Skip to main content
Log in

Portfolio optimization in a defaultable Lévy-driven market model

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
OR Spectrum Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we analyse a market where the risky assets follow defaultable exponential additive processes, with coefficients depending on the default state of the assets. In this market we show that when an investor wants to maximize a utility function which is logarithmic on both his/her consumption and terminal wealth, his/her optimal portfolio strategy consists in keeping proportions of wealth in the risky assets which only depend on time and on the default state of the risky assets, but not on their price or on current wealth level; this generalizes analogous results of Pasin and Vargiolu (Econ Notes 39:65–90, 2010) in non-defaultable markets without intermediate consumption. We then present several examples of market where one, two or several assets can default, with the possibility of both direct and information-induced contagion, obtaining explicit optimal investment strategies in several cases. Finally, we study the growth-optimal portfolio in our framework and show an example with necessary and sufficient conditions for it to be a proper martingale or a strict local martingale.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ang A, Bekaert G (2002) International asset allocation with regime shifts. Rev Financ Stud 15:1137–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli F, Ramponi A, Scarlatti S (2013) Option-based risk management of a bond portfolio under regime switching interest rates. Decis Econ Financ 36:47–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backhaus J, Frey R (2008) Pricing and hedging of portfolio credit derivatives with interacting default intensities. Int J Theor Appl Financ 11:611–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becherer D (2001) The numeraire portfolio for unbounded semimartingales. Financ Stoch 5:327–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellamy N (2001) Wealth optimization in an incomplete market driven by a jump-diffusion process. J Math Econ Spec Issue Arbitr Control Probl Financ 35(3):259–287

  • Benth F, Schmeck M (2012) Stability of Merton’s portfolio optimization problem for Lévy models. Stochastics 85(5):833–858

    Google Scholar 

  • Benth FE, Karlsen KH, Reikvam K (2001) Optimal portfolio management rules in a non-Gaussian market with durability and intertemporal substitution. Financ Stoch 5:447–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhanot DHK, Burns N, Williams M (2014) News spillovers from the Greek debt crisis: impact on the Eurozone financial sector. J Bank Financ 38:51–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bielecki T, Jang I (2006) Portfolio optimization with a defaultable security. Asia Pac Financ Mark 13:113–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bo L, Wang Y, Yang X (2010) An optimal portfolio problem in a defaultable market. Adv Appl Probab 42:689–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bühlmann H, Platen E (2003) A discrete time benchmark approach for insurance and finance. Astin Bull 33:153–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callegaro G (2013) Optimal consumption problems in discontinuous markets. Optimization 62(11):1575–1602

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callegaro G, Vargiolu T (2009) Optimal portfolio for HARA utility functions in a pure jump multidimensional incomplete market. Int J Risk Assess Manag Spec Issue Meas Manag Financ Risk 11:180–200

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Callegaro G, Jeanblanc M, Runggaldier WJ (2012) Portfolio optimization in a defaultable market under incomplete information. Decis Econ Financ 35:91–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capponi A, Figueroa-López J (2014) Dynamic portfolio optimization with a defaultable security and regime-switching markets. Math Financ 24(2):207–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capponi A, Figueroa-López J, Nisen J (2014) Pricing and semimartingale representations of vulnerable contingent claims in regime-switching markets. Math Financ 24(2):250–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen MM, Larsen K (2007) No arbitrage and the growth optimal portfolio. Stoch Anal Appl 25:255–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cont R, Tankov P (2004) Financial modelling with jump processes. Chapman & Hall/CRC financial mathematics series. Chapman & Hall/CRC, Boca Raton

    Google Scholar 

  • Cousin A, Jeanblanc M, Laurent J-P (2011) Hedging CDO, tranches in a Markovian environment. In: Paris-Princeton lectures on mathematical finance 2010. Lecture notes in mathematics, vol 2003. Springer, Berlin, pp 1–61

  • Cvitanić J, Karatzas I (1992) Convex duality in constrained portfolio optimization. Ann Appl Probab 2:767–818

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dai KJSQ, Yang W (2007) Regime shifts in a dynamic term structure model of U.S. treasury bond yields. Rev Financ Stud 20:1669–1706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dumontaux N, Pop A (2012) Contagion effects in the aftermath of Lehman’s collapse: measuring the collateral damage. LEMNA Working Paper, vol 27, pp 1–45

  • Fleming WH, Soner HM (2006) Controlled Markov processes and viscosity solutions, 2nd edn. Stochastic modelling and applied probability, vol 25. Springer, New York

  • Fontana C, Runggaldier W (2013) Diffusion-based models for financial markets without martingale measures. In: Biagini F, Richter A, Schlesinger H (eds) Risk measures and attitudes. EAA series, Springer, pp 45–81

  • Framstad NC, Øksendal B, Sulem A (2001) Optimal consumption and portfolio in a jump diffusion market with proportional transaction costs. J Math Econ Spec Issue Arbitr Control Probl Financ 35(3):233–257

  • Gentile M, Giordano L (2012) Financial contagion during Lehman default and sovereign debt crisis. Quaderni di Finanza CONSOB 72:3–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Giesecke SSK, Longstaff F, Strebulaev I (2011) Corporate bond default risk: a 150-year perspective. J Financ Econ 102:233–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeanblanc-Picqué M, Pontier M (1990) Optimal portfolio for a small investor in a market model with discontinuous prices. Appl Math Optim 22:287–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kallsen J (2000) Optimal portfolios for exponential Lévy processes. Math Methods Oper Res 51:357–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kazi IR, Salloy S (2013) Contagion effect due to Lehman Brothers’ bankruptcy and the global financial crisis—from the perspective of the credit default swaps’ G14 dealers. Working Paper Université Paris Ouest, 06, pp 1–49

  • Korn R, Oertel F, Schäl M (2003) The numeraire portfolio in financial markets modeled by a multi-dimensional jump diffusion process. Decis Econ Financ 26:153–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramkov D, Schachermayer W (1999) The asymptotic elasticity of utility functions and optimal investment in incomplete markets. Ann Appl Probab 9:904–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu J, Longstaff F, Pan J (2003) Dynamic asset allocation with event risk. J Financ 58:231–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Øksendal B, Sulem A (2005) Applied stochastic control of jump diffusions. Springer, Berlin

  • Pasin L, Vargiolu T (2010) Optimal portfolio for HARA utility functions where risky assets are exponential additive processes. Econ Notes 39:65–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Platen E (2006) A benchmark approach to finance. Math Financ 16:131–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Protter PE (2004) Stochastic integration and differential equations. In: Stochastic modelling and applied probability. Applications of mathematics (New York), vol. 21, 2nd edn. Springer, Berlin

  • Valdez A, Vargiolu T (2013) Optimal portfolio in a regime-switching model. In: Seminar on stochastic analysis, random fields and applications VI—Centro Stefano Franscini-Ascona. Progress in probability, vol 67. Springer, Berlin, pp 435–449

Download references

Acknowledgments

A significant portion of the research reported in this paper was done while the first author was a PhD student in the Department of Mathematics at the University of Padova. This work was partially supported by the grant CPDA138873-2013 of the University of Padova ’Stochastic models with spatial structure and applications to new challenges in Mathematical Finance, with a focus on the post-2008 financial crisis environment and on energy markets’. The authors would like to thank Giorgia Callegaro, Wolfgang Runggaldier and two anonymous referees for constructive comments which contributed to improve the quality of this manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tiziano Vargiolu.

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 5.4

Appendix: Proof of Theorem 5.4

We first need to introduce the following notation.

Definition 8.1

Given \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\), we call the length of \(d\) the positive integer defined as

$$\begin{aligned} l(d):=n-\sum _{i=0}^n d_i. \end{aligned}$$

Moreover we establish on \(\{0,1\}^n\) the following (partial) order relation:

$$\begin{aligned} d\le d'\quad \hbox {if}\ d_i\ge d'_i\quad \forall i=1,\ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

Note that given \(D_t=d\) for a certain \(t\le 0\), the states \(d'<d\) are the only states accessible for \(D\) after the time \(t\).

Roughly speaking, the length of \(d\) is equal to the number of risky asset that are still alive. In particular, when every firm has already defaulted we have \(l(d)=0\), whereas when every firm did not we have \(l(d)=n\). We also explicitly observe that

$$\begin{aligned} d+\chi (d,x)\le d\quad \forall d\in \{0,1\}^n,x\in X^n. \end{aligned}$$

Hence by (5.4), given a state \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\), \(A^h J(t,x,d)\) depends only on the states \(d'\le d\), i.e. the states whose alive assets are a subset of the alive ones in \(d\); in other words, \(A^{h,c} J(t,x,d)\) does not depend on the assets whose entities have already defaulted.

We also need the following

Lemma 8.2

Consider the function

$$\begin{aligned} \psi (t,v,c)= \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \log c - c\frac{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }{v},&{} \quad \delta >0 \\ B \log c - c\frac{A +B(T-t)}{v},&{} \quad \delta =0 \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(8.1)

with \(A,B\ge 0,A+B>0\). Then, for any \(t\in [0,T]\) and \(v>0\) we have

$$\begin{aligned} {\bar{c}}(t)v=\arg \max _{c>0}\psi (t,v,c), \end{aligned}$$
(8.2)

where \({\bar{c}}\) is defined as in (5.16). Moreover,

$$\begin{aligned} \max \limits _{c>0} \psi (t,v,c) =\psi (t,v,{\bar{c}}(t)v)&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\left( \log \left( \frac{B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }\right) -1 \right) \nonumber \\&+ B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \log v \end{aligned}$$
(8.3)

if \(\delta >0,\) whereas

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{c>0} \psi (t,v,c) =\psi (t,v,{\bar{c}}(t)v)=B \left( \log \left( \frac{B}{A +B(T-t)}\right) -1 \right) + B \log v \end{aligned}$$

if \(\delta =0\).

Proof

We only prove the case \(\delta >0\). For any \(t\in [0,T],v>0\) we have

$$\begin{aligned} \psi _c(t,v,c)=\frac{B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}}{c}-\frac{A+\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1-\mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }{v}=0 \end{aligned}$$

if and only if \(c={\bar{c}}(t)v\). Thus, \({\bar{c}}(t)v\) is the only stationary point for \(\psi (t,v,\cdot )\), and since \(\lim _{c\rightarrow 0}\psi (t,v,c)=\lim _{c\rightarrow \infty }\psi (t,v,c)=-\infty \), we obtain (8.2). Eventually, (8.3) follows from a direct computation. \(\square \)

We now prove Theorem 5.4.

Proof of Theorem 5.4

We only prove the theorem for \(\delta >0\), as the case \(\delta =0\) is totally analogous.

Part (a). By induction on \(k=l(d)\). We start proving the statement when \(k=0\). In this case we clearly have \(d={\mathbf {1}}:=(1,\ldots ,1)\), i.e. all the entities have defaulted. If we search for a solution of the kind \(K(t,v,d)\) as in (5.13), we clearly obtain

$$\begin{aligned} A^{h,c} K(t,v,{\mathbf {1}})=A^h K(t,v,1,\ldots ,1)=-c\frac{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }{v}, \end{aligned}$$
(8.4)

so that the HJB equation becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}}{{\mathrm {d}}t}\Phi ^{{\mathbf {1}}}(t)&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v -\sup _{c>0}\left( B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \log c - c\frac{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }{v} \right) \nonumber \\&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v -\sup _{c>0} \psi (t,v,c), \end{aligned}$$
(8.5)

with \(\psi (t,v,c)\) as in (8.1). Thus by Lemma 8.2 we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{{\mathrm {d}}}{{\mathrm {d}}t}\Phi ^{{\mathbf {1}}}(t)&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v - \psi (t,v,{\bar{c}}(t)v) \nonumber \\&= - B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\left( \log \left( \frac{B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }\right) -1 \right) \end{aligned}$$
(8.6)

Therefore, we define \(\Phi ^{{\mathbf {1}}}\) as the unique solution of (8.6) provided with the terminal condition \(\Phi ^{{\mathbf {1}}}(T)=0\), so that \(K(t,v,{\mathbf {1}})\) solves Eq. (5.3) with the terminal condition (5.7).

We now assume the statement to be true for any \(d'\in \{0,1\}^n\) such that \(l(d')\le k-1\) and prove it to be true for any \(d\) such that \(l(d)=k\). We set

$$\begin{aligned} K(t,v,d)=\left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) \log v + \Phi ^{d}(t), \end{aligned}$$
(8.7)

where \(\Phi ^{d}\) is a \(C^1\) deterministic function such that \(\Phi ^{d}(T)=0\). Then we have

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial K}{\partial t}(t,v,d)&= \frac{{\mathrm {d}}}{{\mathrm {d}}t}\Phi ^{d}(t)- B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}, \\ v \frac{\partial K}{\partial v}(t,v,d)&= -v^2 \frac{\partial ^2 K}{\partial v^2}(t,v,d)=A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore we obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{A^{h,c} K(t,v,d)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }=\langle \mu (t,d),h^{d} \rangle - \frac{c}{v}-\frac{1}{2}\langle h^{d}\Sigma (t,d),h^{d} \rangle \\&\quad +\int _{X^n}\left( \frac{ K\big (t,v(1+\langle x,h^{d} \rangle ),d+\chi (d,x)\big )-\Phi ^{d}(t)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) } -\log {v}-\langle x,h^{d} \rangle \right) \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x) \end{aligned}$$

[by (5.6)]

$$\begin{aligned} =\langle \mu (t),h^{d} \rangle - \frac{c}{v}-\frac{1}{2}\langle h^{d}\Sigma (t),h^{d} \rangle + I_1 +I_2, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} I_1=\int _{X^n\backslash \Theta ^{d}}\left( \frac{ K\big (t,v(1+\langle x,h^{d} \rangle ),d\big )-\Phi ^{d}(t)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }-\log {v}-\langle x,h^{d} \rangle \right) \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x), \end{aligned}$$

[by (8.7)]

$$\begin{aligned} =\int _{X^n\backslash \Theta ^{d}}\Big ( \log {(1+\langle x,h^{d} \rangle )}-\langle x,h^{d} \rangle \Big )\nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x), \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} \Theta ^{d}=X^n\bigcap \left( \mathop {\bigcup }\limits _{\begin{array}{c} 1\le i\le n,\\ d_i=0 \end{array}}\{x_{i}= -1\}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(8.8)

and where

$$\begin{aligned} I_2=\int _{\Theta ^{d}}\left( \frac{ K\big (t,v(1+\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle ),d+\chi (d,x)\big )-\Phi ^{d}(t)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }-\log {v}-\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle \right) \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x) \end{aligned}$$

(by induction hypothesis)

$$\begin{aligned} =\int _{\Theta ^{d}}\left( \frac{ \Phi ^{d+\chi (d,x)}(t)-\Phi ^{d}(t)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }+\log {(1+\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle )}-\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle \right) \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x) \end{aligned}$$

[by (5.6)]

$$\begin{aligned} =\frac{ \varphi ^{d}(t)-\nu _t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t)}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }+\int _{\Theta ^{d}}\Big ( \log {(1+\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle )}-\langle x^{d},h^{d} \rangle \Big )\nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x), \end{aligned}$$

where \(\varphi ^{d}\) is the continuous deterministic function

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi ^{d}(t)=\sum _{d'<d}\nu ^d_t\left( \Lambda ^{d'}\right) \Phi ^{d'}(t), \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda ^{d'}=X^n\bigcap \left( \mathop {\bigcap }\limits _{\begin{array}{c} 1\le i\le n,\\ d'_i=0 \end{array}}\{x_{i}\ne -1\}\right) \bigcap \left( \mathop {\bigcap }\limits _{\begin{array}{c} 1\le i\le n,\\ d'_i=1 \end{array}}\{x_{i}= -1\}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Thus we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} A^{h,c} K(t,v,d)&= \varphi ^{d}(t)-\nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t) \nonumber \\&+\left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) \left( F^{d}(t,h)- \frac{c}{v}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(8.9)

with \(F^d\) as in (5.12), and the HJB equation becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{{\mathrm {d}}t}\Phi ^{d}(t)&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v -\sup _{h\in H,\, c>0}\left( A^{h,c} K(t,v,d)+ B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \log c \right) \nonumber \\&= B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v + \nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t)-\varphi ^{d}(t)\nonumber \\&- \left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) \sup _{h\in H} F^{d}(t,h) \nonumber \\&- \sup _{c>0}\left( B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \log c - c \frac{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }{v} \right) \nonumber \\&= \nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t)-\varphi ^{d}(t)- \left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) \sup _{h\in H} F^{d}(t,h) \nonumber \\&+B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v - \sup _{c>0}\psi (t,v,c), \end{aligned}$$
(8.10)

with \(\psi (t,v,c)\) as in (8.1). Let us observe that \(\arg \max _{h\in H}F^{d}(t,h)\) is not empty for any \(t\in [0,T]\) because \(H\) is a compact subset of \({\mathbb {R}}^n\) and \(F^{d}\) is continuous, and thus

$$\begin{aligned} \sup _{h\in H} F^{d}(t,h)=F^{d}(t,{\bar{h}}(t,d)), \end{aligned}$$
(8.11)

with \(F^d\) as in (8.1). Therefore, plugging (8.11)–(8.2) into (8.10) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}}{{\mathrm {d}}t}\Phi ^{d}(t)&= \nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t)-\varphi ^{d}(t)- \left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) F^{d}(t,{\bar{h}}(t,d)) \\&+B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\log v - \psi (t,v,{\bar{c}}(t)v) \end{aligned}$$

[by (8.3)]

$$\begin{aligned}&=\nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \Phi ^{d}(t)-\varphi ^{d}(t)- \left( A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \right) F^{d}(t,{\bar{h}}(t,d)) \nonumber \\&\qquad - B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}\left( \log \left( \frac{B \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)}}{A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) }\right) -1 \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(8.12)

Furthermore, note that \(\varphi ^{d}(t)\) and \(\nu ^d_t\left( \Theta ^{d}\right) \) are continuous in \(t\) by Assumption 3.5. Thus, setting \(\Phi ^{d}(\cdot )\) as the unique solution of the ODE (8.12) with terminal condition \(\Phi ^{d}(T)=0\), we have that \(K(t,v,d)\) solves Eq. (5.3) with terminal condition (5.7), and Part (a) is proved.

Part (b). To prove \(K\in {\mathcal D}\) it is sufficient to prove that for any \(\bar{t}\in [0,T]\) and \(({\mathfrak {h}},{\mathfrak {c}})\in {\mathcal A}[\bar{t},T]\),

$$\begin{aligned} K(t,(V,D)^{{\mathfrak {h}},{\mathfrak {c}};\bar{t},v,d}_{t})-\int _{\bar{t}}^{t}A^{{\mathfrak {h}}_{u},{\mathfrak {c}}_u}K(u,(V,D)^{{\mathfrak {h}},{\mathfrak {c}};\bar{t},v,d}_{u}){\mathrm {d}}u \end{aligned}$$
(8.13)

is a martingale. Now, by applying the Itô formula, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm {d}}K(t,(V,D)^{{\mathfrak {h}},{\mathfrak {c}}}_t)=A^{{\mathfrak {h}}_{t},{\mathfrak {c}}_{t}}K(t,(V,D)^{{\mathfrak {h}},{\mathfrak {c}}}_{t}){\mathrm {d}}t+{\mathrm {d}}M_t, \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathrm {d}}M_t&= a(t) {\mathfrak {h}}^{D_t}_t\sigma (t){\mathrm {d}}W_t+\int _{{\mathbb {R}}^n}\Big ( a(t) \log {\big ( 1+\langle x,{\mathfrak {h}}^{D_{t-}}_{t-} \rangle \big )}\\&+\Phi ^{D_{t-}+\chi (D_{t-},x)}(t)-\Phi ^{D_{t-}(t)}\Big )\big ( N(D_{t-},{\mathrm {d}}x,{\mathrm {d}}t)-\nu _t(D_{t-},{\mathrm {d}}x){\mathrm {d}}t \big ), \end{aligned}$$

and where we have set \(a(t):=A +\frac{B}{\delta }\left( 1- \mathrm{e}^{-\delta (T-t)} \right) \). Therefore, to prove the theorem it is sufficient to check that \(M_t\) is a martingale. Since

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb {E}}\left[ \int _{\bar{t}}^T | a(t) {\mathfrak {h}}^{D_t}_t\sigma (u)|^2 {\mathrm {d}}t \right]&\le a^2(0) {\mathbb {E}}\left[ \int _{\bar{t}}^T \left\| {\mathfrak {h}}_t\right\| ^2\left\| \sigma (t)\right\| ^2 {\mathrm {d}}t \right] \\&\le a^2(0) \sup _{h\in H}\left\| h\right\| ^2\int _{\bar{t}}^{T}\left\| \sigma (t)\right\| ^2 {\mathrm {d}}u<+\infty , \end{aligned}$$

the continuous part is a martingale. We observe now that since \({\mathfrak {h}}\) takes values in the compact set \(H\subset \hbox {int}(\cap _{t\in [\bar{t},T]}H_t)\), there exists a constant \(\delta >0\) such that \(1+\langle {\mathfrak {h}}_t,x \rangle \ge \delta \) \(\nu ^d({\mathrm {d}}x)\)-a.s. for any \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\), \(t\in [\bar{t},T]\). Thus, the function \(x\rightarrow \log {(1+\langle {\mathfrak {h}}_t,x \rangle )}\) is bounded from below and with linear growth, and so there is a constant \(C>0\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} |\log {(1+\langle {\mathfrak {h}}_t,x \rangle )}|\le C \sup _{h\in H}\left\| h\right\| \left\| x\right\| \quad \nu ^d({\mathrm {d}}x)\text {-a.s.} \end{aligned}$$
(8.14)

for any \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\), \(t\in [\bar{t},T]\). According now to the notation used in the proof of part (a), we define

$$\begin{aligned} \Theta :=\Theta ^{(0,\ldots ,0)}=\bigcup _{i=1}^{n}\{x_{i}= -1\}, \end{aligned}$$
(8.15)

and finally, to verify the pure jump stochastic integral to be a martingale, we only need to check that for any \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\)

$$\begin{aligned}&{\mathbb {E}}\left[ \int _{\bar{t}}^{T}\int _{{\mathbb {R}}^n}\left| a(t) \log {\big ( 1+\langle x,{\mathfrak {h}}^{D_{t-}}_{t-} \rangle \big )} +\Phi ^{D_{t-}+\chi (D_{t-},x)}(t)-\Phi ^{D_{t-}(t)}\right| ^2 \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x){\mathrm {d}}t \right] \end{aligned}$$

[by (5.6) and (8.15)]

$$\begin{aligned}&=\!{\mathbb {E}}\left[ \!\int _{\bar{t}}^{T}\!\int _{{\mathbb {R}}^n}\left| a(t) \log {\big ( 1\!+\!\langle x,{\mathfrak {h}}^{D_{t-}}_{t-} \rangle \big )} \!+\!{1\!\!1}_{\Theta }(x)\left( \Phi ^{D_{t-}\!+\!\chi (D_{t-},x)}(t)\!-\!\Phi ^{D_{t-}(t)}\right) \right| ^2 \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x){\mathrm {d}}t \right] \end{aligned}$$

(by the triangular inequality)

$$\begin{aligned}&\le 2 a^2(0)\, {\mathbb {E}}\left[ \int _{\bar{t}}^{T}\int _{{\mathbb {R}}^n}\left| \log {\big ( 1+\langle x,{\mathfrak {h}}^{D_{t-}}_{t-} \rangle \big )}\right| ^2 \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x){\mathrm {d}}t \right] \\&\quad +2{\mathbb {E}}\left[ \int _{\bar{t}}^{T}\int _{\Theta }\left| \Phi ^{D_{t-}+\chi (D_{t-},x)}(t)-\Phi ^{D_{t-}}(t)\right| ^2 \nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x){\mathrm {d}}t \right] \end{aligned}$$

[by (8.14) and Assumption 3.3]

$$\begin{aligned} \le 2 a^2(0) \int _{\bar{t}}^{T} C^2 \sup _{h\in H}\left\| h\right\| ^2 \int _{{\mathbb {R}}^n}\left\| x\right\| ^2\nu ^d_t({\mathrm {d}}x)\!+\!2 \left( \max _{d'\in \{0,1\}^n}\Phi ^{d'}(t)\right) ^2\nu ^d_t(\Theta ){\mathrm {d}}t\!<\!+\infty . \end{aligned}$$

Part (c). By (8.9), (8.11) and Lemma 8.2 we have

$$\begin{aligned} ({\bar{h}}(t,d),{\bar{c}}(t)v)\in \arg \max _{h\in H,\, c>0}A^{h,c} K(t,v,d)\quad \forall v\in {\mathbb {R}}^{+} \end{aligned}$$
(8.16)

for any \(t\in [0,T]\) and \(d\in \{0,1\}^n\). Therefore, the process \((\bar{{\mathfrak {h}}}_t,\bar{{\mathfrak {c}}}_t)\) defined in (5.14) satisfies (5.9) and the statement follows by Theorem 5.2. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pagliarani, S., Vargiolu, T. Portfolio optimization in a defaultable Lévy-driven market model. OR Spectrum 37, 617–654 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-014-0374-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-014-0374-7

Keywords

Navigation