Abstract
In order to reduce informational asymmetry a signaling contract seems to be an efficient solution. Standard theory argues that insurance contracts typically produce separating equilibria. Mostly, this property is based on the assumption of two states of the world only. If however, there is a world with a continuum of states the solution is different. We prove that there is no longer a separating equilibrium. As a result, insurance markets are characterized by pooling equilibria or self-insurance structures.


Similar content being viewed by others
References
Culp, C. L. (2002). The art of risk management. New York: Wiley.
Doherty, N. A. (2000). Integrated risk management. New York: Mc Graw Hill.
Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. (1992). The analytics of uncertainty and information. Cambridge: CUP.
Kürsten, W. (1997). Zur Anreiz-Inkompatibilität von Kreditsicherheiten, oder: Insuffizienz des Stiglitz/Weiss-Models der Agency-Theorie. ZFBF, 49, 819.
Mas-Colell, A., et al. (1995). Microeconomic theory. Oxford: OUP.
Rasmusen, E. (2001). Games & information. Malden MA: Blackwell Publishers.
Rothschild, M., & Stiglitz, J. (1970). Increasing risk: I. A definition. Journal of Economic theory, 2, 225.
Rothschild, M., & Stiglitz, J. (1976). Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 629.
Stiglitz, J., & Weiss, A. (1994). Sorting out the differences between signaling and screening models. In M. O. L. Bacharrach, M. A. H. Dempster, & J. H. Enos (Eds.), Mathematical models in economics (Vol. 156). Oxford: OUP.
Sudhölter, P., et al. (2012). The bounded core for games with precedence constraints. Annals of Operations Research, 201, 251.
Sudhölter, P., et al. (2013). Axiomatizations of symmetrically weighted solutions. Annals of Operations Research. https://pure.uvt.nl/portal/files/1490904/2013-007.pdf.
Wilson, C. (1977). A model of insurance markets with incomplete information. Journal of Economic theory, 16, 167.
Acknowledgments
The author thanks the Editor, one anonymous referee and Peter Sudhölter for helpful comments and extensive proposals to improve an earlier version of the paper. Building on this, but going beyond the framework of the research done, there exist at least two directions to extend the presented paper. On the one hand, by using deductibles as an indication of the customer’s level of risk aversion instead of using deductibles to predict customer’s loss probability the paper could be embedded in an Arrowian approach. On the other hand, the paper would have taken a step nearer to insurance reality, if the right hand side of Eq. 7 is replaced by a positive constant instead of zero. A subsequent paper is in preparation, in which both are considered as well.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
Proposition 1
Proof
As the insurance customer’s a level indifference curve \(P(Z)\left| {_{E[u\left| {t_i ]=\textit{const}=a} \right. }} \right. \) is implicitly given by \(F(Z,P;t_i )\!\!=\!U(Z,P;t_i )-a \!\!=\!\!\int \limits _0^\mathrm{Z} {\hbox {u}(\hbox {w}_0 -\hbox {L}-\hbox {P})\hbox {f}(\hbox {L};\hbox {t}_{\mathrm{i}} )\hbox {dL}} +\int \limits _{\mathrm{Z}}^{\mathrm{M}} {\hbox {u}(\hbox {w}_0 -\hbox {Z}-\hbox {P})\hbox {f}(\hbox {L};\hbox {t}_{\mathrm{i}} )\hbox {dL}} \) we get \(\frac{\textit{dP}}{\textit{dZ}}\left| {_{E[u\left| {t_i ]=\textit{const}} \right. }} \right. =-\frac{F_1 (Z,P;t_i )}{F_2 (Z,P;t_i )}\) using \(F_1 (Z,P;t_i )=-u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} \) and \(F_2 (Z,P;t_i )=\int \limits _0^Z u^{\prime }(w_0 -L-P)(-1)f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}+\int \limits _Z^M{u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)(-1)f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} \). Then, the type i indifference curves are strictly monotonic decreasing according to \(\frac{\textit{dP}}{\textit{dZ}}\left| {_{E[u\left| {t_i ]=\textit{const}} \right. } } \right. =-\frac{F_1 (Z,P;t_i )}{F_2 (Z,P;t_i )}=-\frac{u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} }{\int \limits _0^Z {u^{\prime }(w_0 -L-P)f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}+u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} } }\). \(\square \)
Proposition 2
Proof
The assertion follows from \(\frac{\textit{dP}_i }{\textit{dZ}}=-Z f(Z;t_i )+\int \limits _M^Z {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}+Z f(Z;t_i )} =\int \limits _M^Z {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} \quad =-\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}=-p(Z;t_i )} \). \(\square \)
Proposition 3
The insurance customer’s indifference curves are convex
Proof
Let (i) \(Z_i \in [0, M], Z_1 <Z_2 \) and \(\bar{{Z}}=(Z_1 +Z_2 )2^{-1}\), (ii) \(P_1 , P_2 \) be chosen such that \((Z_1 ,P_1 ), (Z_2 ,P_2 )\) are parts of the insurance customer’s a level indifference curve, and (iii) (Z, P) be given by \(P\le w_0 -Z, P<w_0 -Z\) for \(Z<M\) since indifference curves with non-negative expected utility are considered only. Note furthermore (iv) \(w_0 -Z\) is the insurer’s highest premium in the case of damage, (v) \((w_0 ,0)\) is the only possible contract in the borderline case\(Z=M=w_0 \), and (vi) \(P_1 >(P_1 +P_2 )2^{-1}>P{ }_2\) since the indifference curves are strictly monotonic decreasing. Given \(\bar{{P}}=(P_1 +P_2 )2^{-1}\), we have to show \((\bar{{Z}},\bar{{P}})\) is part of an indifference curve of a lower level than a.
We prove \(U(\bar{{Z}},\bar{{P}};t_i )<a\). As \(U(\bar{{Z}},\bar{{P}};t_i )<\int \limits _0^{\bar{Z}} {u(w_0 -L-\bar{{P}})f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} +2^{-1}\int \limits _{\bar{Z}}^M (u( w_0 -Z_1 -P_1 ) +u(w_0 -Z_2 -P_2 ))f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}\) is valid (note: the concavity of \(u(\cdot )\) implies the convexity of \(\nu (\cdot )\) if \(v(X): =u(w_0 -X)) \quad v(2^{-1}(Z_1 +P_1 +Z_2 +P_2 ))<2^{-1}(u(w_0 -Z_1 -P_1 )+u(w_0 -Z_2 -P_2 ))\) is satisfied. Hence,
\(\square \)
Proposition 4
\(\left| {\frac{dP}{dZ}\left| {_{E[u\left| {t_i ]=\textit{const}} \right. } } \right. } \right| >p(Z;t_i )\) for \(0<Z<M\)
Proof
Using that the marginal utility is descending the assertion follows according to \(\left| {\frac{dP}{dZ}|_{E[u|t_i ] = \textit{const}} } \right| \!\!>\frac{u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} }{u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _0^Z {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}+u^{\prime }(w_0 -Z-P)\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} } } =\!\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}\!=p(Z;t_i )}\). \(\square \)
Proposition 5
\(P_1 (Z)\le P_2 (Z)\) for all \(Z\in [0;M]\)
Proof
Using SSD we get \(P_1 (Z)=\bar{{L}}-Z+\int \limits _0^Z {F(L;t_1 )\textit{dL}} \le \bar{{L}}-Z+\int \limits _0^Z {F(L;t_2 )\textit{dL}} =P_2 (Z)\) since \(P_i (Z)=\int \limits _Z^M {(L-Z)f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}=} \int \limits _0^Z {Lf(L;t_i )\textit{dL}+\int \limits _Z^M {Lf(L;t_i )\textit{dL}}} -\int \limits _0^Z {Lf(L;t_i )\textit{dL}}-Z\int \limits _Z^M {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} =\bar{{L}}-(ZF(Z;t_i )-\int \limits _0^Z F(L;t_i )\textit{dL})-Z(1-\int \limits _0^Z {f(L;t_i )\textit{dL})}=\bar{{L}}-Z+\int \limits _0^Z {F(L;t_i )\textit{dL}} \) holds for.
Since the anti-derivative of \(L f(L;t_i )\) is given by \(H(L;t_i)\!=\!L F(L;t_i )-\!\int \limits _0^L (\int \limits _0^y {f(u;t_i )du)}dy \) we get \(\int \limits _0^Z {L f(L; t_i )\textit{dL}=ZF(Z; t_i )-\int \limits _0^Z {F(L; t_i )\textit{dL}} } \). \(\square \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Bieta, V. Signaling theory revisited: a very short insurance case. Ann Oper Res 235, 75–84 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1958-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-015-1958-6