Skip to main content
Log in

Approval mechanism to solve prisoner’s dilemma: comparison with Varian’s compensation mechanism

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

After having played a prisoner’s dilemma, players can approve or reject the other’s choice of cooperation or defection. If both players approve the other’s choice, the outcome is the result of the chosen strategies in the prisoner’s dilemma; however, if either rejects the other’s choice, the outcome is the same as if they had mutually defected from the prisoner’s dilemma. In theory, such an approval mechanism implements cooperation in backward elimination of weakly dominated strategies, although this is not the case in the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium. By contrast, the compensation mechanism proposed by Varian (Am Econ Rev 84(5):1278–1293, 1994) implements cooperation in the latter but not in the former. This result motivates the present experimental study of the two mechanisms. The approval mechanism sessions yield a cooperation rate of 90% in the first period and 93.2% across periods, while the compensation mechanism sessions yield a cooperation rate of 63.3% in the first period and 75.2% across periods. In addition, the backward elimination of weakly dominated strategies better predicts subjects’ behavior than does the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in both mechanism sessions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This holds provided the payoff asymmetry in the underlying prisoner’s dilemma is not too large (Qin 2005).

  2. See Hamaguchi et al. (2003), Bracht et al. (2008), and Midler et al. (2015). For Moore-Repullo SPNE mechanism experiments, see Fehr et al. (2014).

  3. Selten (1975) and Kalai (1981) applied BEWDS to game theory.

  4. In this vein, Saijo et al. (2016), who developed a working paper version of the present paper, characterized the AM using certain no-punishment and no-coercion conditions. Kimbrough and Sheremeta (2013) presented situations in which side payments assumed in the CM—collusion in a market, patent races, and R&D competition—might not be legal. Guala (2012) pointed out that there is little anthropological evidence that humankind has used private punishment.

  5. The AM differs from the money-back guarantee mechanism, as follows. If either player, but not both, chooses C, then the $10 contribution is returned to the cooperator. The money-back guarantee mechanism cannot generate (7,17), while the AM achieves (7,17) if players choose (CD) and then both choose y. The same argument applies to Brams and Kilgour’s (2009) concept of voting between the outcomes of all-C and all-D in order to overcome PD. The AM has an advantage in terms of welfare compared to the money-back guarantee mechanism and Brams and Kilgour’s (2009) voting. To observe this, consider a case in which only player 1 is sufficiently altruistic that player 1’s utility is given by (player 1’s material payoff) \(+{\uprho } \) (player 2’s material payoff), \({\uprho } >4/3\). Assume that players know each other’s payoff function. Then, the outcome of CD maximizes the sum of utilities of two players among four possible outcomes of the PD in Fig. 1. The AM implements CD, while neither the money-back guarantee mechanism nor Brams and Kilgour’s (2009) voting mechanism does.

  6. A path is a list of what each player does in each stage: player 1’s choice between C and D, player 2’s choice between C and D, player 1’s choice between y and n, and player 2’s choice between y and n. For simplicity, hereafter, we write a path as CDny instead of (CDny). In the AM, we have 96 SPNEs. See Saijo et al. (2016) for more details.

  7. The risk dominance criterion, even with subgame perfection, cannot select the strategy uniquely, unlike in the case of BEWDS. The off-path prediction by risk dominance is redundant. To observe this, consider subgame CD in Fig. 2. According to risk dominance, an NE with greater product deviation loss is more likely to occur (e.g., Blonski and Spagnolo 2015). Since the product of loss deviating from NE (ny) and that of (nn) are zero, both are predicted in light of risk dominance. However, seven out of the eight observed choices in subgame CD are (ny), as reported in Table 2.

  8. These results are due to the discreteness of strategies.

  9. The pairings were anonymous and determined in advance so that no two subjects were paired more than once.

  10. We used Andreoni and Miller’s (1993) method for statistical testing. We first calculated the average cooperation rate for each subject across periods, followed by the test statistic using the averages to eliminate cross-period correlation.

  11. The cooperation rate in the PD is slightly lower than that recorded in previous experiments. For example, Cooper et al. (1996) and Andreoni and Miller (1993) found 20 and 18% cooperation rates, respectively.

  12. Additional experiments on the AM and PD, in which subjects play the game in only one period, provide similar results, suggesting that the AM works without repetition. The data and results are available upon request.

  13. Selten’s index has been used in the literature on testing revealed preference. Our notations follow those of Beatty and Crawford (2011). Forsythe et al. (1996) applied Selten’s index to a voting game experiment.

  14. Although many people advocated the Paris Accord, the national pledges by countries to cut emissions are voluntary and do not involve penalty. “At best, scientists who have analyzed it say it will cut global greenhouse gas emissions by about half the required amount to avert a potential increase in atmospheric temperatures of 2 degrees Celsius or 3.6 degrees Fahrenheit” (NYTimes, 2015).

References

  • Andreoni J, Varian H (1999) Preplay contracting in the prisoners’ dilemma. Proc Natl Acad Sci 96(19):10933–10938

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni J, Miller JH (1993) Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner’s dilemma: experimental evidence. Econ J 103(418):570–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks JS, Plott CR, Porter DP (1988) An experimental analysis of unanimity in public goods provision mechanisms. Rev Econ Stud 55(2):301–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty T, Crawford I (2011) How demanding is the revealed preference approach to demand? Am Econ Rev 101(6):2782–2795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonski M, Spagnolo G (2015) Prisoners’ other dilemma. Intl J Game Theory 44(1):61–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracht J, Figuieres C, Ratto M (2008) Relative performance of two simple incentive mechanisms in a public goods experiment. J Pub Econ 92(1):54–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams SJ, Kilgour DM (2009) How democracy resolves conflict in difficult games. In: Levin S (ed) Games, groups, and the global good. Springer, Berlin, pp 229–241

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Charness G, Fréchette GR, Qin C-Z (2007) Endogenous transfers in the prisoner’s dilemma game: an experimental test of cooperation and coordination. GEB 60(2):287–306

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y (2008) Incentive-compatible mechanisms for pure public goods: a survey of experimental literature. In: Plott CR, Smith VL (eds) The handbook of experimental economics results. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 625–643

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper R, DeJong DV, Forsythe R, Ross TW (1996) Cooperation without reputation: experimental evidence from prisoner’s dilemma games. GEB 12(2):187–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Davenport C (2015) Nations approve landmark climate accord in Paris. New York Times. Retrieved November 7, 2017 http://www.nytimes.com/2015/12/13/world/europe/climate-change-accord-paris.html

  • Fehr E, Gächter S (2000) Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 90(4):980–994

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr E, Powell M, Wilkening T (2014) Handing out guns at a knife fight: behavioral limitations of subgame-perfect implementation, ECON – Working Paper 171, University of Zurich

  • Fischbacher U (2007) z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10(2):171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe R, Rietz T, Myerson R, Weber R (1996) An experimental study of voting rules and polls in three-candidate elections. Intl J Game Theory 25(3):355–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guala F (2012) Reciprocity: weak or strong? What punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate. Behav Brain Sci 35(01):1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamaguchi Y, Mitani S, Saijo T (2003) Does the Varian mechanism work? Emissions trading as an example. Intl J Bus Econ 2(2):85–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang X, Masuda T, Okano Y, Saijo T (2017) Cooperation among behaviorally heterogeneous players in social dilemma with stay or leave decisions. University of Arizona Department of Economics Working Paper series 2017-16

  • Kalai E (1981) Preplay negotiations and the prisoner’s dilemma. Math Soc Sci 1(4):375–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimbrough EO, Sheremeta RM (2013) Side-payments and the costs of conflict. Intl J Ind Organ 31:278–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masuda T, Okano Y, Saijo T (2014) The minimum approval mechanism implements the efficient public good allocation theoretically and experimentally. Games Econ Behav 83:73–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Midler E, Figuières C, Willinger M (2015) Choice overload, coordination and inequality: three hurdles to the effectiveness of the compensation mechanism? Soc Choice Welf 45(3):513–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott CR, Smith VL (2008) Handbooks in economics 28: handbook of experimental economics results. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Qin CZ (2005) Penalties and rewards as inducements to cooperate. Department of Economics, University of California-Santa Barbara

  • Saijo T, Okano Y, Yamakawa T (2016) The approval mechanism experiment: a solution to prisoner’s dilemma. KUT-SDES Working Paper no. 2015-12 (Revised), Kochi University of Technology

  • Saijo T, Shen J (2018) Mate choice mechanism for solving a quasi-dilemma. J Behav Exp Econ 72:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten R (1975) Reexamination of the perfectness concept for equilibrium points in extensive games. Intl J Game Theory 4(1):25–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selten R (1991) Properties of a measure of predictive success. Math Soc Sci 21(2):153–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian HR (1994) A solution to the problem of externalities when agents are well-informed. Am Econ Rev 84(5):1278–1293

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tatsuyoshi Saijo.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

We thank the associate editor and two anonymous referees for their useful comments and suggestions. Masuda is also grateful for helpful comments from Ryan Tierney. This research was supported by the Suntory Foundation; the Joint Usage/Research Center at the Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University; Scientific Research A (24243028) and Challenging Exploratory Research (16K13354) of the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science; the Research Institute for Humanity and Nature (RIHN Project Number 14200122); and “Experimental Social Sciences: Toward Experimentally-based New Social Sciences for the 21st Century,” a project funded by a Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research on Priority Areas from the Ministry of Education, Science and Culture of Japan. We also thank the Economics Department, Osaka University, for allowing us to use their computer laboratory.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 356 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Saijo, T., Masuda, T. & Yamakawa, T. Approval mechanism to solve prisoner’s dilemma: comparison with Varian’s compensation mechanism. Soc Choice Welf 51, 65–77 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1107-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-017-1107-z

Navigation