Abstract
This work develops a general model of a two-echelon supply chain in which a dominant retailer interacts with a manufacturer via a consignment contract with revenue sharing. The manufacturer’s cost function is known only to him, whereas the retailer has only an estimation of this function, which is based on common knowledge. We formulate the interaction between the parties as a Stackelberg game in which the less informed party (the retailer) moves first. We investigate a strategic information-sharing policy of the manufacturer under general formulations of (i) the supply chain’s revenue and cost functions, and (ii) the manufacturer’s decision functions. Two models are considered: (i) a point-estimation model—the retailer relies on a single-valued estimation of the manufacturer’s cost function, based on her “best belief”; and (ii) an interval-estimation model—the retailer faces uncertainty with regard to the cost function and thus estimates its parameter values within intervals. We find a condition that distinguishes between a case in which it is optimal for both parties for the manufacturer to share his exact cost function and a case in which such information-sharing is not optimal for the manufacturer but is optimal for the retailer. In the interval-estimation model, equilibrium is obtained using a normative (probabilistic) approach as well as behavioral-decision criteria (max–max, max–min and regret minimization). Under a normative approach both hidden and known superiority of the manufacturer are considered. Finally, we use our model to analyze a supply chain of a mobile application.

Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
\( s \to \infty \) means that at least one component of S tends to infinity.
References
Ali, F. (2018). US ecommerce sales grow 15.0% in 2018. Digital Commerce 360. https://www.digitalcommerce360.com/article/us-ecommerce-sales/
Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., Fruchter, G. E., & Prasad, A. (2020). Contract design when quality is co-created in a supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 286, 908–918.
Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., & Perlman, Y. (2015a). The effect of risk sensitivity on a supply chain of mobile applications under a consignment contract with revenue sharing and quality investment. International Journal of Production Economics, 168, 31–40.
Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., & Perlman, Y. (2015b). Consignment contract for mobile apps between a single retailer and competitive developers with different risk attitudes. European Journal of Operational Research, 246(3), 949–957.
Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., & Perlman, Y. (2016). Mergers and acquisitions between risk-averse parties. European Journal of Operational Research, 259(3), 926–934.
Avinadav, T., Chernonog, T., & Perlman, Y. (2017). Value of information-sharing and information accuracy in a supply chain under a revenue-sharing contract. Working paper.
Becker-Peth, M., & Thonemann, U. W. (2016). Reference points in revenue sharing contracts—How to design optimal supply chain contracts. European Journal of Operational Research, 249(3), 1033–1049.
Bian, J., Guo, X., Lai, K. K., & Hua, Z. (2014). The strategic peril of information sharing in a vertical-Nash supply chain: A note. International Journal of Production Economics, 158, 37–43.
Cachon, G. P., & Zhang, F. (2006). Procuring fast delivery: Sole sourcing with information asymmetry. Management Science, 52(6), 881–896.
Cachon, G. P., & Zhang, F. (2007). Obtaining fast service in a queueing system via performance-based allocation of demand. Management Science, 53(3), 408–420.
Çakanyıldırım, M., Feng, Q., Gan, X., & Sethi, S. P. (2012). Contracting and coordination under asymmetric production cost information. Production and Operations Management, 21(2), 345–360.
Chen, Y. J., & Deng, M. (2015). Information sharing in a manufacturer–supplier relationship: Suppliers’ incentive and production efficiency. Production and Operations Management, 24(4), 619–633.
Chen, X., & Wang, A. (2012). Trade credit contract with limited liability in the supply chain with budget constraints. Annals of Operations Research, 196(1), 153–165.
Chernonog, T. (2020). Inventory and marketing policy in a supply chain of a perishable product. International Journal of Production Economics, 219, 259–274.
Chernonog, T., & Avinadav, T. (2014). Profit criteria involving risk in price setting of virtual products. European Journal of Operational Research, 236(1), 351–360.
Chernonog, T., & Avinadav, T. (2019). Pricing and advertising in a supply chain of perishable products under asymmetric information. International Journal of Production Economics, 209, 249–264.
Choi, T. M., & Guo, S. (2020). Is a ‘free lunch’ a good lunch? The performance of zero wholesale price-based supply-chain contracts. European Journal of Operational Research,285, 237–246.
Chu, W. H. J., & Lee, C. C. (2006). Strategic information sharing in a supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 174(3), 1567–1579.
Corbett, C. J., & De Groote, X. (2000). A supplier’s optimal quantity discount policy under asymmetric information. Management Science, 46(3), 444–450.
Cui, R., & Shin, H. (2018). Sharing aggregate inventory information with customers: Strategic cross-selling and shortage reduction. Management Science, 64(1), 381–400.
Dana, Jr, J. D., & Spier, K. E. (2001). Revenue sharing and vertical control in the video rental industry. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 49(3), 223–245.
El Ouardighi, F., & Kim, B. (2010). Supply quality management with wholesale price and revenue-sharing contracts under horizontal competition. European Journal of Operational Research, 206, 329–340.
Fishburn, G. (1981). Tax evasion and inflation. Australian Economic Papers, 20(37), 325–332.
Gans, J. S. (2012). Mobile application pricing. Information Economics and Policy, 24(1), 52–59.
Gao, L., Li, Z., & Shou, B. (2014). Information acquisition and voluntary disclosure in an export-processing system. Production and Operations Management, 23(5), 802–816.
Guan, X., & Chen, Y. J. (2017). The interplay between information acquisition and quality disclosure. Production and Operations Management, 26(3), 389–408.
Guo, L. (2009). The benefits of downstream information acquisition. Marketing Science, 28(3), 457–471.
Guo, L., & Iyer, G. (2010). Information acquisition and sharing in a vertical relationship. Marketing Science, 29(3), 483–506.
Guo, L., Li, T., & Zhang, H. (2014). Strategic information sharing in competing channels. Production and Operations Management, 23(10), 1719–1731.
Gurnani, H., & Shi, M. (2006). A bargaining model for a first-time interaction under asymmetric beliefs of supply reliability. Management Science, 52(6), 865–880.
Ha, A. Y., & Tong, S. (2008). Contracting and information sharing under supply chain competition. Management Science, 54(4), 701–715.
He, Y., Zhao, X., Zhao, L., & He, J. (2009). Coordinating a supply chain with effort and price dependent stochastic demand. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 33(6), 2777–2790.
Huang, S., & Yang, J. (2016). Information acquisition and transparency in a supply chain with asymmetric production cost information. International Journal of Production Economics, 182, 449–464.
Jiang, B., Tian, L., Xu, Y., & Zhang, F. (2016). To share or not to share: Demand forecast sharing in a distribution channel. Marketing Science, 35(5), 800–809.
Kreps, D. M. (1990). A course in microeconomic theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Lau, A. H. L., & Lau, H. S. (2001). Some two-echelon style-goods inventory models with asymmetric market information. European Journal of Operational Research, 134(1), 29–42.
Lau, A. H. L., Lau, H. S., & Zhou, Y. W. (2006). Considering asymmetrical manufacturing cost information in a two-echelon system that uses price-only contracts. IIE Transactions, 38(3), 253–271.
Lei, Q., Chen, J., Wei, X., & Lu, S. (2015). Supply chain coordination under asymmetric production cost information and inventory inaccuracy. International Journal of Production Economics, 170, 204–218.
Li, S., & Hua, Z. (2008). A note on channel performance under consignment contract with revenue sharing. European Journal of Operational Research, 184(2), 793–796.
Li, T., Tong, S., & Zhang, H. (2014). Transparency of information acquisition in a supply chain. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 16(3), 412–424.
Li, L., & Zhang, H. (2008). Confidentiality and information sharing in supply chain coordination. Management Science, 54(8), 1467–1481.
Li, S., Zhu, Z., & Huang, L. (2009). Supply chain coordination and decision making under consignment contract with revenue sharing. International Journal of Production Economics, 120(1), 88–99.
Maskin, E. (1979). Decision-making under ignorance with implications for social choice. Game theory, social choice and ethics (pp. 319–337). Amsterdam: Springer, Netherlands.
Ru, J., & Wang, Y. (2010). Consignment contracting: Who should control inventory in the supply chain? European Journal of Operational Research, 201(3), 760–769.
Shen, Y., & Willems, S. P. (2012). Coordinating a channel with asymmetric cost information and the manufacturer’s optimality. International Journal of Production Economics, 135(1), 125–135.
Smith, A.S. (2016) Retailers made Black Friday irresistible for consumers with great deals, online and in-store. https://nrf.com/media/press-releases/retailers-made-black-friday-irresistible-consumers-great-deals-online-and-store
Wang, X., Guo, H., Yan, R., & Wang, X. (2018). Achieving optimal performance of supply chain under cost information asymmetry. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 53, 523–539.
Wang, Y., Jiang, L., & Shen, Z. J. (2004). Channel performance under consignment contract with revenue sharing. Management Science, 50(1), 34–47.
Xiao, T., & Yang, D. (2009). Risk sharing and information revelation mechanism of a one-manufacturer and one-retailer supply chain facing an integrated competitor. European Journal of Operational Research, 196(3), 1076–1085.
Xie, G., Yue, W., Wang, S., & Lai, K. K. (2011). Quality investment and price decision in a risk-averse supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 214, 403–410.
Yang, D., Choi, T. M., Xiao, T., & Cheng, T. C. E. (2011). Coordinating a two-supplier and one-retailer supply chain with forecast updating. Automatica, 47(7), 1317–1329.
Yang, H., Luo, J., & Wang, H. (2017). The role of revenue sharing and first-mover advantage in emission abatement with carbon tax and consumer environmental awareness. International Journal of Production Economics, 193, 691–702.
Zhang, D., De Matta, R., & Lowe, T. J. (2010). Channel coordination in a consignment contract. European Journal of Operational Research, 207(2), 897–905.
Zhao, J., & Wei, J. (2014). The coordinating contracts for a fuzzy supply chain with effort and price dependent demand. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 38(9–10), 2476–2489.
Acknowledgements
This research was supported by the ISRAEL SCIENCE FOUNDATION (grant No. 1571/20).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix
Appendix
Proof of Lemma 1
The total profit is \( R(p,q) - C(q) = p\left( {a - \alpha p + \beta q} \right) - \gamma {{q^{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{q^{2} } 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2} \). The gradient of this function is \( \left( {a - 2\alpha p + \beta q,\beta p - \gamma q} \right)\, \), and the Hessian is \( \,\,\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - 2\alpha } & \beta \\ \beta & { - \gamma } \\ \end{array} } \right) \). It is easy to verify that when \( \gamma > 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha \), the function is concave with finite maxima. □
Proof of Proposition 3
The gradient and the Hessian of \( \varPi_{m} (p,q,\eta ) = (1 - \eta )p(a - \alpha p + \beta q) - \gamma {{q^{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{q^{2} } 2}} \right. \kern-0pt} 2} \) with respect to p and q are
It is easy to verify that when \( \gamma > 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha \), the profit function is concave. Solving \( \nabla \varPi_{m} (p,q|\eta ) = 0 \), we obtain the manufacturer’s best response for \( \eta < 1 \):
and
The derivative of \( \varPi_{r} (\eta ,p(n),q(n)) = \eta p(n)(a - \alpha p(n) + \beta q(n)) \) with respect to \( \eta \) is
\( \frac{{a^{2} \alpha \gamma^{2} }}{{(2\alpha \gamma - (1 - \eta )\beta^{2} )^{3} }} \) is positive because \( \gamma > 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha \). Therefore, the sign of the derivative is dictated by \( 2\alpha \gamma - (1 + \eta )\beta^{2} \).
(i) When \( \gamma < \beta^{2} /\alpha \), \( 2\alpha \gamma - (1 + \eta )\beta^{2} \) crosses 0 only once and it is from above; therefore, \( \varPi_{r} (\eta ,p(\eta ),q(\eta )) \) is quasi-concave with a maximum point \( \eta^{*} = (2\alpha \gamma - \beta^{2} )/\beta^{2} \),\( \eta^{*} \in (0,1) \). Substituting \( \eta^{*} \) into (A.1) and (A.2) yields the equilibrium price and quality level. The retailer’s and manufacturer’s profits at equilibrium are obtained by substituting \( \eta^{*} ,p^{*} \) and q* into (7) and (8), respectively.
(ii) Otherwise, if \( \alpha \gamma - \beta^{2} \ge 0 \), then \( \varPi_{r} (\eta ,p(\eta ),q(\eta )) \) monotonically increases and hence is maximized at \( \eta = 1 \). □
Proof of Proposition 4
(i) Similarly to the proof of Proposition 3, by substituting the expressions of (7) and (8) into optimization problem (4), we obtain \( \hat{\eta }^{*} = \frac{{2\alpha \hat{\gamma } - \beta^{2} }}{{\beta^{2} }} \) for \( \frac{{\beta^{2} }}{2\alpha } < \hat{\gamma } < \frac{{\beta^{2} }}{\alpha } \). Substituting \( \hat{\eta }^{*} \) into (A.1) and (A.2) yields the equilibrium price and quality level. The retailer’s and manufacturer’s profits at equilibrium are obtained by substituting \( \hat{\eta }^{*} ,\hat{p}^{*} \) and \( \hat{q}^{*} \) into (7) and (8), respectively.
(ii) If \( \hat{\gamma } \ge \beta^{2} /\alpha \), then \( \varPi_{r} (\eta ,p(\eta ),q(\eta )) \) monotonically increases and hence is maximized at \( \eta = 1 \). □
Proof of Corollary 4
(i) We prove the claim using simple calculus. (ii) Straightforward from Proposition 1. (iii) By Proposition 2, \( \varPi_{m} (p^{*} ,q^{*} ,\eta^{*} ) \ge \varPi_{m} (\hat{p}^{*} ,\hat{q}^{*} ,\hat{\eta }^{*} ) \) if and only if \( \eta^{*} = \frac{{2\alpha \gamma - \beta^{2} }}{{\beta^{2} }} < \frac{{2\alpha \hat{\gamma } - \beta^{2} }}{{\beta^{2} }} = \hat{\eta }^{*} \), that is, if and only if \( \gamma < \hat{\gamma } \). □
Proof of Lemma 2
Set \( \varOmega = \left\{ {x|0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha < x < \beta^{2} /\alpha } \right\} \) according to the conditions of Proposition 3(i). Following (5), the retailer, based on her belief, sets her equilibrium revenue share \( \eta_{f}^{*} \) by solving
The claim is proved by substituting the last two expressions into the objective function of (A.3). □
Proof of Lemma 3
As stated in Sect. 3.2.1, the optimal \( \eta_{b}^{*} \) solves \( \max_{\eta } \left\{ {\min_{x \in \varOmega } \left[ {\varPi_{r} (\eta ,p(\eta ,x),q(\eta ,x))} \right]} \right\} \). Substituting expression (A.4) into the retailer’s profit (7), we obtain
which can be shown to be a decreasing function of x. Thus, its minimal value is attained at \( x = \beta^{2} /\alpha \), which according to Proposition 3(ii), yields \( \eta = 1 \). □
Proof of Lemma 4
According to Sect. 3.2.1, \( \eta_{b}^{*} = \arg \min_{\eta } \left\{ {\max_{x \in \varOmega } \left[ {G(\eta ,x)} \right]} \right\} \), where \( G(\eta ,x) \equiv \max_{\eta } \left[ {\eta R(s(\eta ,x))} \right] - \eta R(s(\eta ,x)) \). By Proposition 3, for any \( x \in \varOmega \), \( \max_{\eta } \left[ {\eta R(s(\eta ,x))} \right] = \varPi_{r} (\eta^{*} (x),p^{*} (x),q^{*} (x)) = \frac{{a^{2} x^{2} \alpha }}{{4\beta^{2} (2\alpha x - \beta^{2} )}} \), which is the retailer’s maximal profit for a given manufacturer’s efficiency. Using (A.5), \( G(\eta ,x) = \frac{{a^{2} x^{2} \alpha }}{{4\beta^{2} (2\alpha x - \beta^{2} )}} - \frac{{a^{2} x^{2} \alpha \eta }}{{(2\alpha x - \beta^{2} (1 - \eta ))^{2} }} \). To find the maximum value of \( G(\eta ,x) \), consider the first derivative of \( G(\eta ,x) \) with respect to x over \( \varOmega = \left\{ {x|0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha < x < \beta^{2} /\alpha } \right\} \):
where \( \varLambda (x) \equiv 4\alpha^{3} x^{3} - 8\alpha^{2} \beta^{2} (1 - \eta )x^{2} + \alpha \beta^{4} (1 - \eta )(5 + \eta )x - \beta^{6} (1 - \eta^{2} ) \). The polynomial equation \( \varLambda (x) = 0 \) has only one real root, and \( \varLambda (0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha ) = 0.125\beta^{6} \eta^{2} > 0 \) and \( \varLambda (\beta^{2} /\alpha ) = \beta^{6} \eta > 0 \). In addition, \( \frac{\partial }{\partial x}G(\eta ,x) = 0 \) at \( x = 0.5\beta^{2} (1 + \eta )/\alpha \) and \( \left. {\frac{{\partial^{2} }}{{\partial x^{2} }}G(\eta ,x)} \right|_{{x = \frac{{\beta^{2} (1 + \eta )}}{2\alpha }}} = \frac{{a^{2} \alpha (1 + \eta )^{2} }}{{8\beta^{4} \eta^{3} }} > 0. \) Consequently, over \( \varOmega = \left\{ {\gamma |0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha < \gamma < \beta^{2} /\alpha } \right\} \), \( G(\eta ,x) \) has a unique minimum, which implies \( \max_{x \in \varOmega } \left[ {G(\eta ,x)} \right] = \hbox{max} \left( {\mathop {\lim }\limits_{{x \to 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha }} G(\eta ,x),\mathop {\lim }\limits_{{x \to \beta^{2} /\alpha }} G(\eta ,x)} \right) \). Because \( \mathop {\lim }\limits_{{x \to 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha }} G(\eta ,x) = \infty \) and \( \mathop {\lim }\limits_{{x \to \beta^{2} /\alpha }} G(\eta ,x) = \frac{{a^{2} (1 - \eta )^{2} }}{{4\alpha (1 + \eta )^{2} }} \), for any \( 0 \le \eta \le 1 \),\( \max_{x \in \varOmega } \left[ {G(\eta ,x)} \right] = \mathop {\lim }\limits_{{x \to 0.5\beta^{2} /\alpha }} G(\eta ,x) \). Because \( \frac{\partial }{\partial \eta }G(\eta ,x) = \frac{{a^{2} }}{{4\alpha \eta^{2} }} > 0 \), \( \eta_{b}^{*} = 0 \) solves \( \min_{\eta } \left\{ {\max_{x \in \varOmega } \left[ {G(\eta ,x)} \right]} \right\}. \) □
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Chernonog, T. Strategic information sharing in online retailing under a consignment contract with revenue sharing. Ann Oper Res 300, 621–641 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03807-1
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03807-1