Skip to main content
Log in

Risk exposure and Lagrange multipliers of nonanticipativity constraints in multistage stochastic problems

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Mathematical Methods of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We take advantage of the interpretation of stochastic capacity expansion problems as stochastic equilibrium models for assessing the risk exposure of new equipment in a competitive electricity economy. We develop our analysis on a standard multistage generation capacity expansion problem. We focus on the formulation with nonanticipativity constraints and show that their dual variables can be interpreted as the net margin accruing to plants in the different states of the world. We then propose a procedure to estimate the distribution of the Lagrange multipliers of the nonanticipativity constraints associated with first stage decisions; this gives us the distribution of the discounted cash flow of profitable plants in that stage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Those assumptions guarantee (Shapiro et al. 2009, Proposition 3.4) the absence of duality gap between problems (2.2) and (2.7). A problem with relative complete recourse and stagewise independent process satisfies that assumption.

  2. Traditionally (Eisner and Olsen 1975; Rockafellar and Wets 1976; Shapiro et al. 2009), nonanticipativity constraints have been introduced for the nested formulation of the stochastic problem, i.e., letting \(x_t(\cdot )\) depend on the whole data vector \(\xi _{[T]}\). This formulation is not well suited for our purposes because it destroys the recursive pattern of the cost-to-go functions.

  3. Based on the fact that \(\mathbb E _{\vert \xi _{[t]}} \{x_t(\xi _{[t+1]})- \mathbb E [x_t(\xi _{[t+1]})] \} =0\) and hence replacing \(\lambda _t(\xi _{[t+1]})\) with \(\lambda _t(\xi _{[t+1]})- \mathbb E [\lambda _t(\xi _{[t+1]})\vert \xi _{[t]}]\) does not change the Lagrangian (2.11) (Shapiro et al. 2009, p. 83).

  4. The interchangeability of the operators is valid because the cost-to-go functions are convex and finite valued (Shapiro et al. 2009, Theorem 7.46)

  5. The estimation of the Lagrange multipliers does not require a specific algorithm to compute \(\bar{x}_t(\xi _{[t]})\).

  6. The load duration curve measures the number of hours per year the total load is at or above any given level of demand (definition taken from Steven Stoft 2002).

  7. The complementarity notation \(0 \le x \bot y \ge 0\) stands for \(x \ge 0, y \ge 0\) and \(x \cdot y=0\).

  8. This contrasts with the now standard missing money argument (Paul Joskow 2007) that pure market operations cannot spontaneously develop the required capacity because of an insufficient remuneration of plant in case of high demand or high plant failure. The response of the proponents of the energy only market is that one must price electricity in every state of the world at the cost that it implies, whether this is the cost of the most expensive operating unit or the cost of demand curtailment.

  9. The risk implied by renewable policy stems from the ambitious objectives of the EU and the historical record that its plans do not always materialize as expected.

  10. The number and the duration of the time segments are identical for all the time period \(t=1,\ldots ,T\)

  11. The wind regimes are obtained from actual wind speed measured in 2010 in the center of Germany (\(51^\circ \) N, \(9^\circ \) E) by the National Centre for Environmental Prediction (NCEP) and applying the output function of an offshore wind turbine. Our model neglects spatial smoothing effects and exacerbates the difference between the wind efficiency regimes.

    Table 2 Initial demand
  12. We used SAA and quasi-Monte Carlo sampling to solve the stochastic programs. A sample of 196 scenario is used for the transition from one stage to the next one (in total \(196^2\) states of the world in the third stage) in the computation of the first stage solution. The lower bound estimate was computed by solving 50 instances of problem.

    Table 3 Wind regimes
    Table 4 Capacities invested in the different technologies
  13. These distribution are obtained as the distribution of the Lagrange multipliers of the nonanticipativity constraints. It is computationally convenient not to explicitly solve the extensive form of the nonanticipativity formulation but to compute the Lagrange multiplier using (2.17). We applied the procedure described in 2.2 to estimate \(\bar{\lambda }_1\), using a more extended sampling (\(77^2\)) for the second stage data vector \(\xi _2\).

    Fig. 1
    figure 1

    Histogram of coal margins

    Fig. 2
    figure 2

    Histogram of CCGT margins

  14. \(\mathsf CVaR ( \mathbb E [\mathrm Margin \vert \xi _2] \vert \xi 1)\) is a time-consistent risk measure

References

  • Ehrenmann A, Smeers Y (2011) Stochastic equilibrium models for generation capacity expansion. In: Consigli M Bertochi G, Dempster M (eds) Handbook on stochastic optimization methods in finance and energy. Springer, Berlin, pp 273–309

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Eisner MJ, Olsen P (1975) Duality for stochastic programming interpreted as l.p. in \(l_p\)-space. SIAM J Appl Math 28:779–792

    Google Scholar 

  • Joskow Paul (2007) Competitive electricity markets and investment in new generation capacity. In: Helm D (ed) The new energy paradigm. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Morlat G, Bessière F (eds) (1971) Vingt cinq ans d’Economie électrique. Dunod, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Pereira MVF, Pinto LMVG (1991) Multi-stage stochastic optimization applied to energy planning. Math Program 52:359–375

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Philpott AB, Guan Z (2008) On the convergence of sampling-based methods for multi-stage stochastic linear programs. Oper Res Lett 36:450–455

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar RT, Wets RJ-B (1976) Stochastic convex programming: basic duality. Pac J Math 62:173–195

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro A (2003) Inference of statistical bounds for multistage stochastic programming problems. Math Methods Oper Res 58:57–68

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro A (2006) On conplexity of multistage stochastic programs. Oper Res Lett 24:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro A (2011a) Analysis of stochastic dual dynamic programming method. Eur J Oper Res 209(1):63–72

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro A (2011b) Topics in stochastic programming. Universite Catholique de Louvain, CORE lecture series

  • Shapiro A, Dentcheva D, Ruszczynski A (2009) Lectures on stochastic programming: modeling and theory. SIAM, Philadelphia, PA

  • Stoft Steven (2002) Power system economics. Wiley-Interscience, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gauthier de Maere d’Aertrycke.

Additional information

Gauthier de Maere d’Aertrycke was partly supported by a grant from GDF-Suez. Alexander Shapiro was partly supported by the NSF award DMS-0914785 and ONR award N000140811104.

Appendix: Dual problem

Appendix: Dual problem

The optimal solutions of the Lagrangian dual problem (\(\bar{\beta }_t(\xi _{[t]}),\bar{\pi }_t(\xi _{[t]}),\bar{\mu }_t(\xi _{[t]})\) ) are obtained by solving

$$\begin{aligned} \mathfrak{D }_t(v_{t-1},\xi _{[t]})&\equiv \arg \displaystyle \max _{\varvec{\beta },\varvec{\mu },\varvec{\pi }} \displaystyle \sum _{\ell =1}^L\tau _{t,\ell } D_{t,\ell } \pi _{t,\ell } - \sum _{k=1}^K\left(\beta _{t,k} +\sum _{\ell =1}^L\tau _{t,\ell } \mu _{t,k,\ell } \right) v_{t-1,k}\nonumber \\&+ \mathbb E \left[ \sum _{t^{\prime } =t+1}^T \sum _{\ell =1}^L\tau _{t,\ell } D_{t^{\prime } ,\ell } \pi _{t^{\prime },\ell } \vert \xi _{[t]}\right] \nonumber \\&\begin{array}{lll} \mathrm{{s.t.}}&\quad C_{t^{\prime },k,\ell }+\mu _{t^{\prime },k,\ell }-\pi _{t^{\prime },\ell } \ge 0&\qquad t^{\prime }=t,\ldots ,T\\&PC_t -\pi _{t^{\prime },\ell } \ge 0&\qquad t^{\prime }=t,\ldots ,T \\&I_{t^{\prime },k} - \beta _{t^{\prime },k} \ge 0&\qquad t^{\prime }=t,\ldots ,T\!\!-\!\!1\\&\beta _{t^{\prime },k} = \mathbb E \left[ \sum \limits _{\ell =1}^{L}\tau _{t,\ell } \mu _{t^{\prime }+1,k,\ell } + \beta _{t^{\prime }+1,k}\vert \xi _{[t^{\prime }]} \right]&\qquad t^{\prime }=t,\ldots ,T\!\!-\!\!2\\&\beta _{T-1,k} = \mathbb E \left[ \sum \limits _{\ell =1}^{L} \tau _{t,\ell } \mu _{T,k,\ell } \vert \xi _{[T-1]} \right]\\&\mu _{t^{\prime },k,\ell }\ge 0; \quad \pi _{t^{\prime },\ell } \ge 0&\qquad t^{\prime }=t,\ldots ,T \end{array}\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(5.1)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

de Maere d’Aertrycke, G., Shapiro, A. & Smeers, Y. Risk exposure and Lagrange multipliers of nonanticipativity constraints in multistage stochastic problems. Math Meth Oper Res 77, 393–405 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-012-0423-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00186-012-0423-4

Keywords

Navigation