Skip to main content
Log in

A comparison of milestone contract and royalty contract under critical value criterion in R&D alliance

  • Focus
  • Published:
Soft Computing Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper attempts to better understand contract type and risk attitude in R&D alliance under information asymmetry, that is, how the marketer designs and chooses optimal contract between royalty contract and milestone contract and how the innovator’s risk attitude and asymmetric information affect the marketer’s optimal contract strategies and profits. We use principal–agent models to formulate the marketer’s contracting problem under asymmetric information about the innovator’s innovation expertise and unobservable efforts. We find that, compared to the case under full information in both contracting structures, the marketer should distort the commission rate upwards under dual asymmetric information when the innovator is risk averse or downwards to lower innovation–expertise and risk-loving innovator; nevertheless, the marketer should offer the first-best contract. Furthermore, investigating the impacts of information asymmetry on the marketer’s profits under two information structures, we find that dual asymmetric information harms the marketer’s profit, especially when the innovator’s effort marginal efficiency is higher. Finally, by comparing the marketer’s profits in two types of contracts, we give the specific regions that milestone contract or royalty contract benefits the marketer better under different information structures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Explore related subjects

Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.

Notes

  1. https://baijiahao.baidu.com/s?id=1611190363631137958&wfr=spider&for=pc.

References

  • Bergen M, Dutta S, Walker OC Jr (1992) Agency relationships in marketing: a review of the implications and applications of agency and related theories. J Mark 56(3):1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya S, Gaba V, Hasija S (2014) A comparison of milestone-based and buyout options contracts for coordinating R&D partnerships. Manag Sci 61(5):963–978

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cao J, Hu L, Yao Q, Zhou G (2015) Coordination mechanism between government and reverse supply chain system based on incentive theory. J Syst Eng 30(6):821–835

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chang B (2017) Adverse selection and liquidity distortion. Rev Econ Stud 85(1):275–306

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Chao RO, Lichtendahl KC, Grushka-Cockayne Y (2014) Incentives in a stage-gate process. Prod Oper Manag 23(8):1286–1298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen H, Yan Y, Ma N, Yang L (2018) Coopetition strategy and pricing timing in an outsourcing supply chain with uncertain operation risks. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst https://doi.org/10.1109/TFUZZ.2018.2821106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Lan Y, Zhao R (2018) Impacts of risk attitude and outside option on compensation contracts under different information structures. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 17(1):13–47

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Crama P, Reyck BD, Degraeve Z (2008) Milestone payments or royalties? Contract design for R&D licensing. Oper Res 56(6):1539–1552

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Crama P, De Reyck B, Taneri N (2016) Licensing contracts: control rights, options, and timing. Manag Sci 63(4):1131–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellsberg D (1961) Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Q J Econ 75(4):643–669

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fu Y, Chen Z, Lan Y (2018) The impacts of private risk aversion magnitude and moral hazard in R&D project under uncertain environment. Soft Comput 22(16):5231–5246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He Z, Li S, Wei B, Yu J (2013) Uncertainty, risk, and incentives: theory and evidence. Manag Sci 60(1):206–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont JJ (1994) The new economics of regulation ten years after. Econometrica 62(3):507–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lan Y, Zhao R, Tang W (2014) A fuzzy supply chain contract problem with pricing and warranty. J Intell Fuzzy Syst 26(3):1527–1538

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Li X, Qin Z (2014) Interval portfolio selection models within the framework of uncertainty theory. Econ Model 41:338–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu B (2007) Uncertainty theory. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Luo J, Kaul A, Seo H (2018) Winning us with trifles: adverse selection in the use of philanthropy as insurance. Strateg Manage J 39:2591–2617. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2935

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manso G (2011) Motivating innovation. J Finance 66(5):1823–1860

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mu R, Lan Y, Tang W (2013) An uncertain contract model for rural migrant worker’s employment problems. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 12(1):29–39

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast C (1999) The provision of incentives in firms. J Econ Lit 37:7–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahoo A (2008) Successful pharmabiotech alliance strategies: driving synergies, avoiding failure and managing relationships. Business Insights, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Taneri N, De Meyer A (2017) Contract theory: impact on biopharmaceutical alliance structure and performance. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 19(3):453–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu X, Zhao R, Tang W (2014) Uncertain agency models with multi-dimensional incomplete information based on confidence level. Fuzzy Optim Decis Mak 13(2):231–258

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Wu X, Lan Y, Liu H (2014) Optimal revenue-sharing contract based on forecasting effort for uncertain agency problem. Int J Mach Learn Cybern 5(6):971–979

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu Y, Ramachandran K, Krishnan V (2014) Managing cost salience and procrastination in projects: compensation and team composition. Prod Oper Manag 23(8):1299–1311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xiao W, Xu Y (2012) The impact of royalty contract revision in a multistage strategic R&D alliance. Manag Sci 58(12):2251–2271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yang K, Lan Y, Zhao R (2017) Monitoring mechanisms in new product development with risk-averse project manager. J Intell Manuf 28(3):667–681

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao K, Li X (2012) Uncertain alternating renewal process and its application. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst 20(6):1154–1160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu X, Lan Y, Zhao R (2018) Cooperation royalty contract design in research and development alliances: help vs. knowledge-sharing. Eur J Oper Res 268(2):740–754

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Q, Zhang J, Zaccour G, Tang W (2018) Strategic technology licensing in a supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 267(1):162–175

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant Nos. 71771166, 71771165 and 11761025), Yanta Scholars Foundation of Xi’an University of Finance and Economics and Tianjin Natural Science Foundation (Grant No. 18JCQNJC04200).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhihua Chen.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human or animal participants performed by any of the authors.

Informed consent

Informed consent is obtained from all individual participants included in the study.

Additional information

Communicated by Y. Ni.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

Based on the expected value criterion, the marketer’s expected profit

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _m=(k_1\theta +k_2e_1)(1-w_1(\theta ))+l_1e-\frac{1}{2}e^2-w_0(\theta ). \end{aligned}$$

Based on the critical value criterion, if the innovator accepts milestone contract, his \(\alpha \)-utility

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )= & {} \left( k_1\theta +k_2e_1+\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \\&\quad \times w_1(\theta )+w_0(\theta )-\frac{1}{2}e_1^2. \end{aligned}$$

Because the marketer’s expected profit is decreasing in the fixed payment \(w_0\), at optimality, the individual rationality constraint should be binding, i.e., \(\pi _m(\theta ,\theta )=0\). Thus, substituting the fixed payment into the marketer’s objective function, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _m= & {} w_1(\theta )\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }+k_1\theta +k_2e_1+l_1e \\&-\frac{1}{2}e^2-\frac{1}{2}e_1^2, \end{aligned}$$

which is concave in \(e_1\) and e, respectively. Using the first-order condition, the optimal efforts can be solved as: \(e_1=k_2\) and \(e=l_1\). By substituting these optimal effort levels into the marketer’s simplified problem above, we simplify the firm’s problem to

$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \displaystyle \max _{w_1(\theta )} w_1(\theta )\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }+k_1\theta +\frac{1}{2}\left( k_2^2+l_1^2\right) \\ \text{ subject } \text{ to: }\\ \displaystyle \quad 0\leqslant w_1(\theta )\leqslant 1,\quad \forall \theta \in [\overline{\theta },\underline{\theta }].\\ \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Because the objective function is piecewise linear in \(w_1(\theta )\), we focus on the corner point solutions \(w_1(\theta )\in \{0,1\}\). To ensure the marketer can get a positive and maximum profit, if \(\alpha >1/2\), the optimal incentive compensation rate is \(w_1^F(\theta )=0\); if \(\alpha \leqslant 1/2\), the optimal incentive compensation rate is \(w_1^F(\theta )=1\). The corresponding optimal fixed payment \(w_0^F(\theta )\) for the innovator can be derived based on the binding individual rationality constraint immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition2

Similar to the Proof of Proposition 1. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 1

For part (i) and part (ii), if the innovator’s true innovation expertise is \(\theta \) but he selects the milestone contract \((w_0(\hat{\theta }),w_1(\hat{\theta }))\), his \(\alpha \)-utility

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta },e_1)= & {} \left( k_1\theta +k_2e_1+\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \\&\times w_1(\hat{\theta })+w_0(\hat{\theta })-\frac{1}{2}e_1^2. \end{aligned}$$

By the first-order condition, the innovator maximizes his profit by exerting an effort \(e_1=k_2w_1(\hat{\theta })\). The innovator’s profit under this optimal effort is

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta })= & {} \frac{1}{2}k_2^2w_1^2(\hat{\theta })+\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \\&\times w_1(\hat{\theta })+w_0(\hat{\theta }). \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, if the innovator selects the contract \((w_0(\theta ),w_1(\theta ))\) based on his true innovation expertise \(\theta \), his profit

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )= & {} \frac{1}{2}k_2^2w_1^2(\theta ) +\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \\&\times w_1(\theta )+w_0(\theta ). \end{aligned}$$

The incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection means that the innovator can obtain his maximal profit \(\pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta })\) if and only if \(\hat{\theta }=\theta \). In other words, the innovator with innovation expertise \(\theta \) has no incentive to pretend to be other idea value \(\hat{\theta }\). Thus, \(\pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta })\) satisfies the first-order condition (i.e., local incentive compatibility constraint) \(\frac{\partial \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta })}{\partial \hat{\theta }}\bigm |_{\hat{\theta }=\theta }=0\) and the second-order condition \(\frac{\partial ^{2} \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta })}{\partial \hat{\theta }^{2}}\bigm |_{\hat{\theta }=\theta }\leqslant 0\). The local incentive compatibility constraint:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \frac{\mathrm {d}w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta } +k_2^2w_1(\theta ) \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }\nonumber \\&\quad +\frac{\mathrm {d} w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }=0. \end{aligned}$$
(1)

And the second-order condition:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }+k_2^2w_1(\theta )\right) \frac{\mathrm {d}^2w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta ^2} \nonumber \\&\quad +\,k_2^2\left( \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }\right) ^2 +\frac{\mathrm {d}^2w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta ^2}\leqslant 0. \end{aligned}$$
(2)

If we further differentiate the local incentive compatibility constraint with the respect to \(\theta \), we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned}&\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1\!-\!\alpha }{\alpha }\!+\!k_2^2w_1(\theta )\right) \frac{\mathrm {d}^2w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta ^2}\nonumber \\&\quad +\,k_2^2\left( \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }\right) ^2 +\frac{\mathrm {d}^2w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta ^2}\!+\!k_1\frac{\mathrm {d}w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }\!=\!0. \end{aligned}$$
(3)

On the basis of (2) and (3), we gain the monotonicity condition

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }\leqslant 0,\quad \forall \theta \in [\overline{\theta },\underline{\theta }]. \end{aligned}$$
(4)

Suppose, next, that both the local incentive compatibility and monotonicity conditions hold. Then it must be the case that all the innovator’s incentive compatibility conditions hold. To see this result, without loss of generality, suppose that \(\theta <\hat{\theta }\). By integrating the local incentive compatibility condition (1) and using the monotonicity condition (4), we can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} w_{0}(\hat{\theta })-w_{0}(\theta )\leqslant (w_1(\theta )-w_1(\hat{\theta }))\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) . \end{aligned}$$

That is to say

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )\geqslant \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta }),\quad \forall \theta ,\hat{\theta }\in [\overline{\theta },\underline{\theta }]. \end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, if \(\theta \geqslant \hat{\theta }\), by integrating the local incentive compatibility condition (1) and using the monotonicity condition (4), we also can obtain

$$\begin{aligned} w_{0}(\theta )-w_{0}(\hat{\theta })\geqslant (w_1(\hat{\theta })-w_1(\theta ))\left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) . \end{aligned}$$

That is to say

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )\geqslant \pi _m(\theta ,\hat{\theta }),\quad \forall \theta ,\hat{\theta }\in [\overline{\theta },\underline{\theta }]. \end{aligned}$$

This result establishes the equivalence between the monotonicity condition together with the local incentive compatibility condition and the full set of the innovator’s incentive constraints.

Differentiating \(\pi _m(\theta ,\theta )\) with respect to \(\theta \) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\mathrm {d} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }= & {} \left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \frac{\mathrm {d}w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta } \\&+\,k_2^2w_1(\theta )\frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }+\frac{\mathrm {d} w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }+k_1w_1(\theta )\nonumber \\= & {} k_1w_1(\theta )\geqslant 0. \end{aligned}$$

The individual rationality constraint is equivalent to

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\underline{\theta },\underline{\theta })\geqslant 0. \end{aligned}$$

The constraint is binding under the optimal mechanism because the marketer can reap the redundant profit under the optimal incentive mechanism, so that \(\pi _m(\underline{\theta },\underline{\theta })=0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 3

Because

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \frac{\partial \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )}{\partial \theta }=k_1w_1(\theta ), \end{aligned}$$

we can derive

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )=\int ^{\theta }_{\underline{\theta }}\frac{\partial \pi _m(\theta ,\theta )}{\partial \theta }-\pi _m(\underline{\theta },\underline{\theta })=\int ^{\theta }_{\underline{\theta }}k_1w_1(x)\mathrm {d}x. \end{aligned}$$

Combining the definition of \(\pi _m(\theta ,\theta )\) yields

$$\begin{aligned} w_0(\theta )= & {} \int ^{\theta }_{\underline{\theta }}k_1w_1(x)\mathrm {d}x- \left( k_1\theta +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\right) \nonumber \\&w_1(\theta )-\frac{1}{2}k_2^2w_1^2(\theta ). \end{aligned}$$

By substituting the fixed wage into the objective function, we can derive

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _m^D= & {} \int ^{\overline{\theta }}_{\underline{\theta }} \left[ k_1\theta \!+\!k_2^2w_1(\theta )\! +\!l_1e -\frac{1}{2}e^2-\frac{1}{2}k_2^2w_1^2(\theta )\right. \\&\left. +\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1\!-\!\alpha }{\alpha }w_1(\theta ) -\int ^{\theta }_{\underline{\theta }}k_1w_1(x)\mathrm {d}x\right] f(\theta )\mathrm {d}\theta . \end{aligned}$$

We can use the first-order condition \(\frac{\partial \Pi _m^D}{\partial e}=0\) to yield the first-best effort level \(e^D=l_1\). Substituting it into the objective function and ignoring the monotonicity constraint in Lemma 1, the marketer’s problem can be written as unconstrained optimization problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \max _{0\leqslant w_1(\theta )\leqslant 1} \Pi _m^D= & {} \int ^{\overline{\theta }}_{\underline{\theta }} \left[ k_1\theta +\frac{1}{2}l_1^2+(k_2^2-k_1h(\theta ) \right. \\&+\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi } \ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }w_1(\theta ) \\&\left. -\frac{1}{2}k_2^2w_1^2(\theta )\right] f(\theta )\mathrm {d}\theta . \end{aligned}$$

The first-order variation and the second-order variation of the marketer’s expected profit are derived as

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \delta \Pi _m^D= & {} \int ^{\overline{\theta }}_{\underline{\theta }}\left[ k_2^2-k_1h(\theta )+\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }-k_2^2w_1(\theta )\right] \\&f(\theta )[\delta w_1(\theta )]\mathrm {d}\theta , \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \displaystyle \delta ^2\Pi _m^D=-\int ^{\overline{\theta }}_{\underline{\theta }}k_2^2f(\theta )[\delta w_1(\theta )]^2\mathrm {d}\theta . \end{aligned}$$

If \(\alpha <1/2\), there are two cases: (i) \(\underline{\theta }\leqslant \theta \leqslant \theta _{12}\) and (ii) \(\theta _{12}<\theta \leqslant \overline{\theta }\) (here the threshold \(\theta _{12}\) satisfies \(\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }-k_1 h(\theta )=0\)). For case (i), we can obtain \(w_1^D=1+\frac{1}{k_2^2}(\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }- h(\theta ))\). For case (ii), we can obtain \(w_1^D(\theta )=1\). On the other hand, if \(\alpha \geqslant 1/2\), there are two cases: (iii) \(\underline{\theta }\leqslant \theta \leqslant \theta _{11}\) and (iv) \(\theta _{11}<\theta \leqslant \overline{\theta }\) (here the threshold \(\theta _{11}\) satisfies \(\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }-k_1 h(\theta )+k_2^2=0\)). For case (iii), we can obtain \(w_1^D(\theta )=0\). For case (iv), we can obtain \(w_1^D=1+\frac{1}{k_2^2}(\frac{\sqrt{3}\sigma _1}{\pi }\ln \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }- h(\theta ))\). Following the determinate optimal incentive commission rate \(w_1^D(\theta )\), the corresponding optimal fixed payment \(w_0^D(\theta )\) and the optimal effort levels \(e_1^D\), \(e^D\) can be obtained immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 2

Similar to the Proof of Lemma 1. \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 4

Similar to the Proof of Proposition 3.

\(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 5

The result is derived directly by comparing the contracts shown in Propositions 14. \(\square \)

Proof of Propositions 6–8

The result is derived directly by comparing the marketer’s profits shown in Corollaries 12. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fu, Y., Chen, Z., Liu, Z. et al. A comparison of milestone contract and royalty contract under critical value criterion in R&D alliance. Soft Comput 24, 2447–2462 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-018-03727-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00500-018-03727-0

Keywords