Skip to main content
Log in

Models of travel demand with endogenous preference change and heterogeneous agents

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Geographical Systems Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the literatures of regional science, urban economics, and urban development planning, a working assumption is that individuals respond to incentives and regulations, given their preferences. Models for planning and policy analyses are used to consider what might occur if the incentives or regulations were different. In these models, however, preferences are usually assumed to be given and stable, and agents are usually assumed to be homogeneous. This paper focuses on the implications of making preferences in models of policy implementation endogenously determined and time varying heterogeneous agents. We consider first the recent literature on intertemporal choice and preference change, which cuts across many disciplines, and more briefly the literature on norm-regarding behavior. We then elaborate a simple model of transportation demand—from a static to a dynamic orientation, from fixed and exogenously given preferences of strictly self-regarding agents to endogenously determined and policy-induced preferences of heterogeneous agents—and illustrate its characteristics with simple numerical examples.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Most generally, in his review of the literature on endogenous preferences, Bowles (1998) defines preferences as “reasons for behavior, that is, attributes of individuals that (along with their beliefs and capacities) account for the actions they take in a given situation (p. 78)”. As such, Bowles sees preferences as being different from and going beyond mere tastes. See also Innocenti (1996) for a somewhat different take on the relationship between preferences and tastes.

  2. The problem statement is more general that it may seem because the elements of q can be broken out more finely according to alternative routes and departure times, etc.

  3. Roy’s identity states that the Marshallian (or ordinary market) demand for good i is given by the negative of the ratio of the partial derivative of the indirect utility function taken w.r.t. the price of the good to the partial derivative of this function taken w.r.t. the aggregate expenditure level. See e.g., Varian (1978), p. 93.

  4. These values were chosen on the basis of past experience in working with demand systems of this type, intuition, and experimentation. They do not correspond to any empirical case that we are aware of. Note that if the exponential growth rates of \( p_{1}^{x} ,p_{2}^{x} ,{\text{ and }}c \) are identical, Z is constant.

  5. When the rates of decay in consumer capital are the same, the decay factor has no effect.

  6. The solution paths obtained for all simulations reflect stable ‘growth’ paths to which consumption patterns will return after exogenous shocks or learning effects occur. This property is due to the form of disequilibrium adjustment adapted for the model and the values of the adjustment parameters chosen. See Anderson and Blundell (1983).

References

  • Anderson GJ, Blundell RW (1983) Testing restrictions in a flexible dynamic demand system. Rev Econ Stud 50:397–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1996) Accounting for tastes. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Murphy KM (1988) A theory of rational addiction. J Polit Econ 96:675–700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S (1998) Endogenous preferences: the cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. J Econ Lit 36:75–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Gintis H (2006) Prosocial emotions. In: Blume LE, Durlauf SN (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system, III. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 339–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Hwang SH (2008) Social preferences and public economics: mechanism design when social preferences depend on incentives. J Public Econ 92:1811–1820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooper RJ, Mclaren KR (1992) An empirically oriented demand system with improved regularity properties. Can J Econ 25:652–668

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1992) Understanding consumption. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A, Muellbauer J (1980) An almost ideal demand system. Am Econ Rev 70:312–326

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert WE (1982) Duality approaches to microeconomic theory. In: Arrow K, Intriligator MD (eds) Handbook of mathematical economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 535–599

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaghy KP (1996) Models of policy implementation with endogenous preference change. In Paper presented at the North American meetings of the regional science association international, Washington, DC, November 14–17

  • Donaghy KP, Schintler LA (1994) Optimal policies for reducing congestion of major commuting arteries in a growing urbanized area. J Plann Educ Res 13:189–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durlauf S (2005) Complexity and empirical economics. Econ J 115:F225–F243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster J (1984) Ulysses and the Sirens. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster J (1998) Emotions and economic theory. J Econ Lit 36:47–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank RH (1988) Passions within reason: the strategic role of the emotions. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis H, Bowles S, Boyd R, Fehr E (eds) Moral sentiments and material interests: The foundations of cooperation in economic life, MIT Press: Cambridge

  • Gorman WM (1976) Tricks with utility functions. In: Artis M, Nobay R (eds) Essays in economic analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 211–243

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg HJ, Perskalla WP (1971) A review of quasi-convex functions. Oper Res 19:1553–1570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heaton J (1990) The interaction between time-nonseparable preferences and time aggregation. Sloan School MIT working paper 3181–90 EFA

  • Hernstein RJ, Prelec D (1992) A theory of addiction. In: Loewenstein G, Elster J (eds) Choice over time. Russel Sage Foundation, New York, pp 331–360

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman A (1985) Against parsimony. Econ Philos 1:7–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins LD (1974) Plan, project, policy: mathematical programming and planning theory. Environ Plann A 6:419–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Innocenti A (1996) Alternative approaches to the theory of consumer choice with endogenous tastes. University of Sienna, WP 660

  • Intriligator MD, Sheshinski E (1986) Toward a theory of planning. In: Heller WP, Starr RM, Starret DA (eds) Social choice and public decision making. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 135–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein G, Elster J (eds) (1992) Choice over time. Russel Sage Foundation, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • March JG (1978) Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice. Bell J Econ 9:587–608

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1978) Cost, revenue, and profit functions. In: Fuss M, McFadden D (eds) Production economics: a dual approach to theory and applications, vol 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Muellbauer J (1975) Aggregation, income distribution, and consumer demand. Rev Econ Stud 42:525–545

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (2000) Collective action and the evolution of social norms. J Econ Perspect 14:137–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen A (1977) Rational fools: a critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philos Public Aff 6:317–344

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone R (1966) The changing pattern of consumption. In: Stone R (ed) Mathematics in the social sciences and other essays. Chapman and Hall, London, pp 190–203

    Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa H (1968) Time preference, the consumption function, and optimum asset holdings. In: Wolfe JN (ed) Value, capital and growth: papers in honor of Sir John Hicks. Aldine, Chicago, pp 485–504

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian H (1978) Microeconomic analysis. W.W. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • von Weiszacker CC (1971) Notes on endogenous change of tastes. J Econ Theory 3:335–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

An earlier version of this article was presented in August 2008 at the European meetings of the Regional Science Association International in Liverpool, England. Comments and suggestions for improvement of the article by a discussant, the guest editor, and an anonymous referee are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kieran P. Donaghy.

Additional information

Paper prepared for the European Meetings of the Regional Science Association International, August 27–30, 2008, Liverpool, England.

Technical appendix: properties of the MPIGLOG demand system

Technical appendix: properties of the MPIGLOG demand system

To discuss the regularity properties of Eq. 2, which we reprise here as

$$ U(c,p) = \ln (c/P1)\,(c^{\eta } /P2), $$
(16)

it is helpful to recall the set of conditions associated with regular indirect utility functions that are dual to cost functions. From standard duality theory (Diewert 1982; McFadden 1978), the indirect utility functions should satisfy the following conditions:

  • U1: U is HD0 in (c, p),

  • U2: U is non-decreasing in c,

  • U3: U is non-increasing in p,

  • U4: U is quasi-convex in p.

If P1 and P2 are positive functions, HD1 and HDη, respectively, and η ≥ 0, (2) will satisfy U1 and U2. If P1 and P2 are also non-decreasing in prices, then U3 will be satisfied over the region where c ≥ 0. Finally, concavity of P1 and P2, when c ≥ P1, ensures quasi-convexity of U in p (Greenberg and Perskalla 1971), although concavity of P2 also requires that 0 ≤ η ≤ 1.

As noted above, applying Roy’s identity to (16) yields expenditure share equations of the form

$$ s_{j} = [\varepsilon_{1j} + \varepsilon_{2j} \,\ln (c/P1)]/[1 + \eta \,\ln (c/P1)], $$
(17)

where \( s_{j} = p_{j} q_{j} /c, \, \varepsilon_{ij} = \partial \ln \,P_{i} /\partial \ln \,p_{j} , \, \sum\nolimits_{j} {\varepsilon_{1j} = 1.0{\text{ and }}\sum\nolimits_{j} {\varepsilon_{2j} = \eta .} } \)

In the region c ≥ P1, ln(c/P1) will be non-negative. Thus restricting the price elasticities of P1 and P2, \( \varepsilon_{1j} {\text{ and }}\varepsilon_{2j} , \) to be non-negative will ensure that \( 0 \le s_{j} \le 1. \) Following Deaton and Muellbauer (1980), Cooper and Mclaren 1992 take the MPIGLOG share equations to indicate that, for given prices and rising income, the share s j moves monotonically from ɛ 1j , the level of the subsistence expenditure share for the ‘poor’, toward \( (\varepsilon_{2j} /\eta ) \), the asymptote share level for the ‘rich.’

Some insight into (17) can be gained by defining the following expression:

$$ Z = \eta \,{ \ln }(c/P1)/[1 + \eta \,\ln (c/P1)]. $$
(18)

Then, the share equations can be rewritten in terms of Z as

$$ s_{j} = \varepsilon_{1j} (1 - Z) + (\varepsilon_{2j} /\eta )Z, $$
(19)

that is, as weighted averages of the shares of the ‘rich’, \( (\varepsilon_{2j} /\eta ) \) and ‘poor,’ ɛ 1j .

It is apparent from the form of the share equations that the potentially unbounded variable, ‘real expenditures’, (c/P1), enters the right-hand side only through the bounded variable, Z, and the potentially unbounded price term enters through the HD0 elasticity terms ɛ 1j and ɛ 2j . From the perspective of co-integration accounting, then, the budget shares have an appropriate set of explanatory variables.

Other properties of the MPIGLOG system can also now be easily derived in terms of Z. The expenditure elasticities of demand for each type of service j, E j , satisfy

$$ E_{j} = 1 + (\varepsilon_{2j} /s_{j} - \eta )\,(1 - Z), $$
(20)

while the price elasticities of demand, M ij , satisfy

$$ M_{ij} = [\varepsilon_{1j} (1 - Z) + (\varepsilon_{2j} /\eta )Z - \varepsilon_{2i} \varepsilon_{1j} (1 - Z)]/[s_{i} - \delta_{ij} + \eta \varepsilon_{1j} (1 - Z)], $$
(21)

in which δ ij is the Kronecker delta—i.e., assumes the value of 1.0 when i = j, and is zero everywhere else. A typical term of the Slutsky matrix is

$$ S_{ij} = (c/p_{i} p_{j} )\,[s_{i} M_{ij} + s_{i} s_{j} E_{i} ]. $$
(22)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Donaghy, K.P. Models of travel demand with endogenous preference change and heterogeneous agents. J Geogr Syst 13, 17–30 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10109-010-0129-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10109-010-0129-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation