver J, Pasch R (2005) Hurricanes andglobal warming. Bull Am Meteorol Soc 86(11):1571–1575

    Google Scholar 

  90. Plambeck EL, Hope CW (1996) PAGE95 – An updated valuation of theimpacts of global warming. Energy Policy 24(9):783–793

    Google Scholar 

  91. Ready R, Navrud S, Day B, Dubourg R, Machado F, Mourato S, Spaninks F,Rodriguez MXV (2004) Benefit transfer in europe: How reliable are transfers between countries? Environ Resour Econ29(1):67–82

    Google Scholar 

  92. Rehdanz K, Maddison DJ (2005) Climate and happiness. Ecol Econ52:111–125

    Google Scholar 

  93. Schelling TC (1984) Choice and consequence. Harvard University Press,Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  94. Schelling TC (1992) Some economics of global warming. Am Econ Rev82:1–14

    Google Scholar 

  95. Schelling TC (1995) Intergenerational discounting. Energy Policy23(4/5):395–401

    Google Scholar 

  96. Schneider SH, Semenov S, Patwardhan A, Burton I, Magadya CHD, Oppenheimer M,Pittock AB, Rahman A, Smith JB, Suarez A, Yamin F (2007) Assessing key vulnerability and the risk from climate change. In: Parry ML et al (eds) ClimateChange 2007: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulnerability – Contribution of Working Group II to the Fourth Assessment Report of the IntergovernmentalPanel on Climate Change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 779–810

    Google Scholar 

  97. Scott D, McBoyle G, Mills B (2003) Climate change and the skiing industry insouthern ontario (Canada): exploring the importance of snowmaking as a technical adaptation. Clim Res 23:171–181

    Google Scholar 

  98. Smith JB (1996) Standardized estimates of climate change damages for theunited states. Clim Chang 32(3):313–326

    Google Scholar 

  99. Smith JB, Schellnhuber HJ, Mirza MMQ, Fankhauser S, Leemans R, Lin E, OgalloL, Pittock B, Richels RG, Rosenzweig C, Tol RSJ, Weyant JP, Yohe GW (2001) Vulnerability to climate change and reasons for concern: a synthesis. In:Mccarthy JJ, Canziani OF, Leary NA, Dokken DJ, White KS (eds) Climate change 2001: Impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability, vol 19. Cambridge University Press,Cambridge, pp 913–967

    Google Scholar 

  100. Stern NH, Peters S, Bakhshi V, Bowen A, Cameron C, Catovsky S, Crane D,Cruickshank S, Dietz S, Edmonson N, Garbett SL, Hamid L, Hoffman G, Ingram D, Jones B, Patmore N, Radcliffe H, Sathiyarajah R, Stock M, Taylor C, VernonT, Wanjie H, Zenghelis D (2006) Stern review: The economics of climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  101. Szolnoky C, Buzas K, Clement A (1997) Impacts of the climate change on theoperation of a freshwater cooled electric power plant. Periodica Polytecnica: Civil Eng 41(2):71–94

    Google Scholar 

  102. Titus JG (1992) The costs of climate change to the united states. In:Majumdar SK et al (eds) Global climate change: implications, challenges and mitigation measures. Pennsylvania Academy of Science, Easton,pp 384–409

    Google Scholar 

  103. Tol RSJ (1995) The damage costs of climate change – towards morecomprehensive calculations. Environ Resour Econ 5:353–374

    Google Scholar 

  104. Tol RSJ (2001) Equitable cost-benefit analysis of climate change. Ecol Econ36(1):71–85

    Google Scholar 

  105. Tol RSJ (2002) New estimates of the damage costs of climate change, Part I:Benchmark Estimates. Environ Resour Econ 21(1):47–73

    Google Scholar 

  106. Tol RSJ (2003) Is the uncertainty about climate change too large forexpected cost-benefit analysis? Clim Chang 56(3):265–289

    Google Scholar 

  107. Tol RSJ (2005) The marginal damage costs of carbon dioxide emissions: anassessment of the uncertainties. Energy Policy 33(16):2064–2074

    Google Scholar 

  108. Tol RSJ (2005) Emission abatement versus development as strategies to reducevulnerability to climate change: an application of FUND. Environ Dev Econ 10:615–629

    Google Scholar 

  109. Tol RSJ (2005) Adaptation and mitigation: trade-offs in substance andmethods. Environ Sci Policy 8:572–578

    Google Scholar 

  110. Tol RSJ (2007) The social cost of carbon: trends, outliers and catastrophes,research unit sustainability and global change FNU-144. Hamburg University and Centre for Marine and Atmospheric Science,Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  111. Tol RSJ (2007) Europe’s long-term climate target: A critical evaluation.Energy Policy 35:424–432

    Google Scholar 

  112. Tol RSJ, van der Grijp NM, Olsthoorn AA, van der Werff PE (2003) Adapting toclimate change: A case study of riverine flood risks in the netherlands. Risk Analysis 23(3):575–583

    Google Scholar 

  113. Tol RSJ, Verheyen R (2004) State responsibility and compensation for climatechange damages – a legal and economic assessment. Energy Policy 32:1109–1130

    Google Scholar 

  114. Tol RSJ, Yohe GW (2006) Of dangerous climate change and dangerous emissionreduction. In: Schellnhuber HJ, Cramer W, Nakicenovic N, Wigley T, Yohe G (eds) Avoiding dangerous climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,pp 291–298

    Google Scholar 

  115. Tol RSJ, Yohe GW (2006) A review of the stern review. World Econ7(4):233–250

    Google Scholar 

  116. Toman M (2006) Values in the economics of climate change. Environ Values15:365–379

    Google Scholar 

  117. Viscusi WK, Zeckhauser RJ (2006) The perception and valuation of the risksof climate change: A rational and behavioral blend. Clim Chang 77:151–177

    Google Scholar 

  118. Weitzman ML (2001) Gamma discounting. Am Econ Rev91(1):260–271

    Google Scholar 

  119. Weitzman ML (2007) A review of the stern review on the economics of climatechange. J Econ Lit 45(3):703–724

    Google Scholar 

  120. Weitzman ML (2008) On modeling and interpreting the economics of catastrophic climate change. Rev Econ Stat

    Google Scholar 

  121. Wilson KJ, Falkingham J, Melling H, de Abreu R (2004) Shipping in thecanadian arctic: Other possible climate change scenarios. Int Geosci Remote Sens Symp 3:1853–1856

    Google Scholar 

  122. Yohe GW, Schlesinger ME (2002) The economic geography of the impacts ofclimate change. J Econ Geogr 2:311–341

    Google Scholar 

  123. Yohe GW, Tol RSJ (2002) Indicators for social and economic copingcapacity – moving towards a working definition of adaptive capacity. Glob Environ Chang 12(1):25–40

    Google Scholar 

  124. Zhang DD, Jim CY, Lin GCS, He YQ, Wang JJ, Lee HF (2006) Climatic change,wars and dynastic cycles in China over the last millennium. Clim Chang 76:459–477

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

My thoughts on this subject were shaped by discussions with Hadi Dowlatabadi, Tom Downing, Sam Fankhauser, David Maddison, Rob Mendelsohn, BillNordhaus, David Pearce, Steve Schneider, Joel Smith, and Gary Yohe.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2009 Springer-Verlag

About this entry

Cite this entry

Tol, R.S.J. (2009). Climate Change, Economic Costs of. In: Meyers, R. (eds) Encyclopedia of Complexity and Systems Science. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-30440-3_71

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics