Skip to main content
Log in

A leader-followers model of power transmission capacity expansion in a market driven environment

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Computational Management Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We introduce a model for analyzing the upgrade of the national transmission grid that explicitly accounts for responses given by the power producers in terms of generation unit expansion. The problem is modeled as a bilevel program with a mixed integer structure in both upper and lower level. The upper level is defined by the transmission company problem which has to decide on how to upgrade the network. The lower level models the reactions of both power producers, who take a decision on new facilities and power output, and Market Operator, which strikes a new balance between demand and supply, providing new Locational Marginal Prices. We illustrate our methodology by means of an example based on the Garver’s 6-bus Network.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For each constraint we report its dual variable after the colon.

References

  • Aguado JA, de la Torre S, Contreras J, Conejo AJ, Martínez A (2012) Market-driven dynamic transmission expansion planning. Electr Power Syst Res 82(1):88–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacon RW (1995) Privatization and reform in the global electricity supply industry. Annu Rev Energy Environ 20:119–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bard JF (1998) Practical bilevel optimization. Nonconvex optimization and its applications, vol 30. Kluwer Academic, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baringo L, Conejo AJ (2012) Transmission and wind power investment. IEEE Trans Power Syst 27(2):885–893

  • Bialas WF, Karwan MH, Sourie J-C (1982) On two-level optimization. IEEE Trans Autom Control 1:211–214

  • Final Report of the Investigation Committee on the 28 September 2003 Blackout in Italy (2004) UCTE

  • Fortuny-Amat J, McCarl B (1981) A representation and economic interpretation of a two-level programming problem. J Oper Res Soc 32:783–792

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galloway CD, Garver LL, Kirchmayer LK, Wood AJ (1966) Generation-Transmission Expansion Planning. In: Proceedings of Power Systems Computation Conference pt. 5, Stockholm, Sweden

  • Garcés LP, Romero R, Market-driven Lopez-Lezama JM, Planning Security-constrained Transmission Network Expansion (2010) IEEE/PES Transmission and Distribution Conference and Exposition: Latin America (T&D-LA), pp 427–433

  • Garcés LP, Conejo AJ, Garcia-Bertrand R, Romero R (2009) A bilevel approach to transmission expansion planning within a market environment. IEEE Trans Power Syst 24(3):1513–1522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garver LL (1970) Transmission network estimation using linear programming. IEEE Trans Power Appar Syst 89:1688–1697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genesi C, Marannino P, Siviero I, Zanellini F, Carlini EM, Pericolo PP (2008) Coordinated Transmission and Generation Planning to Increase the Electricity Market Efficiency. In: XVI Power Systems Computation Conference (PSCC 2008), Glasgow, United Kingdom

  • Hashimoto H (1985) A spatial nash equilibrium model. In: Harker P (ed) Spatial price equilibrium: advances in theory, computation and application. Springer, Berlin, pp 20–40

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hesamzadeh MR, Hosseinzadeh N, Wolfs PJ (2010) A leader-followers model of transmission augmentation for considering strategic behaviours of generating companies in energy markets. Int J Electr Power Energy Syst 32(5):358–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobbs BF (2001) Linear complementarity models of nash-cournot competition in bilateral and POOLCO power markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 16(2):194–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hyman LS (2010) Restructuring electricity policy and financial models. Energy Econ 32:751–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Energy Agency (1999) Electricity market reform: an IEA handbook. OECD/IEA, Paris, p 106

  • Maurovich-Horvat L, Boomsma TK, Fleten SE, Siddiqui AS (2013) Transmission and Wind Investment in a Deregulated Electricity Industry. In: 10th International Conference on the European Energy Market (EEM), pp 1–7

  • Ng SKK, Zhong J, Lee CW (2009) A game-theoretic Study of the Strategic Interaction Between Generation and Transmission Expansion Planning. In: IEEE Power Systems Conference and Exposition, IEEE, Ed. Seattle, USA, p 10

  • Park H, Baldrick R (2013) Transmission planning under uncertainty of wind and load: sequential approximation approach. IEEE Trans Power Syst 28(3):2395–2402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patterson W (1999) Transforming electricity. Earthscan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Pozo D, Sauma EE, Contreras J (2013) A three-level static MILP model for generation and transmission expansion planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 28(1):202–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pozo D, Contreras J, Sauma EE (2013) If You Build it, He Will Come: anticipative power transmission planning. Energy Econ 36:135–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roh JH, Shahidehpour M, Fu Y (2007) Market-based coordination of transmission and generation capacity planning. IEEE Trans Power Syst 22(4):1406–1419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roh JH, Shahidehpour M, Wu L (2009) Market-based generation and transmission planning with uncertainties. IEEE Trans Power Syst 24(3):1587–1598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauma EE, Oren SS (2006) Proactive planning and valuation of transmission investments in restructured electricity markets. J regul Econ 30:261–290

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauma EE, Oren SS (2007) Economic criteria for planning transmission investment in restructured electricity markets. IEEE Trans Power Syst 22(4):1394–1405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shan J, Ryan SM (2011) Capacity expansion in the integrated supply network for an electricity market. IEEE Trans Power Syst 26(4):2275–2284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • TERNA, S.p.A (2007) Development Plan of the National Electric Transmission Network. www.terna.it

  • Vespucci MT, Allevi E, Gnudi A, Innorta M (2010) Cournot equilibria in oligopolistic electricity markets. IMA J Manag Math 21(2):183–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vespucci MT, Innorta M, Cervigni G (2013) A mixed integer linear programming model of a zonal electricity market with a dominant producer. Energy Econ 35:40–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Energy Counc (1998) The Benefits and Deficiencies of Energy Sector Liberalisation, vol 1. World Energy Counc, London

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paolo Pisciella.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof

of Proposition 1 The proposition can be proved by making considerations on the structure of the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions for the modified MO problem. We report the complementarity conditions of such system

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\left( \pi _{zt}- \sigma ^{E}_{ikt} - b_{ikt}\right) q_{ikt}=0&\qquad i \in I, t \in T, z \in Z, k \in K^E_{iz} \\&\left( \pi _{zt}- \sigma ^{C}_{ikt} -b_{ikt}\right) q_{ikt}=0&\qquad i \in I, t \in T, z \in Z, k \in K^C_{iz} \\&\left( q_{ikt} - \varGamma ^E_{ik} \right) \sigma ^{E}_{ikt}=0&\qquad i \in I, t \in T, z \in Z, k \in K^E_{iz} \\&\left( q_{ikt} - \varGamma ^C_{ik}Y_{ik} \right) \sigma ^{C}_{ikt}=0&\qquad i \in I, t \in T, z \in Z, k \in K^C_{iz} \\&\left( \overline{TR}_{lt}-TR_{lt}\right) \eta ^+_{lt}=0&\qquad l \in L^E \cup L^C, t \in T \\&\left( TR_{lt}-\underline{TR}_{lt}\right) \eta ^-_{lt}=0&\qquad l \in L^E \cup L^C, t \in T \\&\left( \overline{\theta }_z-\theta _{zt}\right) \kappa ^+_{zt}=0&\qquad z \in Z, t \in T \\&\left( \theta _{zt}-\underline{\theta }_{z}\right) \kappa ^-_{zt}=0&\qquad z \in Z, t \in T \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(105)

Let us first prove that the margin of every GenCo is non negative. From the first two equations of the complementarity system (105) one has

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{zt}q_{ikt} = \sigma ^{E}_{ikt}q_{ikt} + b_{ikt}q_{ikt} \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{zt}q_{ikt} = \sigma ^{C}_{ikts}q_{ikt} + b_{ikt}q_{ikt} \end{aligned}$$

with \(\sigma ^{E}_{ikt}q_{ikt}, \sigma ^{C}_{ikt}q_{ikt} \ge 0\).

This implies that

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{zt}q_{ikt} \ge b_{ikt}q_{ikt} \end{aligned}$$

and since by assumption \(b_{ikt} \ge c_{ik}\), one has that

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{zt}q_{ikt} \ge c_{ik}q_{ikt} \end{aligned}$$

therefore the margin is non negative, which means that each GenCo is willing to increase its production until either the maximum accepted bid or a capacity bound is reached.

Now we show the main claim of the proposition. The power produced by each GenCo cannot be such that \(\tilde{q}_{ikt} > q_{ikt}\) and it can be \(\tilde{q}_{ikt} < q_{ikt}\) if and only if \(\tilde{q}_{ikt}=\varGamma ^E_{ik}\) for existing generation units or \(\tilde{q}_{ikt}=\varGamma ^C_{ik}Y_{ik}\) for candidate generation units. But then it would be \(q_{ikt} > \varGamma ^E_{ik}\) or \(q_{ikt} > \varGamma ^C_{ik}Y_{ik}\) which is not feasible for the modified MO Problem. Therefore, once the MO solves the aforementioned problem it must be \(\tilde{q}_{ikt}=q_{ikt}\) for each GenCo. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pisciella, P., Bertocchi, M. & Vespucci, M.T. A leader-followers model of power transmission capacity expansion in a market driven environment. Comput Manag Sci 13, 87–118 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10287-014-0223-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10287-014-0223-9

Keywords

Navigation