Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of dual fairness concerns on bargaining game and its dynamic system stability

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper introduces dual fairness concerns into the classic two-level supply chain consisting of the fairness neutral supplier and fairness concerned retailers. The bargaining process is modeled under both simultaneous and sequential game to analyze the different situation of fairness concerns. The impact of dual fairness concerns is considered comprehensively on both short-term and long-term games. In short-term game, we conduct a sensitivity analysis on the optimal decision in a single cycle and find that the bargaining power and distributional fairness concern has opposite effects on the optimal solutions. Similarly, the impact of dual fairness concerns on that is also opposite. In long-term game, the dynamic system is constructed to investigate the influence of dual fairness concerns on system stability. At last, comparing the performance of the supplier and retailers, this paper explores the supplier’s timing choice based on the equilibrium point. The comparison shows that sequential game is more beneficial to the supplier because peer-induced fairness concern exacerbates the internal friction of retailers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ahmed, E., & Elettreby, M. F. (2014). Controls of the complex dynamics of a multi-market Cournot model. Economic Modelling, 37(2), 251–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aydin, G., & Heese, H. S. (2015). Bargaining for an assortment. Management Science, 61(3), 542–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bao, B., Ma, J., & Goh, M. (2020). Short-and long-term repeated game behaviors of two parallel supply chains based on government subsidy in the vehicle market. International Journal of Production Research, 58(24), 7507–7530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, J., Zhang, T., Zhou, Y., & Zhong, Y. (2020). Joint decision of pricing and ordering in stochastic demand with Nash bargaining fairness. Computers & Operations Research, 123(11), 105037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, Y., & Cui, T. H. (2013). The benefit of uniform price for branded variants. Marketing Science, 32(1), 36–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, S. H., & Tang, C. S. (2013). Advance selling in a supply chain under uncertain supply and demand. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 15(2), 305–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, S., & Messinger, P. R. (2016). The role of fairness in competitive supply chain relationships: An experimental study. European Journal of Operational Research, 251(3), 798–813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, T. M. (2020). Supply chain financing using blockchain: Impacts on supply chains selling fashionable products. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-020-03615-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cui, T. H., Raju, J. S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2007). Fairness and channel coordination. Management Science, 53(8), 1303–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, A. M., & Hyndman, K. (2019). Multidimensional bargaining and inventory risk in supply chains: An experimental study. Management Science, 65(3), 1286–1304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du, S., Ma, F., Fu, Z., Zhu, L., & Zhang, J. (2015). Game-theoretic analysis for an emission-dependent supply chain in a ‘cap-and-trade’ system. Annals of Operations Research, 228(1), 135–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du, S., Nie, T., Chu, C., & Yu, Y. (2014). Newsvendor model for a dyadic supply chain with Nash bargaining fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Research, 52(17), 5070–5085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Du, S., Wei, L., Zhu, Y., & Nie, T. (2018). Peer-regarding fairness in supply chain. International Journal of Production Research, 56(10), 3384–3396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federgruen, A., Lall, U., & Şimşek, A. S. (2019). Supply chain analysis of contract farming. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 21(2), 361–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fu, Q., Sim, C. K., & Teo, C. P. (2018). Profit sharing agreements in decentralized supply chains: A distributionally robust approach. Operations Research, 66(2), 500–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gal-Or, E. (1985). First mover and second mover advantages. International Economic Review, 26(3), 649–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerchak, Y., & Khmelnitsky, E. (2019). Bargaining over shares of uncertain future profits. EURO Journal on Decision Processes, 7(1), 55–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goller, D. (2022). Analysing a built-in advantage in asymmetric darts contests using causal machine learning. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04563-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant, A., Johnstone, D., & Kwon, O. K. (2008). Optimal betting strategies for simultaneous games. Decision Analysis, 5(1), 10–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, S., Fu, Y., Cao, B., & Luo, Z. (2018). Pricing and bargaining strategy of e-retail under hybrid operational patterns. Annals of Operations Research, 270(1), 179–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayter, S., & Visser, J. (2021). Making collective bargaining more inclusive: The role of extension. International Labour Review, 160(2), 169–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. H., & Su, X. (2009). Peer-induced fairness in games. American Economic Review, 99(5), 2022–2049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. H., Su, X., & Wu, Y. (2014). Distributional and peer-induced fairness in supply chain contract design. Production and Operations Management, 23(2), 161–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu, V. N., Lai, G., Niu, B., & Xiao, W. (2017). Leader-based collective bargaining: Cooperation mechanism and incentive analysis. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 19(1), 72–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Z. (2020). Stochastic differential game in the closed-loop supply chain with fairness concern retailer. Sustainability, 12(8), 3289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, Z., & Li, S. X. (2001). Co-op advertising models in manufacturer–retailer supply chains: A game theory approach. European Journal of Operational Research, 135(3), 527–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jain, T., & Hazra, J. (2019). Vendor’s strategic investments Under IT outsourcing competition. Service Science, 11(1), 16–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katok, E., & Pavlov, V. (2013). Fairness in supply chain contracts: A laboratory study. Journal of Operations Management, 31(3), 129–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leider, S., & Lovejoy, W. S. (2016). Bargaining in supply chains. Management Science, 62(10), 3039–3058.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, B., Hou, P. W., & Li, Q. H. (2017b). Cooperative advertising in a dual-channel supply chain with a fairness concern of the manufacturer. IMA Journal of Management Mathematics, 28(2), 259–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, H., Zhou, W., Elsadany, A. A., & Chu, T. (2021b). Stability, multi-stability and instability in Cournot duopoly game with knowledge spillover effects and relative profit maximization. Chaos Solitons & Fractals. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chaos.2021.110936

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, J., Fan, X., & Dai, B. (2017a). Fairness of extra-gain guilty in performance of supply chain and contract design. Journal of Systems Science and Complexity, 30(4), 866–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, K. J., & Jain, S. (2016). Behavior-based pricing: An analysis of the impact of peer-induced fairness. Management Science, 62(9), 2705–2721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q. (2018). The optimal multi-period modular design with fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Economics, 206(12), 233–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, W., & Chen, J. (2018). Pricing and quality competition in a brand-differentiated supply chain. International Journal of Production Economics, 202(8), 97–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, X., Cui, X., Li, Y., Xu, D., & Xu, F. (2021a). Optimisation of reverse supply chain with used-product collection effort under collector’s fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Research, 59(2), 652–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, L., Parlar, M., & Zhu, S. X. (2007). Pricing and lead time decisions in decentralized supply chains. Management Science, 53(5), 713–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lou, W., & Ma, J. (2018). Complexity of sales effort and carbon emission reduction effort in a two-parallel household appliance supply chain model. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 64(12), 398–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, J., & Xie, L. (2018). The impact of loss sensitivity on a mobile phone supply chain system stability based on the chaos theory. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation, 55(2), 194–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, X., Bao, C., & Su, L. (2020). Analysis of complex dynamics in different bargaining systems. Complexity. https://doi.org/10.1155/2020/8406749

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsui, K. (2020). Optimal bargaining timing of a wholesale price for a manufacturer with a retailer in a dual-channel supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 287(1), 225–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modak, N. M., & Kelle, P. (2019). Managing a dual-channel supply chain under price and delivery-time dependent stochastic demand. European Journal of Operational Research, 272(1), 147–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monroy, L., Rubiales, V., & Mármol, A. M. (2017). The conservative Kalai-Smorodinsky solution for multiple scenario bargaining. Annals of Operations Research, 251(1), 285–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nie, T., & Du, S. (2017). Dual-fairness supply chain with quantity discount contracts. European Journal of Operational Research, 258(2), 491–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panda, S., Modak, N. M., & Cárdenas-Barrón, L. E. (2017). Coordination and benefit sharing in a three-echelon distribution channel with deteriorating product. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 113(11), 630–645.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qin, Y., & Shao, Y. (2019). Supply chain decisions under asymmetric information with cost and fairness concern. Enterprise Information Systems, 13(10), 1347–1366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, A., Dwivedi, G., & Singh, A. (2019). Game-theoretic analysis of a two-echelon supply chain with option contract under fairness concerns. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 137(11), 106096.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stengel, V. B. (2016). Recursive inspection games. Mathematics of Operations Research, 41(3), 935–952.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swinney, R., Cachon, G. P., & Netessine, S. (2011). Capacity investment timing by start-ups and established firms in new markets. Management Science, 57(4), 763–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zheng, X. X., Liu, Z., Li, K. W., Huang, J., & Chen, J. (2019). Cooperative game approaches to coordinating a three-echelon closed-loop supply chain with fairness concerns. International Journal of Production Economics, 212(6), 92–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhou, W., & Wang, X. X. (2019). On the stability and multistability in a duopoly game with R&D spillover and price competition. Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society, 2019(5), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, X., Yang, C., Liu, K., Zhang, R., & Jiang, Q. (2021b). Cooperation and decision making in a two-sided market motivated by the externality of a third-party social media platform. Annals of Operations Research. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-021-04109-w

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhu, Y., Zhou, W., Chu, T., & Elsadany, A. A. (2021a). Complex dynamical behavior and numerical simulation of a Cournot-Bertrand duopoly game with heterogeneous players. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cnsns.2021.105898

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zwick, R., & Chen, X. P. (1999). What price fairness? A bargaining study. Management Science, 45(6), 804–823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The research was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China [No. 71964023]; Special Fund for post-doctoral Innovation Project of Shandong Province [No. 201903025]; The Research Center of Enterprise Decision Support, Key Research Institute of Humanities and Social Sciences in Universities of Hubei Province [No. DSS20210401].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chunyu Bao.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix A: Proofs for main results

Appendix A: Proofs for main results

Proof of lemma 1

Given that \(\overline{\pi }_{S,i} + \overline{\pi }_{{R_{i} }} = \pi_{S,i} + \pi_{{R_{i} }} = \pi_{{_{i} }}\), the Nash bargaining model of retailer \(i\) can be written as: \(\max [\pi_{{R_{i} }} - \lambda_{i} (\frac{{k_{i} }}{{1 - k_{i} }}(\pi_{i} - \overline{\pi }_{{R_{i} }} ) - \pi_{{R_{i} }} )]^{{k_{i} }} [(w_{i} - c)(a - bp_{i} )]^{{1 - k_{i} }}\). The reference profit can be obtained by deriving it.

Proof of proposition 1

In the simultaneous game, the bargaining process is carried out separately. The marginal utility of retailer \(i\) is:

$$ \frac{{\partial U_{{R_{i} }} }}{{\partial p_{i} }} = (1 + \lambda_{i} )(a - 2bp_{i} + bw_{i} - \frac{{k_{i} \lambda_{i} }}{{k_{i} \lambda_{i} + \lambda_{i} + 1}}(a - 2bp_{i} + bc)) $$
(A.1)

By backward induction, the optimal solution can be obtained.

Proof of proposition 2

In the second stage of sequential bargaining game, the supplier negotiates with the retailer 2. The objective of the supplier is:

$$ \pi_{S,2} = (w_{2} - c)(a - bp_{2} ) $$
(A.2)

As the second mover, the retailer 2 has both distributional fairness concern and peer-induced fairness concern. The objective of the retailer 2 is:

$$ U_{{R_{2} }} = \pi_{{R_{2} }} - \lambda_{2} (\frac{{k_{2} }}{{1 - k_{2} }}\overline{\pi }_{S,2} - \pi_{{R_{2} }} ) - \theta (\frac{{k_{2} }}{{k_{1} }}\overline{\pi }_{{R_{1} }} - \pi_{{R_{2} }} ) $$
(A.3)

Considering that \(\overline{\pi }_{S,2} + \overline{\pi }_{{R_{2} }} = \pi_{S,2} + \pi_{{R_{2} }} = \pi_{2}\), the bargaining process can be formulated as:

$$ \max [\pi_{{R_{2} }} - \lambda_{2} (\frac{{k_{2} }}{{1 - k_{2} }}(\pi_{2} - \overline{\pi }_{{R_{2} }} ) - \pi_{{R_{2} }} ) - \theta (\frac{{k_{2} }}{{k_{1} }}\overline{\pi }_{{R_{1} }} - \pi_{{R_{2} }} )]^{{k_{2} }} [(w_{2} - c)(a - bp_{2} )]^{{1 - k_{2} }} $$
(A.4)

The reference profit can be obtained by deriving it. based on the reference points, the utility of the retailer 2 is:

$$ U_{{R_{2} }} = (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )\pi_{{R_{2} }} - \frac{{k_{2} \lambda_{2} (k_{1} (1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} )\pi_{2} - \theta k_{2} \overline{\pi }_{{R_{1} }} )}}{{k_{1} (k_{2} \lambda_{2} + 1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} )}} - \frac{{\theta k_{2} \overline{\pi }_{{R_{1} }} }}{{k_{1} }} $$
(A.5)

The marginal utility of retailer 2 is:

$$ \frac{{\partial U_{{R_{2} }} }}{{\partial p_{2} }} = (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )(a - 2bp_{2} + bw_{2} - \frac{{k_{2} \lambda_{2} }}{{k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \lambda_{2} + \theta + 1}}(a - 2bp_{2} + bc)) $$
(A.6)

By backward induction, the optimal solution can be obtained.

Proof of proposition 3

The proof is similar to that of Proposition 2. In the first stage of sequential bargaining game, the supplier negotiates with the retailer 1. The objective of the supplier is:

$$ \pi_{S,1} = (w_{1} - c)(a - bp_{1} ) $$
(A.7)

As the first mover, the retailer 1 has only distributional fairness concern. The objective of the retailer 1 is:

$$ U_{{R_{1} }} = \pi_{{R_{1} }} - \lambda_{1} (\frac{{k_{1} }}{{1 - k_{1} }}\overline{\pi }_{S,1} - \pi_{{R_{1} }} ) $$
(A.8)

Considering that \(\overline{\pi }_{S,1} + \overline{\pi }_{{R_{1} }} = \pi_{S,1} + \pi_{{R_{1} }} = \pi_{1}\), the bargaining process can be formulated as:

$$ \max [\pi_{{R_{1} }} - \lambda_{1} (\frac{{k_{1} }}{{1 - k_{1} }}\overline{\pi }_{S,1} - \pi_{{R_{1} }} )]^{{k_{1} }} [(w_{1} - c)(a - bp_{1} ) - \pi_{s}^{r} ]^{{1 - k_{1} }} $$
(A.9)

The reference profit can be obtained by deriving it. based on the reference points, the utility of the retailer 2 is:

$$ U_{{R_{1} }} = (1 + \lambda_{1} )\pi_{{R_{1} }} - \frac{{k_{1} \lambda_{1} ((1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 - k_{1} )\pi_{1} + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} )\pi_{s}^{r} )}}{{(1 - k_{1} )(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)}} $$
(A.10)

The marginal utility of retailer 1 is:

$$ \frac{{\partial U_{{R_{1} }} }}{{\partial p_{1} }} = (1 + \lambda_{1} )(a - 2bp_{1} + bw_{1} - \frac{{k_{1} \lambda_{1} }}{{k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + \theta + 1}}(a - 2bp_{2} + bc)) $$
(A.11)

By backward induction, the optimal solution can be obtained.

Proof of proposition 4

In order to ensure that the retailer’s selling price is higher than the wholesale price, \(a > bc\) should be satisfied. The first derivatives of the optimal solutions with respect to bargaining power are:

$$ \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial w_{i}^{*} }}{{\partial k_{i} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)\lambda_{i} (1 + \lambda_{i} )}}{{2b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \pi_{{R_{i} }}^{*} }}{{\partial k_{i} }} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} \lambda_{i} (1 + \lambda_{i} )}}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} > 0 \hfill \\ \frac{{\partial \pi_{S,i}^{*} }}{{\partial k_{i} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} \lambda_{i} (1 + \lambda_{i} )}}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial U_{{R_{i} }}^{*} }}{{\partial k_{i} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} \lambda_{i} (1 + \lambda_{i} )^{2} }}{{16b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} < 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.12)

The profit difference between the supplier and the retailer with only the distributional fairness concern is: \(\pi_{{R_{i} }}^{*} - \pi_{S,i}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (3k_{1} \lambda_{1} - 1 - \lambda_{1} )}}{{16b(1 + \lambda_{1} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} )}}\). Denoting \(\widehat{{k_{i} }} = \frac{{\lambda_{i} + 1}}{{3\lambda_{i} }}\), \(\pi_{{R_{i} }}^{*}\) is higher than \(\pi_{S,i}^{*}\) when \(k_{i} > \widehat{{k_{i} }}\). Similarly, the profit difference between the supplier and the retailer with dual fairness concerns is: \(\pi_{{R_{2} }}^{*} - \pi_{S,2}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (3k_{2} \lambda_{2} - 1 - \lambda_{2} - \theta )}}{{16b(1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}}\). Denoting \(\widehat{{k_{2} }} = \frac{{1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta }}{{3\lambda_{2} }}\), \(\pi_{{R_{2} }}^{*}\) is higher than \(\pi_{S,2}^{*}\) when \(k_{2} > \widehat{{k_{2} }}\).

Proof of proposition 5

The first derivatives of the optimal solutions with respect to the distributional fairness concern are:

$$ \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial w_{i}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{i} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)k_{i} }}{{2b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \pi_{{R_{i} }}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{i} }} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{i} }}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} > 0 \hfill \\ \frac{{\partial \pi_{S,i}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{i} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{i} }}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial U_{{R_{i} }}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{i} }} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (1 + \lambda_{i} )(1 + k_{i} (\lambda_{i} - 1) + \lambda_{i} )}}{{16b(1 + \lambda_{i} + k_{i} \lambda_{i} )^{2} }} > 0 \hfill \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.13)

From the perspective of the retailer with dual fairness concerns, the results are:

$$ \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial w_{2}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{2} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)k_{2} (1 + \theta )}}{{2b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} < 0,\frac{{\partial \pi_{{R_{2} }}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{2} }} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{2} (1 + \theta )}}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} > 0, \\ \frac{{\partial \pi_{S,2}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{2} }} = - \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{2} (1 + \theta )}}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} < 0, \\ \frac{{\partial U_{{R_{2} }}^{*} }}{{\partial \lambda_{2} }} = \frac{{\left[ \begin{gathered} (a - bc)^{2} [k_{2}^{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} )\theta (1 + \theta ) + k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )((1 - k_{2} )(1 + \theta ) + \lambda_{2} (1 + k_{2} )) \hfill \\ + k_{1} [3k_{2}^{2} \lambda_{1} \theta (1 + \theta ) + (1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )(\lambda_{2} (1 + k_{2} ) + (1 - k_{2} )(1 + \theta ))]] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right]}}{{16bk_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} > 0. \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.14)

Considering the above results comprehensively, we can get proposition 5.

Proof of proposition 6

The first derivatives of the optimal solutions with respect to the peer-induced fairness concern are:

$$ \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial w_{2}^{*} }}{\partial \theta } = \frac{{(a - bc)k_{2} \lambda_{2} }}{{2b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} > 0,\frac{{\partial \pi_{{R_{2} }}^{*} }}{\partial \theta } = - \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{2} \lambda_{2} }}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} < 0, \\ \frac{{\partial \pi_{S,2}^{*} }}{\partial \theta } = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{2} \lambda_{2} }}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} > 0, \\ \frac{{\partial U_{{R_{2} }}^{*} }}{\partial \theta } = \frac{{\left[ \begin{gathered} [k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} - k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} ) + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} - 3k_{2} \lambda_{1} )](1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta ) \hfill \\ - k_{2} \lambda_{2} [k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} )\theta - k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta ) - k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta + \lambda_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta - 3k_{2} \theta ))] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right]}}{{16bk_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )^{2} }} < 0. \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.15)

Considering the above results comprehensively, we can get proposition 6.

Proof of proposition 7

Given the Nash equilibrium point \(E^{*}\), the equilibrium solutions of the selling prices are:

$$ p_{1} = \frac{{bk_{1} \lambda_{1} (w_{1} - c) + (\lambda_{1} + 1)(a + bw_{1} )}}{{2b(\lambda_{1} + 1)}},p_{2} = \frac{{bk_{2} \lambda_{2} (w_{2} - c) + (1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} )(a + bw_{2} )}}{{2b(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} )}} $$
(A.16)

By backward induction, the optimal wholesale prices are:

$$ w_{2}^{*} = \frac{{(a + bc)(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} ) + 2bck_{2} \lambda_{2} }}{{2b(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}},w_{1}^{*} = \frac{{a(1 + \lambda_{1} ) + bc(1 + \lambda_{1} + 2k_{1} \lambda_{1} )}}{{2b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)}} $$
(A.17)

Correspondingly, the supplier’s profit and the retailer 2’s utility in the second stage of sequential bargaining game are:

$$ \pi_{S,2}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )}}{{8b(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}},\pi_{{R_{2} }}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta { + }3k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}}{{16b(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}} $$
(A.18)

The supplier’s profit and the retailer 1’s utility in the first stage of sequential bargaining game are:

$$ \pi_{S,1}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} )}}{{8b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)}},\pi_{{R_{1} }}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} + 3k_{1} \lambda_{1} )}}{{16b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)}} $$
(A.19)

Given that, the difference of the supplier’s profits in the negotiation with different retailers is:

$$ \Delta \pi_{S} { = }\pi_{S,2}^{*} - \pi_{S,1}^{*} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} (k_{1} \lambda_{1} - k_{2} \lambda_{2} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} \lambda_{2} - k_{2} \lambda_{1} \lambda_{2} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} \theta )}}{{8b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )}} $$
(A.20)

Denoting that \(\widehat{\theta } = \frac{{ - k_{1} \lambda_{1} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} - k_{1} \lambda_{1} \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{1} \lambda_{2} }}{{k_{1} \lambda_{1} }}\), when \(\theta > \widehat{\theta }\), \(\Delta \pi_{S} > 0\).

Proof of proposition 8

The difference of the supplier’s profits in the negotiation with different retailers is:

$$ \begin{aligned}\Delta U_{R} &= U_{{R_{2} }}^{*} - U\pi_{{R_{1} }}^{*} \\&= \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} \left[ \begin{gathered} (1 - k_{1} )[k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} - k_{2} (\lambda_{1} + 1) + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} - 3k_{2} \lambda_{1} )]\theta^{2} + [2k_{1}^{3} \lambda_{1} (\lambda_{1} - \lambda_{2} ) \hfill \\ - k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} ) + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 - \lambda_{1} + 2\lambda_{2} ) + k_{1} k_{2} (1 - 2\lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} ) \hfill \\ + k_{1}^{2} (\lambda_{1}^{2} - 1 - 2\lambda_{2} + \lambda_{1} (2 + 3k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} )))]\theta + k_{1} [(1 - k_{1} )(1 - k_{2} + \lambda_{2} )\lambda_{2} \hfill \\ - \lambda_{1}^{2} (1 + (1 + \lambda_{2} )\lambda_{2} - 2k_{1}^{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} ) - k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )) \hfill \\ - \lambda_{1} (1 + 2k_{2} \lambda_{2} - \lambda_{2}^{2} - 2k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} ) - k_{1}^{2} (1 - \lambda_{2}^{2} ))] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right]}}{{16b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )k_{1} (1 - k_{1} )}}\end{aligned} $$
(A.21)

The threshold \(\widehat{\theta }^{\prime }\) can be obtained by solving \(\Delta U_{R} = 0\). Next, we prove the uniqueness of zero point. Since that \(\frac{{(a - bc)^{2} }}{{16b(k_{1} \lambda_{1} + \lambda_{1} + 1)(1 + \theta + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )k_{1} (1 - k_{1} )}} > 0\), it can also be transformed into the discussion of zero point of \(f(\theta )\). Where,

$$ \begin{gathered} f(\theta ) = (1 - k_{1} )[k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} - k_{2} (\lambda_{1} + 1) + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} - 3k_{2} \lambda_{1} )]\theta^{2} + [2k_{1}^{3} \lambda_{1} (\lambda_{1} - \lambda_{2} ) - k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} ) \\ + k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} )(1 - \lambda_{1} + 2\lambda_{2} ) + k_{1} k_{2} (1 - 2\lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} ) + k_{1}^{2} (\lambda_{1}^{2} - 1 - 2\lambda_{2} + \lambda_{1} (2 + 3k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} )))]\theta \\ + k_{1} [(1 - k_{1} )(1 - k_{2} + \lambda_{2} )\lambda_{2} - \lambda_{1}^{2} (1 + (1 + \lambda_{2} )\lambda_{2} - 2k_{1}^{2} (1 + \lambda_{2} ) - k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )) \\ - \lambda_{1} (1 + 2k_{2} \lambda_{2} - \lambda_{2}^{2} - 2k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} ) - k_{1}^{2} (1 - \lambda_{2}^{2} ))] \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.22)

The first derivative of it is:

$$ \begin{gathered} f^{\prime}(\theta ) = - k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} )[(1 - k_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{1} ) - 2k_{1}^{2} \lambda_{1} ] - (1 - k_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )[k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} + 3k_{1} \lambda_{1} )] \\ - (1 - k_{1} )[k_{2} (1 + \lambda_{1} + 3k_{1} \lambda_{1} )\theta - k_{1} (1 + \lambda_{1} + k_{1} \lambda_{1} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + \theta )] \\ \end{gathered} $$
(A.23)

Since that \(f^{\prime}(\theta ) < 0\),\(f(0) > 0\),\(f(1) < 0\), there is a unique zero point.

Proof of proposition 9

The difference of the supplier’s profits in both games is:

$$ \Delta \pi_{S}^{\prime } = \pi_{{\text{S}}}^{Seq} - \pi_{{\text{S}}}^{Sim} = \frac{{(a - bc)^{2} k_{2} \lambda_{2} \theta }}{{8b(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} )(1 + \lambda_{2} + k_{2} \lambda_{2} + \theta )}} > 0 $$
(A.24)

Therefore, the supplier can profit more from the sequential game than from the simultaneous game.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ma, X., Bao, C., Li, J. et al. The impact of dual fairness concerns on bargaining game and its dynamic system stability. Ann Oper Res 318, 357–382 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04851-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-022-04851-9

Keywords