Skip to main content
Log in

Static and dynamic resource allocation models for recovery of interdependent systems: application to the Deepwater Horizon oil spill

  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Determining where and when to invest resources during and after a disruption can challenge policy makers and homeland security officials. Two decision models, one static and one dynamic, are proposed to determine the optimal resource allocation to facilitate the recovery of impacted industries after a disruption where the objective is to minimize the production losses due to the disruption. The paper presents necessary conditions for optimality for the static model and develops an algorithm that finds every possible solution that satisfies those necessary conditions. A deterministic branch-and-bound algorithm solves the dynamic model and relies on a convex relaxation of the dynamic optimization problem. Both models are applied to the Deepwater Horizon oil spill, which adversely impacted several industries in the Gulf region, such as fishing, tourism, real estate, and oil and gas. Results demonstrate the importance of allocating enough resources to stop the oil spill and clean up the oil, which reduces the economic loss across all industries. These models can be applied to different homeland security and disaster response situations to help governments and organizations decide among different resource allocation strategies during and after a disruption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aldy, J. E. (2011). Real-time economic analysis and policy development during the BP Deepwater Horizon oil spill. Faculty research working paper series, Harvard Kennedy School, Cambridge, MA. http://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/handle/1/5241379/RWP11-037_Aldy?sequence=1. Accessed 2 Apr 2012.

  • Bakir, N. O. (2011). A Stackelberg game model for resource allocation in cargo container security. Annals of Operations Research, 187(1), 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barker, K., & Santos, J. R. (2010). A risk-based approach for identifying key economic and infrastructure systems. Risk Analysis, 30(6), 962–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bier, V. M. (2007). Choosing what to protect. Risk Analysis, 27(3), 607–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bier, V. M., & Abhichandani, V. (2003). Optimal allocation of resources for defense of simple series and parallel systems from determined adversaries. In Y. Y. Haimes, D. A. Moser, E. Z. Stakhiv, G. I. Zisk, D. Dirickson, & B. I. Zisk (Eds.), Risk-based decisionmaking in water resources X (pp. 59–76). Reston, VA: American Society of Civil Engineers.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boisvert, R. N. (1992). Indirect losses from a catastrophic earthquake and the local, regional, and national interest. In Indirect economic consequences of a catastrophic earthquake (pp. 207–265). Development Technologies Inc.

  • Brandeau, M. L. (2005). Allocating resources to control infectious diseases. In M. L. Brandeau, F. Sainfort, & W. P. Pierskalla (Eds.), Operations research and health care: A handbook of methods and applications (Vol. 70, pp. 443–464). New York: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrd, R. H., Hribar, M. E., & Nocedal, J. (1999). An interior point algorithm for large-scale nonlinear programming. SIAM Journal on Optimization, 9(4), 877–900.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, M., & Zhuang, J. (2012). Regulation games between government and competing companies: Oil spills and other disasters. Decision Analysis, 9(2), 156–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conrad, S. H., LeClaire, R. J., O’Reilly, G. P., & Uzunalioglu, H. (2006). Critical national infrastructure reliability modeling and analysis. Bell Labs Technical Journal, 11(3), 57–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crowther, K. G. (2008). Decentralized risk management for strategic preparedness critical infrastructure through decomposition of the Inoperability Input-Output Model. International Journal of Critical Infrastructure Protection, 1, 53–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniels, R. L., Hoopes, B. J., & Mazzola, J. B. (1997). An analysis of heuristics for the parallel-machine flexible-resource scheduling problem. Annals of Operations Research, 70, 439–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dell’Olmo, P., & Lulli, G. (2004). Planning activities in a network of logistic platforms with shared resources. Annals of Operations Research, 129, 155–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillon, R. L., Paté-Cornell, M. E., & Guikema, S. D. (2003). Programmatic risk analysis for critical engineering systems under tight resource constraints. Operations Research, 51(3), 354–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillon, R. L., Paté-Cornell, M. E., & Guikema, S. D. (2005). Optimal use of budget reserves to minimize technical and management failure risks during complex project development. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 52(3), 382–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dueñas-Osorio, L., Craig, J. I., Goodno, B. J., & Bostrom, A. (2007). Interdependent Response of Networked Systems. Journal of Infrastructure Systems, 13(3), 185–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dynes, S., Johnson, M. E., Andrijcic, E., & Horowitz, B. (2007). Economic costs of firm-level information infrastructure failures: Estimates from field studies in manufacturing supply chains. The International Journal of Logistics Management, 18(3), 420–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elms, D. G. (1997). Risk balancing in structural problems. Structural Safety, 19(1), 67–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiedrich, F., Gehbauer, F., & Rickers, U. (2000). Optimized resource allocation for emergency response after earthquake disasters. Safety Science, 35(1–3) 41–57.

  • Fowler, T. (2011). Return to gulf: Big oil grabs leases. First auction of deep-water blocks since BP disaster draws \({\$}\)337.6 million in winning bids. Wall Street Journal. http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970203893404577098773281211592.html. Accessed 17 Dec 2011.

  • Gordon, P., Moore, J. E, I. I., Richardson, H. W., & Pan, Q. (2005). The economic impact of a terrorist attack on the twin ports of Los Angeles-long beach. In P. G. H. W. Richardson & J. E. Moore II (Eds.), The economic impacts of terrorist attacks (pp. 262–286). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guikema, S. D., & Paté-Cornell, M. E. (2002). Component choice for managing risk in engineered systems with generalized risk/cost functions. Reliability Engineering and System Safety, 78(3), 227–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haimes, Y. Y., Crowther, K. G., & Horowitz, B. M. (2008). Homeland security preparedness: Balancing protection with resilience in emergent systems. Systems Engineering, 11(4), 287–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haimes, Y. Y., Horowitz, B. M., Lambert, J. H., Santos, J. R., Lian, C., & Crowther, K. G. (2005). Inoperability Input-Output Model for Interdependent Infrastructure. Sectors. II: Case studies. Journal of Infrastructure Systems, 11(2), 80–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausken, K., & Zhuang, J. (2013). The impact of disaster on the strategic interaction between company and government. European Journal of Operational Research, 225(2), 363–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horst, R., & Tuy, H. (1990). Global optimization: deterministic approaches. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson, J., & Hassel, H. (2010). An approach for modelling interdependent infrastructures in the context of vulnerability analysis. Reliability Engineering and System Safety, 95(12), 1335–1344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawler, E. L., & Wood, D. E. (1966). Branch-and-bound methods: A survey. Operations Research, 14(4), 699–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. W. (1936). Quantitative input and output relations in the economic systems of the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics, 18(3), 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, C. A., Barker, K., & Grant, F. H. (2012a). Evaluating the consequences of an inland waterway port closure with a dynamic multiregional interdependence model. IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics A: Systems and Humans, 42(2), 359–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, C. A., Baroud, H., & Barker, K. (2012b). Optimal resource allocation for recovery of interdependent systems: Case study of the Deepwater Horizon oil spill. In G. Lim, & J. W. Hermann (Eds.), Proceedings of the 2012 industrial and systems engineering research conference, 20–22 May.

  • MacKenzie, C. A., Santos, J. R., & Barker, K. (2012c). Measuring changes in international production from a disruption: Case study of the Japanese earthquake and tsunami. International Journal of Production Economics, 158(2), 293–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Major, J. A. (2002). Advanced techniques for modeling terrorism risk. Journal of Risk Finance, 4(1), 15–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Market Dynamics Research Group. (2010). Oil spill research report, national wave 2. Louisiana Office of Tourism Research Section. 16 August. http://crt.louisiana.gov/tourism/research/researchcurrent.aspx. Accessed 2 Apr 2012.

  • McAndrews, K. L. (2011). Consequences of Macondo: A summary of recently proposed and enacted changes to U.S. offshore drilling safety and environmental regulation. Society of Petroleum Engineers, SPE-143718-PP. www.jsg.utexas.edu/news/files/mcandrews_spe_143718-pp.pdf. Accessed 30 Dec 2011.

  • Medal, H., Sharp, S. J., Pohl, E., Rainwater, C., & Mason, S. J. (2011). Models for reducing the risk of critical networked infrastructures. International Journal of Risk Assessment and Management, 15(2/3), 99–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, D. M., & Davis, R. P. (1978). A dynamic resource allocation model for a machine requirements problem. IIE Transactions, 10(3), 237–243.

    Google Scholar 

  • Misra, K. B., & Ljubojević, M. D. (1973). Optimal reliability design of a system: A new look. IEEE Transactions on Reliability, R–22(5), 255–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Resources Defense Council. (2011). The BP oil disaster at one year: A straightforward assessment of what we know, what we don’t, and what questions need to be answered. 20 April 20. http://www.nrdc.org/energy/bpoildisasteroneyear.asp. Accessed 30 Dec 2011.

  • Nocedal, J., & Wright, S. J. (1999). Numerical optimization. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Okuyama, Y. (2008). Critical review of methodologies on disaster impacts estimation. Background paper for the World Bank–UN Assessment on the Economics of Disaster Risk Reduction. http://gfdrr.org/gfdrr/node/284. Accessed 23 Sept 2011.

  • Okuyama, Y., & Chang, S. E. (Eds.). (2004). Modeling spatial and economic impacts of disasters. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxford Economics. (2010). Potential impact of the Gulf oil spill on tourism. A report prepared for the U.S. Travel Association. 22 July. http://www.ustravel.org/news/press-releases/bp-oil-spill-impact-gulf-travel-likely-last-3-years-and-cost-227-billion. Accessed 30 Sept 2011.

  • Pederson, P., Dudenhoeffer, D., Hartley, S., & Permann, M. (2006). Critical infrastructure interdependency modeling: A survey of U.S. and international research. INL/EXT-06-11464, Idaho Falls. http://cipbook.infracritical.com/book3/chapter2/ch2ref2a. Accessed 28 Mar 2012.

  • Petrovic, N., Alderson, D. L., & Carlson, J. M. (2012). Dynamic resource allocation in disaster response: Tradeoffs in wildfire suppression. PLoS ONE, 7(4), e33285. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0033285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psaraftis, H. N., & Ziogas, B. O. (1985). A tactical decision algorithm for the optimal dispatching of oil spill cleanup equipment. Management Science, 31(12), 1475–1491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richards, T. J., & Patterson, P. M. (1999). The economic value of public relations expenditures: Food safety and the strawberry case. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 24(2), 440–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rinaldi, S. M., Peerenboom, J. P., & Kelly, T. K. (2001). Identifying, understanding, and analyzing critical infrastructure interdependencies. IEEE Control Systems Magazine, 21(6), 11–25

  • Robertson, C., & Krauss, C. (2010). Gulf spill is the largest of its kind, scientists say. New York Times. 3 August. http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/03/us/03spill.html?_r=1&fta=y. Accessed 30 Dec 2011.

  • Santos, J. R., & Haimes, Y. Y. (2004). Modeling the demand reduction input–output (I–O) inoperability due to terrorism of interconnected infrastructures. Risk Analysis, 24(6), 1437–1451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shan, X., & Zhuang, J. (2013a). Cost of equity in homeland security resource allocation in the face of a strategic attacker. Risk Analysis, 33(6), 1083–1099.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shan, X., & Zhuang, J. (2013b). Hybrid defensive resource allocations in the face of partially strategic attackers in a sequential defender-attacker game. European Journal of Operational Research, 228(1), 262–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Srinivasa, A. V., & Wilhelm, W. E. (1997). A procedure for optimizing tactical response in oil spill clean up operations. European Journal of Operations Research, 102(3), 554–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tillman, F. A., Hwang, C.-L., Fan, L.-T., & Lai, K. (1970). Optimal reliability of a complex system. IEEE Transactions on Reliability, R–19(3), 95–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trefis Team. (2011). BP rising from Deepwater Horizon abyss but not free yet. Forbes, 4 March. http://www.forbes.com/sites/greatspeculations/2011/03/04/bp-rising-from-deepwater-horizon-abyss-but-not-free-yet/. Accessed 30 Dec 2011.

  • U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. (2010a). Make table, before redefinitions, 2009. 1998–2009 summary make annual I-O table before redefinitions. U.S. Department of Commerce. http://www.bea.gov/industry/io_annual.htm. Accessed 17 Apr 2012.

  • U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. (2010b). Use table, before redefinitions, 2009. 1998–2009 summary use annual I–O table before redefinitions. U.S. Department of Commerce. http://www.bea.gov/industry/io_annual.htm. Accessed 17 Apr 2012.

  • U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. (2011). Gross domestic product by state. Regional economic accounts. U.S. Department of Commerce. http://www.bea.gov/regional/index.htm. Accessed 17 Apr 2012.

  • U.S. Energy Information Administration. (2011). Table 4a. U.S. crude oil and liquid fuels supply, consumption, and inventories. In Short-term energy outlook. http://www.eia.gov/forecasts/steo/data.cfm?type=tables. Accessed 6 Dec 2011.

  • Verbeke, W., & Ward, R. W. (2001). A fresh meat almost ideal demand system incorporating negative TV press and advertising impact. Agricultural Economics, 25(2/3), 359–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waltz, R. A., Morales, J. L., Nocedal, J., & Orban, D. (2006). An interior algorithm for nonlinear optimization that combines line search and trust region steps. Mathematical Programming, 107(3), 391–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Willis, H. H. (2007). Guiding resource allocations based on terrorism risk. Risk Analysis, 27(3), 597–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zaric, G. S., & Brandeau, M. L. (2002). Dynamic resource allocation for epidemic control in multiple populations. IMA Journal of Mathematics Applied in Medicine and Biology, 19, 235–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhuang, J., & Bier, V. M. (2007). Balancing terrorism and natural disasters–defensive strategy with endogenous attacker effort. Operations Research, 55(5), 976–991.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Parts of this article are reprinted with the permission of the Institute of Industrial Engineers, 3577 Parkview Lane, Suite 200, Norcross, GA 30092, www.iienet.org, Copyright@2012 by Institute of Industrial Engineers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cameron A. MacKenzie.

Additional information

This work was funded in part by the National Science Foundation, Division of Civil, Mechanical, and Manufacturing Innovation, under award 0927299.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Given a set of \(z_i>0\) and \(z_i=0\), we seek to prove that (6) has at most three solutions. First, we need to prove the following lemma.

Lemma 1

Given a function \(f\left( x\right) \) that is continuously differentiable for \(x>0\), if \(f'\left( x\right) =0\) has at most two solutions for \(x >0\) and \(\alpha >0\), then \(\mathrm{exp }\left( -\alpha x^2\right) f\left( x\right) =0\) has at most three solutions for \(x>0\).

Proof

Assume the function \(f\left( x\right) \) is continuously differentiable for \(x>0, f'\left( x\right) =0\) has at most two solutions, and \(\alpha >0\). If \(\mathrm{exp }\left( -\alpha x^2\right) f\left( x\right) =0\) has more than three solutions for \(x>0\), then \(f\left( x\right) =0\) has more than three solutions for \(x>0\) because \(\mathrm{exp }\left( -\alpha x^2\right) >0\) for all \(x\).

If \(f\left( x\right) =0\) has more than three solutions, then \(f\left( x\right) \) has at least three local extrema, which means that \(f'\left( x\right) =0\) has at least three solutions. This contradicts the premise that \(f'\left( x\right) =0\) has at most two solutions. Thus, \(\mathrm{exp }\left( -\alpha x^2\right) f\left( x\right) =0\) has at most three solutions for \(x>0\). \(\square \)

If we can show that the first derivative as depicted in (8) has at most two values for \(z_0>0\) where the first derivative equals zero, then Lemma 1 applies because (7) is continuously differentiable for \(z_0>0\).

The second derivative of (7) with respect to \(z_0\) is given in (11).

$$\begin{aligned} F\text {exp}\left( \dfrac{z_0-Z}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\right) \left[ \left( \dfrac{1}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\right) ^2-\dfrac{2k_0z_0}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }-4k_0\right] \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Equation (11) has one solution for \(z_0\) if (11) equals zero. This implies that the first derivative in (8) has one extreme point and at most two solutions for \(z_0\) if (8) equals 0. Because no more than two zeros exist for the first derivative in (8), we can conclude from Lemma 1 that (6) has at most three solutions for \(0<z_0<Z\). \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

First, we show that if (6) has three real solutions for \(z_0\), then each of the three conditions must hold. If (6) has three solutions, then (7) has three solutions because \(\mathrm{exp }\left( -k_0z_0^2\right) \ne 0\). Because the second derivative in (11) has exactly one solution for \(z_0\) when (11) equals 0, the first derivative in (8) has one local extreme point, which means that at most two solutions exist for \(z_0\) when (8) equals 0. This implies that (7) has at most two extreme points. If exactly three solutions exist for \(z_0\) when (7) equals 0, then (7) has a local minimum at \(z_0=z_-\) where (7) is less than 0 and a local maximum at \(z_0=z_+\) where (7) is greater than 0.

Condition 1. The expression in (7) is greater than 0 if \(z_0=0\). If (7) has three solutions, then (7) must be less than or equal to 0 when \(z_0=Z\). If (7) is less than or equal to 0 when \(z_0=Z\), then \(F\left( 1-2k_0Z\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. \right) -2Gk_0Z\le 0\). Then it must be true that \(Z\ge \left. F\big /\left( 2Gk_0+2Fk_0\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. \right. \right) \), which proves condition 1.

Condition 2. A local minimum exists at \(z_0=z_{-}\), and a local maximum exists at \(z_0=z_+\). Since (7) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=0\) and (7) is less than 0 when \(z_0=Z\), it must be true that \(z_-<z_+\). The first derivative in (8) equals 0 when \(z_0=z_-\) and \(z_0=z_+\), which implies that \(2Gk_0=F\text {exp}\left( \frac{z_0-Z}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\right) \left( \frac{1}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }-2k_0z_0-2k_0\sum _{i:z_i>0}\frac{1}{k_i}\right) \) at those two points. Substituting this expression for \(2Gk_0\) into (7) leads to the expression in (12).

$$\begin{aligned} F\text {exp}\left( \dfrac{z_0-Z}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\right) \left( 2k_0z_0^2-\dfrac{z_0}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }+1\right) \end{aligned}$$
(12)

If (12) equals 0, then \(z_0=\left. \left( \frac{1}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\pm \sqrt{\frac{1}{\left( \sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. \right) ^2}-8k_0}\right) \big /\left( 4k_0\right) \right. \), which corresponds to \(z^*\) and \(z^{**}\) as defined in Proposition 2. The expression in (12) is greater than 0 when \(z_0<z^*\) and \(z_0>z^{**}\) and less than 0 when \(z^*<z_0<z^{**}\). If no solution exists when (12) equals 0, then that would imply that (7) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z_-\) because (12) would always be greater than 0. If that were true, then three solutions would not exist for \(z_0\) when (7) equals 0.

Because (7) is less than 0 when \(z_0=z_-\), then it must be true that \(z^*<z_-\). Because (7) is decreasing for \(z_0<z_-\), the first derivative in (8) is less than 0 when \(z_0=z^*\), which proves condition 2.

Condition 3. Because (7) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z_+\), it must be true that \(z^{**}<z_+<Z\). Because (7) is increasing for \(z_-<z_0<z_+\), (8) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z_+\), which proves condition 3.

Second, we show that if the three conditions hold, then (6) has three real solutions for \(z_0\). Assume the three conditions hold. Because (8) is less than 0 when \(z_0=z^*\), (7) is decreasing over some range. Because (8) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z^{**}\), then (7) is increasing over some range. Since \(z^*<z^{**}\), there must be a local minimum at some point \(z_0=z_-\) where \(z^*<z_-<z^{**}\). The expression in (12) is less than 0 for \(z^*<z_0<z^{**}\), which implies that (7) is less than 0 at the local minimum \(z_0=z_-\). The expression in (7) must equal 0 for some point \(0<z_0<z_-\).

Since (8) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z^{**}\), \(2Gk_0<F\text {exp}\left( \frac{z^{**}-Z}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\right) \left( \frac{1}{\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }-2k_0z^{**}-2k_0\sum _{i:z_i>0}\dfrac{1}{k_i}\right) \). This means that (7) is greater than (12) when \(z_0=z^{**}\). Because (12) equals 0 when \(z_0=z^{**}\), (7) is greater than 0. The expression in (7) must equal 0 for some point \(z_-<z_0<z^{**}\).

If \(Z\ge \frac{F}{2Gk_0+2Fk_0\sum _{i:z_i>0}\left. 1\big /k_i\right. }\) then (7) is less than or equal to 0 when \(z_0=Z\). Because \(z^{**}<Z\) and (7) is greater than 0 when \(z_0=z^{**}\), (7) must equal 0 for some point \(z^{**}<z_0<Z\).

This proves there are at least three solutions for \(z_0\) when (7) equals 0, which means that (6) has at least three solutions for \(z_0\). From Proposition 1, no more than three solutions exist, and we conclude that (6) has three solutions for \(z_0\). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

MacKenzie, C.A., Baroud, H. & Barker, K. Static and dynamic resource allocation models for recovery of interdependent systems: application to the Deepwater Horizon oil spill. Ann Oper Res 236, 103–129 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-014-1696-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-014-1696-1

Keywords

Navigation