Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A product strategy for daily deal campaigns utilizing demand expansion and consumer leakage

  • Published:
Electronic Commerce Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Daily deal campaigns help local service merchants expand their market demand, which also result in consumer leakage concerns. This paper investigates how to exercise product strategies, i.e., price and quality decisions, for daily deal campaigns through a systematic exploration of demand expansion and consumer leakage. We consider a local service merchant who currently sells a product in his or her local market and who might contract with a platform to introduce daily deal campaigns. We document how the demand expansion and consumer leakage effects jointly affect a merchant’s product strategy. Particularly, we find it not always profitable to introduce daily deal campaigns amid relatively low levels of the demand expansion effect. Moreover, a merchant should adopt the product strategy of overlooking (inhibiting) consumer leakage amid relatively low (high) levels of the consumer leakage effect. In addition, we discuss the strategic role of a platform’s agency fees on leveraging a merchant’s product strategy. Based on this, we take a platform’s perspective to examine how to establish optimal agency fees amid various market conditions. Our results provide useful insights for firms in the daily deal business on how to carry out more intelligent marketing strategies. Our conclusions also cater to other businesses, wherein offline merchants could adopt online platforms to expand their demand while addressing the issue of consumer leakage.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Anderson, E. T., & Song, I. (2004). Coordinating price reductions and coupon events. Journal of Marketing Research., 41(4), 411–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Bhardwaj, P., & Sajeesh, S. (2017). Strategic revenue sharing with daily deal sites: A competitive analysis. Decision Sciences., 48(6), 1228–1261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Byers, J. W., Mitzenmacher, M., & Zervas, G. (2011). Daily deals: Prediction, social diffusion, and reputational ramifications. In Proceeding Fifth ACM WSDM Conference Web Search Data Mining (ACM, New York), 543–552.

  4. Cao, Z., Hui, K. L., & Xu, H. (2018). When discounts hurt sales: The case of daily-deal markets. Information Systems Research., 29(3), 567–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Che, T., Peng, Z., & Hua, Z. (2016). Characteristics of online group-buying website and consumers intention to revisit: The moderating effects of visit channels. Electronic Commerce Research., 16(2), 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Dholakia U. M. (2011). How businesses fare with daily deals: A multisite analysis of Groupon, Living Social, Open Table, Travel zoo, and Buy with me promotions. Working Paper.

  7. Edelman, B., Jaffe, S., & Kominers, S. D. (2016). To Groupon or not to Groupon: The profitability of deep discounts. Marketing Letter., 27(1), 39–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Guo, L., & Zhang, J. (2012). Consumer deliberation and product line design. Marketing Science., 31(6), 995–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Gupta, S., Weaver, R., Keiningham, T., & Williams, L. (2012). Are daily deals good for merchants? Harvard Business School Case 9–513–059.

  10. Hu, M., Li, X., & Shi, M. (2015). Product and pricing decisions in crowdfunding. Marketing Science., 34(3), 331–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Hu, M., Dang, C., & Chintagunta, P. K. (2019). Search and learning at a daily deals website. Marketing Science., 38(4), 609–642.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Hu, M., & Winer, R. S. (2017). The “tipping point” feature of social coupons: An empirical investigation. International Journal of Research in Marketing., 34(1), 120–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Ke, C., Yan, B., & Xu, R. (2017). A group-buying mechanism for considering strategic consumer behavior. Electronic Commerce Research., 17(4), 721–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Kukar-Kinney, M., Scheinbaum, A. C., & Schaefers, T. (2016). Compulsive buying in online daily deal settings: An investigation of motivations and contextual elements. Journal of Business Research., 69(2), 691–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Kukar-Kinney, M., & Xia, L. (2017). The effectiveness of number of deals purchased in influencing consumers’ response to daily deal promotions: A cue utilization approach. Journal of Business Research., 79, 189–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Kumar, V., & Rajan, B. (2012). Social coupons as a marketing strategy: A multifaceted perspective. Journal of Academy Marketing Science., 40(1), 120–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Li, X., & Wu, L. (2018). Herding and social media word-of-mouth: Evidence from Groupon. MIS Quarterly., 42(4), 1331–1351.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Marinesi, S., Girotra, K., & Netessine, S. (2018). The operational advantages of threshold discounting offers. Management Science., 64(6), 2690–2708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Moorthy, K. S. (1984). Market segmentation, self-selection, and product line design. Marketing Science., 3(4), 288–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Mussa, M., & Rosen, S. (1978). Monopoly and product quality. Journal of Economic Theory., 18(2), 301–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Narasimhan, C. (1984). A price discrimination theory of coupons. Marketing Science., 3(2), 128–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Netessine, S., & Taylor, T. A. (2007). Product line design and production technology. Marketing Science., 26(1), 101–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Reimers, I., & Xie, C. (2018). Do coupons expand or cannibalize revenue? Evidence from an e-Market. Management Science., 65(1), 286–300.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Shao, J., Krishnan, H., & McCormick, S. T. (2013). Distributing a product line in a decentralized supply chain. Production and Operations Management., 22(1), 151–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Song, M., Park, E., Yoo, Y., & Jeon, S. (2016). Is the daily deal social shopping? An empirical analysis of customer panel data. Journal of Interactive Marketing 33: 57-76

  26. Subramanian, U., & Rao, R. C. (2016). Leveraging experienced consumers to attract new consumers: An equilibrium analysis of displaying deal sales by daily deal websites. Management Science, 62(12), 3555–3575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Tang, Y., Chen, R., & Guan, X. (2021). Daily-deal market with consumer retention: Price discrimination or quality differentiation. Omega, 102, 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Villas-Boas, J. M. (1998). Product line design for a distribution channel. Marketing Science., 17(2), 156–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Villas-Boas, J. M. (2004). Communication strategies and product line design. Marketing Science, 23(3), 304–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Wu, Y., & Zhu, L. (2017). Joint quality and pricing decisions for service online group-buying strategy. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 25, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Zhang, L., & Chung, D. J. (2020). Price bargaining and competition in online platforms: An empirical analysis of the daily deal market. Marketing Science, 39(4), 687–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Zhang, J., Savage, S. J., & Chen, Y. (2015). Consumer uncertainty and price discrimination through online coupons: An empirical study of restaurants in Shanghai. Information Economics and Policy, 33, 43–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Zhao, M., Wang, Y., & X, Gan. (2016). Signaling effect of daily deal promotion for a start-up service provider. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 67(2), 280–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author acknowledges the invaluable contributions of the editors and three anonymous reviewers, whose constructive comments significantly improved our work in many ways. The author received financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grants 72101271 and 71701212] and the National Social Science Fund of China [Grants 21BGL035].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yao Tang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: proofs of propositions

Appendix: proofs of propositions

Proposition 1

By using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage, the merchant designs price \({p}_{d}\) and quality \({q}_{d}\) in daily deal campaigns to optimize the following problem:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d}} \;\;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {{p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {\left( {p_l^* - \frac{1}{2}{{\left( {q_l^*} \right)}^2}} \right) - \left( {{p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)} \right)\beta$$
$$s.t.\;\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_d} < p_l^* = 1\;} \\ {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1\;} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \end{array}} \right.$$

It shows that \(\Delta \pi\) is increasing in \({p}_{d}\), and thus, given any feasible quality \({q}_{d}<{q}_{l}^{*}=1\), the optimal price should be set as \({p}_{d}({q}_{d})=\theta {q}_{d}<{p}_{l}^{*}=1\). We enter this optimal mapping into the function \(\Delta \pi\) and obtain the optimal quality as \({q}_{d}^{*}=\theta <{q}_{l}^{*}=1\), the optimal price as \({p}_{d}^{*}={\theta }^{2}<{p}_{l}^{*}=1\), and the optimal profit change as \({\Delta \pi }^{*}=\frac{1}{2}({\theta }^{2}n-(1-{\theta }^{2})\beta )\). Thus, it is profitable for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage given \({\Delta \pi }^{*}\ge 0\), i.e., \(\beta \le \frac{{\theta }^{2}}{1-{\theta }^{2}}n\).

These complete the proof of proposition 1.

Proposition 2

By using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage, the merchant designs price \({p}_{d}\) and quality \({q}_{d}\) in daily deal campaigns and redesigns retail price \({p}_{l}\) to optimize the following problem:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d},{p_l}} \;\;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {{p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {1 - {p_l}} \right)$$
$$s.t.\;\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_d} < {p_l}} \\ {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1} \\ {q_l^* - {p_l} \geq 0} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \\ {q_l^* - {p_l} \geq {q_d} - {p_d}} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq \theta q_l^* - {p_l}} \end{array}} \right.$$

The final two inequalities indicate that \({p}_{d}+\theta ({q}_{l}^{*}-{q}_{d})\le {p}_{l}\le {p}_{d}+{q}_{l}^{*}-{q}_{d}\). Moreover, it shows that \(\Delta \pi\) increases in \({p}_{l}\) given any feasible bundle of \({p}_{d}\) and \({q}_{d}\). Thus, the optimal redesigned price in the local market should be set as \({p}_{l}={p}_{d}+{q}_{l}^{*}-{q}_{d}\). Based on this optimal mapping, we readily obtain \({p}_{d}<{p}_{l}\) due to \({q}_{d}<{q}_{l}^{*}\), which allows us to remove the first inequality from the problem. Moreover, simple exploration shows that we have \({q}_{l}^{*}-{p}_{l}\ge 0\) given \(\theta {q}_{d}-{p}_{d}\ge 0\) and \({q}_{l}^{*}-{p}_{l}\ge {q}_{d}-{p}_{d}\). Thus, we can remove the third inequality from the problem. By using these properties we rewrite the original problem as follows:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d}} \;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {{p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {1 - \left( {{p_d} + q_l^* - {q_d}} \right)} \right)$$
$$s.t.\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1\;} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \end{array}} \right.$$

This shows that \(\Delta \pi\) is increasing in \({p}_{d}\) under any feasible \({q}_{d}\), and thus the optimal price should be set as \({p}_{d}({q}_{d})=\theta {q}_{d}\). Entering \({p}_{d}=\theta {q}_{d}\) and \({q}_{l}^{*}=1\) into function \(\Delta \pi\), we obtain that \(\Delta \pi =-\frac{n}{2}{q}_{d}^{2}+(n\theta -(1-\theta )){q}_{d}\). Therefore, the optimal quality in daily deal campaigns is \({q}_{d}^{*}=\theta -\frac{1-\theta }{n}\) and the optimal price is \({p}_{d}^{*}=\theta {q}_{d}^{*}={\theta }^{2}-\frac{\theta \left(1-\theta \right)}{n}\). The optimal redesigned price in the local market is \({p}_{l}^{*}={p}_{d}^{*}+{q}_{l}^{*}-{q}_{d}^{*}=\frac{({\theta }^{2}+1)(n+1)}{n}-\frac{\theta (n+2)}{n}\). The optimal profit change is \({\Delta \pi }^{*}=(\theta {q}_{d}^{*}-\frac{1}{2}{\left({q}_{d}^{*}\right)}^{2})n-({q}_{d}^{*}-\theta {q}_{d}^{*})=\frac{1}{2n}{(\theta n-(1-\theta ))}^{2}\). Thus, the merchant introduces daily deal campaigns under a condition \(n\ge \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\), which also ensures \({q}_{d}^{*}\ge 0\) and \({p}_{d}^{*}\ge 0\). Otherwise, if \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\), then it is unprofitable to introduce daily deal campaigns for the merchant by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage.

These complete the proof of proposition 2.

Proposition 3

We first discuss the optimal product strategy in daily deal markets with \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\). Proposition 1 indicates that the merchant introduces daily deal campaigns under \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) if \(\beta \le {\beta }_{1}=\frac{{\theta }^{2}}{1-{\theta }^{2}}n\) by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage. Proposition 2 shows that it is not applicable to introduce daily deal campaigns under \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage. Therefore, it is optimal for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage under \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) with \(\beta \le {\beta }_{1}\). Otherwise, the merchant should not introduce daily deal campaigns under \(n\le \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) with \(\beta \ge {\beta }_{1}\).

We then examine the optimal product strategy in daily deal markets with \(n\ge \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\). Proposition 1 indicates that the merchant should introduce daily deal campaigns under \(n\ge \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) if \(\beta \le {\beta }_{1}\) by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage. Proposition 2 shows that it is profitable to introduce daily deal campaigns under \(\frac{\theta }{1-\theta }n\ge 1\) by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage. Thus, we need to contrast these two strategies to draw the final conclusions. We know that the optimal profit change is \(\frac{1}{2}({\theta }^{2}n-(1-{\theta }^{2})\beta )\) in proposition 1 and \(\frac{1}{2n}{(n\theta -(1-\theta ))}^{2}\) in proposition 2. Thus, we let \(\frac{1}{2}({\theta }^{2}n-(1-{\theta }^{2})\beta )-\frac{1}{2n}{(n\theta -(1-\theta ))}^{2}\ge 0\) and obtain \(\beta \le {\beta }_{2}=\frac{2n\theta +\theta -1}{n(1+\theta )}\). Moreover, simple exploration shows that \({\beta }_{2}\le {\beta }_{1}\). Therefore, it is optimal for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage under \(n\ge \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) with \(\beta \ge {\beta }_{2}\). Otherwise, it is optimal for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage under \(n\ge \frac{1-\theta }{\theta }\) with \(\beta \le {\beta }_{2}\).

These complete the proof of proposition 3.

Proposition 4

Similar to the proof of proposition 1, the merchant designs the price \({p}_{d}\) and quality \({q}_{d}\) in daily deal campaigns to optimize the following problem:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d}} \;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {\left( {1 - \gamma } \right){p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {\left( {p_l^* - \frac{1}{2}{{\left( {q_l^*} \right)}^2}} \right) - \left( {\left( {1 - \gamma } \right){p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)} \right)\beta$$
$$s.t.\;\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_d} < p_l^* = 1\;} \\ {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1\;} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \end{array}} \right.$$

It shows that \(\Delta \pi\) is increasing in \({p}_{d}\), and thus, given any feasible quality \({q}_{d}<{q}_{l}^{*}=1\) and agency fee \(\gamma\), the optimal price should be set as \({p}_{d}({q}_{d})=\theta {q}_{d}<{p}_{l}^{*}=1\). We enter this optimal mapping into function \(\Delta \pi\) and obtain the optimal quality as \({q}_{d}^{*}=(1-\gamma )\theta <{q}_{l}^{*}=1\), the optimal price as \({p}_{d}^{*}=\left(1-\gamma \right){\theta }^{2}<{p}_{l}^{*}=1\), and the optimal profit change as \({\Delta \pi }^{*}=\frac{1}{2}({(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2}n-(1-{(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2})\beta )\). Thus, after considering agency fees, it is profitable for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage with \({\Delta \pi }^{*}\ge 0\), which gives \(\beta \le \frac{{\left(1-\gamma \right)}^{2}{\theta }^{2}}{1-{\left(1-\gamma \right)}^{2}{\theta }^{2}}n\).

These complete the proof of proposition 4.

Proposition 5

Similar to the proof of proposition 2, the merchant designs the price \({p}_{d}\) and quality \({q}_{d}\) in daily deal campaigns and redesigns retail price \({p}_{l}\) in the local market to optimize the following problem:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d},{p_l}} \;\;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {\left( {1 - \gamma } \right){p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {1 - {p_l}} \right)$$
$$s.t.\;\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{p_d} < {p_l}} \\ {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1} \\ {q_l^* - {p_l} \geq 0} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \\ {q_l^* - {p_l} \geq {q_d} - {p_d}} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq \theta q_l^* - {p_l}} \end{array}} \right.$$

By a similar token used in the proof of proposition 2, we can reduce the above problem as follows:

$$\mathop {\max }\limits_{{p_d},{q_d}} \;\;\;\Delta \pi = \left( {\left( {1 - \gamma } \right){p_d} - \frac{1}{2}q_d^2} \right)n - \left( {1 - \left( {{p_d} + q_l^* - {q_d}} \right)} \right)$$
$$s.t.\;\;\;\left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {{q_d} < q_l^* = 1\;} \\ {\theta {q_d} - {p_d} \geq 0} \end{array}} \right.$$

It shows that \(\Delta \pi\) is increasing in \({p}_{d}\) given any feasible \({q}_{d}\) and \(\gamma\), and thus the optimal price should be set as \({p}_{d}({q}_{d})=\theta {q}_{d}\). Entering \({p}_{d}=\theta {q}_{d}\) and \({q}_{l}^{*}=1\) into function \(\Delta \pi\), we obtain that \(\Delta \pi =-\frac{n}{2}{q}_{d}^{2}+((1-\gamma )n\theta -(1-\theta )){q}_{d}\). Therefore, the optimal quality in daily deal campaigns is \({q}_{d}^{*}=(1-\gamma )\theta -\frac{1-\theta }{n}\), and the optimal price is \({p}_{d}^{*}=\theta {q}_{d}^{*}=(1-\gamma ){\theta }^{2}-\frac{\theta \left(1-\theta \right)}{n}\). The optimal redesigned price in the local market is \({p}_{l}^{*}={p}_{d}^{*}+{q}_{l}^{*}-{q}_{d}^{*}=\frac{({\theta }^{2}+1)(n+1)}{n}-\frac{\theta \left(n+2\right)}{n}+\gamma \theta (1-\theta )\). The optimal profit change is \({\Delta \pi }^{*}=\frac{1}{2n}{(\left(1-\gamma \right)\theta n-(1-\theta ))}^{2}\). Thus, after considering a platform’s agency fees, it is profitable for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage with \({\Delta \pi }^{*}\ge 0\), which further gives \(\gamma \le 1-\frac{1-\theta }{\theta n}\).

These complete the proof of proposition 5.

Proposition 6

We first discuss the optimal product strategy in daily deal markets with \(\gamma \ge 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\). Proposition 4 indicates that the merchant should introduce daily deal campaign by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage under \(\gamma \ge 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\) if \(\beta \le {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{2}=\frac{{\left(1-\gamma \right)}^{2}{\theta }^{2}}{1-{\left(1-\gamma \right)}^{2}{\theta }^{2}}n\). Proposition 5 shows that it is not applicable to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage under \(\gamma \ge 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\). Thus, it is optimal to introduce daily deal campaigns by the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage under \(\gamma \ge 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\) with \(\beta \le {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{2}\). Otherwise, the merchant should not introduce daily-deal campaigns under \(\gamma \ge 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\) with \(\beta \ge {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{2}\).

We then examine the optimal product strategy in daily deal markets with \(\gamma \le 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\). We need to contrast two product strategies to obtain the final conclusions. We know that the optimal profit change is \(\frac{1}{2}({(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2}n-(1-{(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2})\beta )\) in proposition 4 and \(\frac{1}{2n}{(\left(1-\gamma \right)\theta n-(1-\theta ))}^{2}\) in proposition 5. Thus, we let \(\frac{1}{2}({(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2}n-(1-{(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2})\beta )-\frac{1}{2n}{(\left(1-\gamma \right)\theta n-(1-\theta ))}^{2}\ge 0\) and obtain \(\beta \le \frac{2\left(1-\gamma \right)\theta \left(1-\theta \right)-\frac{{(1-\theta )}^{2}}{n}}{1-{(1-\gamma )}^{2}{\theta }^{2}}={\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{1}\). Moreover, simple exploration shows \({\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{1}\le {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{2}\). Therefore, it is optimal for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of inhibiting consumer leakage under \(\gamma \le 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\) with \(\beta \ge {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{1}\). Otherwise, it is optimal for the merchant to introduce daily deal campaigns by using the product strategy of overlooking consumer leakage under \(\gamma \le 1-\frac{1-\theta }{n\theta }\) with \(\beta \le {\stackrel{\sim }{\beta }}_{1}\).

These complete the proof of proposition 6.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tang, Y. A product strategy for daily deal campaigns utilizing demand expansion and consumer leakage. Electron Commer Res 23, 1861–1883 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-021-09519-3

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-021-09519-3

Keywords