Skip to main content
Log in

Potentials and solutions of cooperative games with a fixed player set

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Journal of Game Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper considers the solutions of cooperative games with a fixed player set that admit a potential function. We say that a solution admits a potential function if the solution is given as the marginal contribution according to the potential function. Hart and Mas-Colell (Econometrica 57(3):589–614, 1989) show that the Shapley value is the only solution that is efficient and admits the HM potential function for games with variable player sets. First, we argue that various solutions admit a potential function if we remove efficiency. Second, we define a potential function for games with a fixed player set and characterize the class of the solutions that admit a potential function by providing their general functional form. Finally, we associate a potential function with the axioms that the Shapley value obeys, which uncovers why the efficiency requirement uniquely pins down the Shapley value in the class of solutions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Hart and Mas-Colell (1989) define \(P(\emptyset ,v)=0\) in their work. However, this difference does not matter in general: The HM-potential uniquely exists up to constant \(P(\emptyset ,v)=0\). For details, see (Casajus and Huettner 2018). We will briefly revisit this in Lemma 2 in Sect. 3.

  2. Sánchez (1997) and Calvo and Santos (1997) show that f admits a potential if and only if

    $$\begin{aligned} f_i(N, v)=Sh_i(N,v^f) \end{aligned}$$

    for all \((N, v) \in \mathcal {G}\) and \(i \in N\), where \(v^f(S)=\sum _{j\in S}f_j(v|_S)\) for every \(S\subseteq N\), and \(v|_S(T)=v(T)\) for every \(T\subseteq S\). In this sense, a solution that admits a potential is almost equivalent to the Shapley value. However, this consistency property does not insist that f is exactly equal to the Shapley value even if f admits a potential. See also Theorem 4 in Casajus and Huettner (2018).

  3. See, for example, Owen (1975) for their mathematical properties.

  4. Strictly speaking, the original result by Shapley does not fix the player set and considers career axiom on games with a variable player set. For detail, see (Winter 2002).

  5. This game is also called a nullified game (Béal et al. 2014, 2016). Specifically, game \(v^i\) is a nullified game with player i if \(v^i(S)=v(S \setminus \{i\})\) for all \(S \subseteq N\). By successive elimination of players in \(N {\setminus } T\), we can see that \(v_T=v^{N {\setminus } T}\).

  6. A solution f is decomposable if there is a solution \(\psi\), called a decomposer, such that

    $$\begin{aligned} f_i(N, v)=\psi _i(N,v)+\sum _{j \in zN \setminus \{i\}}\bigl [ \psi _j(N, v)-\psi _j(N \setminus \{i\}, v) \bigr ] \end{aligned}$$

    for all \((N, v) \in \mathcal {G}\) and \(i \in N\). If a decomposer \(\psi\) of f is also decomposable, then \(\psi\) is said to be a decomposable decomposer. Casajus and Huettner (2018) show that f is decomposable if and only if it admits a potential and, for each decomposable solution f, there is a unique decomposable decomposer. Note that (Casajus and Huettner 2018) define the decomposability and provide their results for all games \(\mathcal {G}\), that is, the games with a variable player set.

  7. An interaction potential is introduced by Ui (2000) in the noncooperative games to characterize the class of potential games (Monderer and Shapley 1996). Nakada (2018) adopts this concept to network formation games to characterize the class of games that has a network potential function (Chakrabarti and Gilles 2007).

  8. This condition is first introduced by Hart and Mas-Colell (1989). They call it the summability condition and note that the Shapley value satisfies it. Ortmann (1998) calls this condition path-independence, which is the same name as the corresponding concept used in Physics.

  9. This condition is introduced by Myerson (1980). Béal et al. (2016) call this axiom balanced contributions under nullification in games with a fixed player set.

  10. f is linear if for any \(v, v' \in \mathcal {G}_N\) and \(c, c' \in \mathbb {R}\), \(f(cv+c'v')= cf(v)+c'f(v')\).

  11. The former result shows that the unique efficient solution that admits a potential is the Shapley value, and the latter shows that the unique efficient solution that satisfies balanced contribution is the Shapley value.

  12. Béal et al. (2016) additionally impose that \(P({\textbf {0}})\) as a normalization and argue that this property is related to the null player property. However, our Lemma 2 suggests that these restrictions are unnecessary and the null player property holds for every potential with \(P({\textbf {0}})\). See the proof of Lemma 3.

References

  • Banzhaf JF (1965) Weighted voting doesn’t work: a mathematical analysis. Rutgers Law Rev 19(2):317–343

    Google Scholar 

  • Béal S, Casajus A, Huettner F, Rémila E, Solal P (2014) Solidarity within a Fixed Community. Econ Lett 125(3):440–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Béal S, Ferriéres S, Rémila E, Solal P (2016) Axiomatic characterizations under players nullification. Math Soc Sci 80:47–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo E, Santos JC (1997) Potentials in cooperative TU-games. Math Soc Sci 34(2):175–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casajus A, Huettner F (2018) Decomposition of solutions and the shapley value. Games Econ Behav 108:37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakrabarti S, Gilles RP (2007) Network potentials. Rev Econ Des 11(1):13–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Dragan I (1998) Potential and consistency for semivalues of cooperative TU games. In: Petrosjan LA, Mazalov VV (eds) Game theory and applications. Nova, New York, pp 32–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Driessen TS, Radzik T (2002) A weighted pseudo-potential approach to values for TU-games. Int Trans Oper Res 9(3):303–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart S, Mas-Colell A (1989) Potential, value, and consistency. Econometrica 57(3):589–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monderer D, Shapley LS (1996) Potential games. Games Econ Behav 14(1):124–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson RB (1980) Conference structures and fair allocation rules. Internat J Game Theory 9(3):169–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakada S (2018) A shapley value representation of network potentials. Internat J Game Theory 47(4):1151–1157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ortmann KM (1998) Conservation of Energy in Value Theory. Math Methods Oper Res 47(3):423–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1975) Multilinear extensions and the Banzhaf value. Naval Res Logis Q 22(4):741–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez F (1997) Balanced contributions axiom in the solution of cooperative games. Games Econ Behav 20(2):161–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapley L (1953a) Additive and non-additive set functions. Ph.D. Thesis, Department of Mathematics, Princeton University

  • Shapley L (1953) A value for n-person games. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games II (annals of mathematics studies 28). Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 307–317

    Google Scholar 

  • Ui T (2000) A shapley value representation of potential games. Games Econ Behav 31(1):121–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber RJ (1988) Probabilistic values for games. In: The shapley value. Essays in Honor of Lloyd S. Shapley, pp 101–119

  • Winter E (2002) The shapley value. Handb Game Theory Econ Appl 3:2025–2054

    Google Scholar 

  • Young P (1985) Monotonic solutions of cooperative games. Internat J Game Theory 14:65–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Satoshi Nakada.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank an associate editor and two anonymous referees for valuable comments that have significantly improved our paper. We also thank the seminar participants of the Summer Workshop on Game Theory 2018 at Fukuoka for their helpful comments. Abe and Nakada acknowledge the financial support from Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI: No.19K23206 (Abe) and No.19K13651 (Nakada). All remaining errors are our own.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Abe, T., Nakada, S. Potentials and solutions of cooperative games with a fixed player set. Int J Game Theory 52, 757–774 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-023-00839-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00182-023-00839-2

Keywords

Navigation