Skip to main content
Log in

Constrained core solutions for totally positive games with ordered players

  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In many applications of cooperative game theory to economic allocation problems, such as river-, polluted river- and sequencing games, the game is totally positive (i.e., all dividends are nonnegative), and there is some ordering on the set of the players. A totally positive game has a nonempty core. In this paper we introduce constrained core solutions for totally positive games with ordered players which assign to every such a game a subset of the core. These solutions are based on the distribution of dividends taking into account the hierarchical ordering of the players. The Harsanyi constrained core of a totally positive game with ordered players is a subset of the core of the game and contains the Shapley value. For special orderings it coincides with the core or the Shapley value. The selectope constrained core is defined for acyclic orderings and yields a subset of the Harsanyi constrained core. We provide a characterization for both solutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Besides the examples discussed in Sect. 3, other examples are, e.g. auction- (see Graham et al. 1990), dual airport- (see Littlechild and Owen 1973), telecommunication- (see van den Nouweland et al. 1996) and queueing games (see Maniquet 2003).

  2. Finite totally positive games, as well as their infinite analogs, were introduced in Vasil’ev (1975).

  3. In fact, \(H(v) = core(v)\) if and only if the dividends of all coalitions with at least two players are nonnegative, see Vasil’ev (1981), Derks et al. (2000) and Vasil’ev and van der Laan (2002).

  4. A game \(v^*\) is the dual of a game \(v\) when \(v^*(S) = v(N) -v(N\setminus S)\) for every \(S \subseteq N.\)

  5. We could easily define this solution on the class of all totally positive games with ordered players, assigning the empty set whenever the order \(D\) contains a cycle.

  6. For single-valued solutions this is weaker than a similar property introduced in van den Brink and Gilles (1996) who do not require the predecessor to be necessary for the successor.

  7. Here we should redefine efficiency, the null player property, additivity and nonnegativity for TU-games by adapting the corresponding axioms for games with ordered players in a straightforward way.

  8. Note that this also follows immediately since a sharing system assigning zero shares to players that have predecessors in the corresponding coalition satisfies the restrictions of \(P^T_D.\)

  9. A similar requirement for simple TU-games is discussed by Napel and Widgrén (2001).

  10. However, a solution that satisfies structural exclusion and nonnegativity also satisfies structural monotonicity.

  11. The condition that only connected coalitions have nonzero dividend also holds for restricted communication graph games, as introduced by Myerson (1977). Given a game and an undirected (communication) graph, Myerson defines the restricted game as the game which assigns to every coalition the sum of the worths of its maximally connected subsets in the graph.

  12. To keep terminology consistent in this paper, we deviated from the terminology of Ni and Wang (2007) who refer to a cost allocation as a solution, and to a solution as a method.

  13. Also, \(\widehat{v}\) is the dual auction game corresponding to the auction situation with \(\sum _{j=i}^n~c_j\) being the valuation of agent \(i\) for the object that is auctioned, see Graham et al. (1990).

  14. These two axioms are already used by Ni and Wang (2007).

  15. Note that on this subclass nonnegativity, meaning that every agent pays a nonnegative share in the cost, is not needed to get uniqueness. A proof can be obtained from the authors on request.

References

  • Ambec S, Sprumont Y (2002) Sharing a river. J Econ Theory 107:453–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brânzei R, Fragnelli V, Tijs S (2002) Tree connected line graph peer group situations and line graph peer group games. Math Method Oper Res 55:93–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curiel I, Pederzoli G, Tijs S (1989) Sequencing games. Eur J Oper Res 40:344–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demange G (2004) On group stability in hierarchies and networks. J Political Econ 112:754–778

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Derks J, Haller H, Peters H (2000) The selectope for cooperative TU-games. Int J Game Theory 29:23–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillies DB (1953) Some theorems on \(n\)-person games. PhD Thesis, Princeton University

  • Gilles RP, Owen G, van den Brink R (1992) Games with permission structures: the conjunctive approach. Int J Game Theory 20:277–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham DA, Marshall RC, Richard J-F (1990) Differential payments within a bidder coalition and the Shapley value. Am Econ Rev 80:493–510

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammer PL, Peled UN, Sorensen S (1977) Pseudo-Boolean functions and game theory. I. Core elements and Shapley value. Cah CERO 19:159–176

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi JC (1959) A bargaining model for cooperative n-person games. In: Tucker AW, Luce RD (eds) Contributions to the theory of games IV. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 325–355

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalai E, Samet D (1987) On weighted Shapley values. Int J Game Theory 16:205–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilgour DM, Dinar A (1995) Are stable agreements for sharing international river water now possible? Policy Research Working Paper 1474. World Bank, Washington

  • Littlechild SC, Owen G (1973) A simple expression for the Shapley value in a special case. Manag Sci 20:370–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maniquet F (2003) A characterization of the Shapley value in queueing problems. J Econ Theory 109: 90–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson RB (1977) Graphs and cooperation in games. Math Oper Res 2:225–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Napel S, Widgrén M (2001) Inferior players in simple games. Int J Game Theory 30:209–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ni D, Wang Y (2007) Sharing a polluted river. Game Econ Behav 60:176–186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS (1953) A value for N-person games. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games II. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 307–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith W (1956) Various optimizers for single-stage production. Nav Res Logist Q 3:59–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink R, Gilles RP (1996) Axiomatizations of the conjunctive permission value for games with permission structures. Game Econ Behav 12:113–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Brink R, van der Laan G, Vasil’ev VA (2008) Extreme points of two polytopes associated with a digraph and applications to cooperative games. J Math Econ 44:1114–1125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Nouweland A, Borm P, van Golstein Brouwers W, Tijs S (1996) A game theoretic approach to problems in telecommunication. Manag Sci 42:294–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasil’ev VA (1975) The Shapley value for cooperative games of bounded polynomial variation. Optim Vyp 17:5–27 (in Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasil’ev VA (1978) Support function of the core of a convex game. Optim Vyp 21:30–35 (in Russian)

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasil’ev VA (1981) On a class of imputations in cooperative games. Sov Math Dokl 23:53–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Vasil’ev VA, van der Laan G (2002) The Harsanyi set for cooperative TU-games. Siberian Adv Math 12:97–125

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research has been done while the third author was visiting the Tinbergen Institute, VU University Amsterdam, on NWO-Grant 047.017.017 within the framework of Dutch-Russian Cooperation. This author also appreciates financial support from the Russian Leading Scientific Schools Fund (Grant 4113.2008.6) and Russian Fund for Basic Research (Grant 13-06-00311). We thank two anonymous referees and the associate editor for their valuable comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to René van den Brink.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

van den Brink, R., van der Laan, G. & Vasil’ev, V.A. Constrained core solutions for totally positive games with ordered players. Int J Game Theory 43, 351–368 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-013-0382-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-013-0382-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation