Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Strategic introduction for competitive fresh produce in an e-commerce platform with demand information sharing

  • Published:
Electronic Commerce Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To satisfy consumers’ diverse demands for fresh produce, the supplier may introduce competitive fresh produce through the reselling or agency channel of the platform to expand market coverage. Under the uncertain market environment, the supplier faces the problem of how to choose the appropriate product introduction strategy to promote information sharing cooperation, and the platform faces how to implement information sharing strategy under different product introduction strategies. This paper attempts to solve these problems and provide practical guidance for the cooperation between the supplier and the platform. Aiming at a fresh produce supply chain comprised of a supplier providing the freshness-keeping effort and a platform owning private demand information, we model a multistage game under asymmetric information to study the two strategies. Our results indicate that the platform may share information voluntarily, depending on the competition intensity and freshness sensitivity. To promote the information sharing cooperation with the platform, the supplier may choose introduction with agency selling even if a high commission fee is charged. Since information sharing promotes the product introduction strategy and vice versa, we reveal a complementary relationship between the two strategies. Interestingly, we find that introducing competitive fresh produce may increase the demand for original fresh produce when the freshness sensitivity is high. However, the platform may suffer from introduction with agency selling even at a high commission rate in some cases.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Subscribe and save

Springer+ Basic
$34.99 /Month
  • Get 10 units per month
  • Download Article/Chapter or eBook
  • 1 Unit = 1 Article or 1 Chapter
  • Cancel anytime
Subscribe now

Buy Now

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Available at https://new.qq.com/rain/a/20210426A0EXP400.

  2. Available at http://m.xinhuanet.com/yn/2018-11/24/c_137628042.htm.

  3. Available at https://www.ebrun.com/20201028/407765.shtml.

  4. Following Boyer and Hult [2], practitioners can conduct a questionnaire survey on consumers’ product freshness perception and purchase intention. Then, practitioners can establish a regression model based on the collected data to obtain the regression coefficient of product freshness on purchase intention, thereby obtaining the freshness sensitivity.

References

  1. Abhishek, V., Jerath, K., & Zhang, Z. J. (2016). Agency selling or reselling? Channel structures in electronic retailing. Management Science, 62(8), 2259–2280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Boyer, K. K., & Hult, G. T. M. (2006). Customer behavioral intentions for online purchases: An examination of fulfillment method and customer experience level. Journal of Operations Management, 24(2), 124–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Cai, X., Chen, J., & Xiao, Y. (2010). Optimization and coordination of fresh product supply chains with freshness-keeping effort. Production and Operations Management, 19(3), 261–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Cai, X., Chen, J., Xiao, Y., Xu, X., & Yu, Y. (2013). Fresh-product supply chain management with logistics outsourcing. Omega, 41(4), 752–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Cai, G., Dai, Y., & Zhou, S. X. (2012). Exclusive channels and revenue sharing in a complementary goods market. Marketing Science, 31(1), 172–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Chen, P., Zhao, R., Yan, Y., & Li, X. (2020). Promotional pricing and online business model choice in the presence of retail competition. Omega, 94, 102085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Guan, Z., Zhang, X., Zhou, M., & Dan, Y. (2020). Demand information sharing in competing supply chains with manufacturer-provided service. International Journal of Production Economics, 220, 107450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Ha, A. Y., Luo, H., & Shang, W. (2022). Supplier encroachment, information sharing and channel structure in Online Retail Platforms. Production and Operations Management, 31(3), 1235–1251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Ha, A. Y., Tian, Q., & Tong, S. (2017). Information sharing in competing supply chains with production cost reduction. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 19(2), 246–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Ha, A. Y., Tong, S., & Wang, Y. (2021). Channel structures of online retail platforms. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management. Advance online publication. https://doi.org/10.1287/msom.2021.1011.

  11. He, B., Gan, X., & Yuan, K. (2019). Entry of online presale of fresh produce: A competitive analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 272, 339–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Huang, S., Chen, S., & Guan, X. (2020). Retailer information sharing under endogenous channel structure with investment spillovers. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 142, 106346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Huang, S., Guan, X., & Chen, Y. J. (2018). Retailer information sharing with supplier encroachment. Production and Operations Management, 27(6), 1133–1147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. iResearch. (2021). Research report on China fresh e-commerce industry. https://www.iresearch.com.cn/Detail/report?id=3776&isfree=0

  15. Jain, A. (2021). Sharing demand information with retailer under upstream competition. Management Science. Advance online publication. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2021.4116

  16. Jain, A., Seshadri, S., & Sohoni, M. (2011). Differential pricing for information sharing under competition. Production and Operations Management, 20(2), 235–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Jiang, B., Tian, L., Xu, Y., & Zhang, F. (2016). To share or not to share: Demand forecast sharing in a distribution channel. Marketing Science, 35(5), 800–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Ke, H., Ye, S., & Mo, Y. (2021). A comparison between the wholesale model and the agency model with different launch strategies in the book supply chain. Electronic Commerce Research. Advance online publication. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-021-09474-z

  19. Li, L. (2002). Information sharing in a supply chain with horizontal competition. Management Science, 48(9), 1196–1212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Li, T., & Zhang, H. (2015). Information sharing in a supply chain with a make-to-stock manufacturer. Omega, 50, 115–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Li, X., & Ai, X. (2021). A choice of selling format in the online marketplace with cross-sales supply chain: Platform selling or traditional reselling? Electronic Commerce Research, 21, 393–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Lin, J., Li, T., & Guo, J. (2021). Factors influencing consumers’ continuous purchase intention on fresh food e-commerce platforms: An organic foods-centric empirical investigation. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 50, 101103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Liu, B., Cai, G., & Tsay, A. (2014). Advertising in asymmetric competing supply chains. Production and Operations Management, 23(11), 1845–1858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Liu, M., Dan, B., Zhang, S., & Ma, S. (2021). Information sharing in an e-tailing supply chain for fresh produce with freshness-keeping effort and value-added service. European Journal of Operational Research, 290(2), 572–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Liu, Y., Ma, D., Hu, J., & Zhang, Z. (2021). Sales mode selection of fresh food supply chain based on blockchain technology under different channel competition. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 162, 107730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Liu, Z., Zhang, D., & Zhang, F. (2021). Information sharing on retail platforms. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 23(3), 606–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Ma, X., Wang, S., Islam, S. M. N., & Liu, X. (2019). Coordinating a three-echelon fresh agricultural products supply chain considering freshness-keeping effort with asymmetric information. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 67, 337–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Roller, L. H., & Tombak, M. M. (1993). Competition and investment in flexible technologies. Management Science, 39(1), 107–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Singh, N., & Vives, X. (1984). Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly. The RAND Journal of Economics, 15(4), 546–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Shamir, N., & Shin, H. (2016). Public forecast information sharing in a market with competing supply chains. Management Science, 62(10), 2994–3022.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Shang, W., Ha, A. Y., & Tong, S. (2016). Information sharing in a supply chain with a common retailer. Management Science, 62(1), 245–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Statista. (2021). JD.com’s revenue share of self-operated business 2017–2020. https://www.statista.com/statistics/1011703/china-revenue-share-of-self-operated-business-of-jd/

  33. Tang, R., & Yang, L. (2020). Financing strategy in fresh product supply chains under e-commerce environment. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 39, 200911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Tsunoda, Y., & Zennyo, Y. (2021). Platform information transparency and effects on third-party suppliers and offline retailers. Production and Operations Management, 30(11), 4219–4235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Wang, J., & Zhuo, W. (2020). Strategic information sharing in a supply chain under potential supplier encroachment. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 150(3), 106880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Xu, C., Fan, T., Zheng, Q., & Song, Y. (2021). Contract selection for fresh produce suppliers cooperating with a platform under a markdown-pricing policy. International Journal of Production Research. https://doi.org/10.1080/00207543.2021.1987548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Yang, L., & Tang, R. (2019). Comparisons of sales modes for a fresh product supply chain with freshness-keeping effort. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 125, 425–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Yu, Y., Xiao, T., & Feng, Z. (2020). Price and cold-chain service decisions versus integration in a fresh agri-product supply chain with competing retailers. Annals of Operations Research, 287, 465–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Zhang, J., Qi, L., & Tong, S. (2021). Dynamic contract under quick response in a supply chain with information asymmetry. Production and Operations Management, 30(5), 1273–1289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Zhang, H. (2002). Vertical information exchange in a supply chain with duopoly retailers. Production and Operations Management, 11(4), 531–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Zhang, S., & Zhang, J. (2020). Agency selling or reselling: Platform information sharing with supplier offline entry. European Journal of Operational Research, 280, 134–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Zhang, X., & Hou, W. (2022). The impacts of e-tailer’s private label on the sales mode selection: From the perspectives of economic and environmental sustainability. European Journal of Operational Research, 296(2), 601–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Zheng, H., Li, G., Guan, X., Sethi, S., & Li, Yu. (2021). Downstream information sharing and sales channel selection in a platform economy. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 156, 102512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Zhong, B., Shen, H., Zhang, J., & Gao, X. (2022). Agency or wholesale? retail selling format in the presence of new manufacturer introduction. Electronic Commerce Research., 8, 9. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-022-09535-x

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This work was supported by the Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant number 72171029, 72101038], the Ministry of Education of Humanities and Social Science project [Grant number 21YJC630081], and the Graduate Scientific Research and Innovation Foundation of Chongqing, China [Grant number CYB20053].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bin Dan.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

No conflicts in our paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Assumption 1

\(0 < \eta < \overline{\eta }\), where \(\overline{\eta } = \min (\sqrt {\frac{4b + 4}{{(1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha }}} ,\sqrt {2 + 2b} )\).

In practice, the higher freshness sensitivity means consumers care much about the freshness of fresh produce purchased online. However, product freshness cannot continuously affect consumer demand, denoting an upper limit on the freshness sensitivity. Additionally, this assumption ensures that all the equilibriums and profits are positive.

Proof of Theorem 1

According to backward induction, the sales price of original fresh produce is solved first. We can know that the expected profit of the platform is concave with \(p_{1}\) due to it satisfies \(\frac{{\partial^{2} E\pi_{o} }}{{\partial p_{1}^{2} }} = - 2\). Let \(\frac{{\partial E\pi_{o} }}{{\partial p_{1} }} = 0\), so we can derive \(p_{1}^{U * } (w_{1} ,\tau ) = \frac{{E(a|Y) + w_{1} - \eta (1 - \tau )}}{2}\). If the platform shares information (does not share)with the supplier, the supplier can use \(p_{1}^{U * } (w,\tau ) = \frac{{E(a|Y) + w_{1} - \eta (1 - \tau )}}{2}\) (\(p_{1}^{U * } (w_{1} ,\tau ) = \frac{{\overline{a} + w_{1} - \eta (1 - \tau )}}{2}\)) to decide the wholesale price \(w_{1}\) and freshness-keeping effort \(\tau\).

Next, we first verify that the expected profit of the supplier is concave with \(w_{1}\) and \(\tau\). The Hessian matrix of \(E\pi_{s}^{U}\) is

$$H\left( {w_{1} ,\tau } \right) = \left( \begin{gathered} \frac{{\partial^{2} E\pi_{s} }}{{\partial w_{1}^{2} }} \, \frac{{\partial^{2} E\pi_{s} }}{{\partial w_{1} \partial \tau }} \, \hfill \\ \frac{{\partial^{2} E\pi_{s} }}{{\partial \tau \partial w_{1} }} \, \frac{{\partial^{2} E\pi_{s} }}{{\partial \tau^{2} }} \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \right) = \left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} { - 1} & {\frac{\eta }{2}} \\ {\frac{\eta }{2}} & { - 1} \\ \end{array} } \right)$$

where \(H_{1} = - 1 < 0\), \(H_{2} = 1 - \eta^{2} /4\). To ensure the Hessian matrix is negative, it should satisfy that \(H_{2} > 0\), namely, \(\eta < 2\). Under this condition, let \(\frac{{\partial E\pi_{s} }}{\partial \tau } = 0\) and \(\frac{{\partial E\pi_{s} }}{{\partial w_{1} }} = 0\), we can derive the equilibrium wholesale price \(w_{1}^{U * }\) and freshness-keeping effort \(\tau^{U * }\). Take the expression of \(w_{1}^{U * }\) and \(\tau^{U * }\) into the function \(p_{1}^{U * } (w_{1} ,\tau ) = \frac{{E(a|Y) + w_{1} - \eta (1 - \tau )}}{2}\), we can derive the equilibrium sales price \(p_{1}^{U * }\).

Finally, take the expressions of \(w_{1}^{U * }\), \(\tau^{U * }\) and \(p_{1}^{U * }\) into the expected profit functions of the supplier and the platform under no introduction, we can derive the expected profits of the supplier and the platform, as shown in the following.

\(E\pi_{s}^{UI * } = \frac{{(\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} }}{{16 - 4{\mkern 1mu} \eta^{2} }}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{UN * } = \frac{{(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2} }}{{8 - 2\eta^{2} }}\),

\(E\pi_{o}^{UI * } = \frac{{(\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} }}{{2(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }}\), \(E\pi_{o}^{UN * } = \frac{{(4\hat{H} - 2\overline{a} - 2\eta - \eta^{2} (\hat{H} - \overline{a}))^{2} }}{{8(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }} + \frac{{(4\hat{L} - 2\overline{a} - 2\eta - \eta^{2} (\hat{L} - \overline{a}))^{2} }}{{8(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }}\).

Proof of Proposition 1

From Theorem 1, we can derive that: \(E\pi_{o}^{UI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } = \frac{{(6 - \eta^{2} )(\eta^{2} - 2)(2\rho - 1)^{2} (H - L)^{2} }}{{16(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }}\). Thus we can derive that \(sign(E\pi_{o}^{UI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } ) = sign(\eta^{2} - 2)\). If \(\eta < \sqrt 2\), \(\eta^{2} - 2 < 0\), we have \(E\pi_{o}^{UI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } < 0\); if \(\eta > \sqrt 2\), \(\eta^{2} - 2 > 0\), we have \(E\pi_{o}^{UI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } > 0\).

Proof of Proposition 2

This proof is similar to that of Theorem 1.

We can derive the expected profits of the supplier and the platform, as shown in the follows.

\(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } = \frac{{((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{4(4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )}} - C\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } = \frac{{((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2} }}{{2(4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )}} - C\).

\(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } = \frac{{(b + 1)((4\alpha - 1)b + 4\alpha + 1)((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{(4b + 4 - M_{1} \eta^{2} )^{2} }}\),

\(E\pi_{o}^{AN * } = \frac{{((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )^{2} (1 - b)(\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} \eta^{4} - 8M_{3} (1 + b)\eta^{2} - 32\overline{a}\eta ((4\alpha - 1)b + 4\alpha + 1)(1 + b)^{2} - 4M_{4} (1 + b)^{2} }}{{16(1 + b)(4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} }}\),where \(M_{3} = ((2\alpha - 1)b^{2} - 2b - 2\alpha + 3)(\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} - 8\alpha b^{2} - 8\alpha b - 8\alpha - 2\) and \(M_{4} = ((4\alpha - 5)(\hat{H}^{2} + \hat{L}^{2} ) + (8\alpha + 6)\hat{H}\hat{L})b + (4\alpha + 5)(\hat{H}^{2} + \hat{L}^{2} ) + (8\alpha - 6)\hat{H}\hat{L}\).

Proof of Proposition 2

This proof is similar to that of Proposition 1.

Proof of Theorem 3

This proof is similar to that of Theorem 1.

We can obtain the expected profits of the supplier and the platform, as shown in the following.

\(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } = \frac{{((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{4(2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )}} - C\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } = \frac{{(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2} }}{{2(2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )}} - C\)

$$E\pi_{o}^{RI * } = \frac{{(1 - b^{2} )((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{4(1 - b)(2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }}$$
$$E\pi_{o}^{RN * } = \frac{{(\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} \eta^{4} - 4(((\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} - 1) - b)(1 + b)\eta^{2} - 8\overline{a}(1 + b)^{2} \eta + (1 + b)^{2} (5\hat{H}^{2} + 5\hat{L}^{2} - 6\hat{H}\hat{L})}}{{8(1 + b)(2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )^{2} }}$$

Proof of Proposition 3

This proof is similar to that of Proposition 1.

Proof of Proposition 4

According to Corollary 3, we know that there are four regions where the information sharing strategy of the platform are differentiated. Thus, we can discuss the supplier’s preference for the introduction strategy combined with these four regions, which are shown as follows.

  1. (1)

    When \(\alpha < 3/4\), \(b < b_{1}\) and \(\eta < \eta_{1}\).

The platform will not share information under all three introduction strategies. Thus, we can get the supplier’s preference by comparing his profits under AN, RN and UN strategies.

First, we can find that \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } - E\pi_{s}^{RN * } = \frac{{(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2} (1/2 - \alpha )(1 + b)^{2} }}{{(2 + 2b - \eta^{2} )(4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )}}\). Thus, we can derive that \(sign(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } - E\pi_{s}^{RN * } ) = sign(1/2 - \alpha )\). If \(\alpha < 1/2\), we have \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } > E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\); if \(\alpha > 1/2\), we have \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } < E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\).

Next, we compare the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\) if \(\alpha < 1/2\), and the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\) if \(\alpha > 1/2\). By comparing \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\), we can find that \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * } = \frac{f(C)}{{(\eta^{2} - 4)(4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )}}\), where \(f(C) = kC + m\), \(k = (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )(4 - \eta^{2} )\), \(m = 4(\alpha b + \alpha - 1)(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2}\). Thus, we can know that \(sign(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * } ) = sign( - f(C))\). It is easy to verify that \(k > 0\) and \(m < 0\) when \(\alpha < 1/2\). Thus, we can know that there exists \(C_{1} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{{{\mkern 1mu} 4(1 - \alpha - \alpha {\mkern 1mu} b){\mkern 1mu} (\overline{a} - \eta )^{2} }}{{(4 - \eta^{2} )(4{\mkern 1mu} b + 4 - M_{1} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{1}\), \(f(C) < 0\), and \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{1}\), \(f(C) > 0\), and \(E\pi_{s}^{AN * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\). Furthermore, we can derive that \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * } = \frac{f(C)}{{(\eta^{2} - 4)(2 + 2b - \eta^{2} )}}\), where \(f(C) = kC + m\), \(k = (2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )(4 - \eta^{2} )\), \(m = (b - 1)(\overline{a} - \eta )^{2}\). Thus, we can know that \(sign(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * } ) = sign( - f(C))\). It is easy to verify that \(k > 0\) and \(m < 0\). Thus, we can know that there exists \(C_{4} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{{(1 - b)({\mkern 1mu} {\mkern 1mu} \overline{a} - {\mkern 1mu} \eta )^{2} }}{{(4 - \eta^{2} )(2b + 2 - {\mkern 1mu} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{4}\), \(f(C) < 0\), and \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{4}\), \(f(C) > 0\), and \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\).

  1. (2)

    When \(\max (0,\eta_{1} ) < \eta < \eta_{2}\).

The platform will share information under the strategy of introduction with agency selling, and not share information under the other two introduction strategies. Thus, we can get the supplier’s preference by comparing his profits under AI, RN and UN strategies. The detailed proof process is similar to that of Part (1).

First, we compare \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\), we can derive that there exists \(\rho_{3} { = }\frac{1}{2}{ + }\sqrt {\frac{{(2\alpha - 1)(2(1 + b)(H + L) - 4(1 + b)\eta )^{2} }}{{2(H - L)^{2} (2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )(3 + b - 2b\alpha - 2\alpha )}}} > 1/2\), if \(\rho < \min (\rho_{3} ,1)\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } < E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\); if \(\rho > \rho_{3}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } > E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\).

Next, we compare \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\), we can know that there exists \(C_{2} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{\begin{gathered} {\mkern 1mu} [4(4\alpha + 4\alpha b - b - 5)\hat{H}^{2} + 4\hat{L}^{2} (4\alpha + 4\alpha b - b - 5) - 64\overline{a}\eta (\alpha b + \alpha - 1) \hfill \\ + 8\hat{H}\hat{L}(1 + b) - 2(((\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} - 16)(1 + b)\alpha + 32 - {\mkern 1mu} (b + 3)(\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} )\eta^{2} ] \hfill \\ \end{gathered} }{{8(\eta^{2} - 4)(4{\mkern 1mu} b + 4 - M_{1} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{2}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{2}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\). Furthermore, we compare \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\), we can know that there exists \(C_{4} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{{(1 - b)({\mkern 1mu} {\mkern 1mu} \overline{a} - {\mkern 1mu} \eta )^{2} }}{{(4 - \eta^{2} )(2b + 2 - {\mkern 1mu} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{4}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{4}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RN * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\).

  1. (3)

    When \(\eta_{2} < \eta < \sqrt 2\), we have that:

The platform will share information under the strategies of introduction with agency selling and reselling, and not share information under no introduction. Thus, we can derive the supplier’s preference by comparing his profits under AI, RI and UN strategies. The detailed proof process is also similar to that of Part (1).

First, we compare \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * }\), we can get that: if \(\alpha < 1/2\), we have \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } > E\pi_{s}^{RI * }\); if \(\alpha > 1/2\), we have \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } < E\pi_{s}^{RI * }\). Next, we compare the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\) if \(\alpha < 1/2\), and the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\) if \(\alpha > 1/2\). By comparing \(E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * }\), we can derive that there exisits \(C_{5} = \frac{{{\mkern 1mu} 6\hat{H}^{2} - 4{\mkern 1mu} \hat{H}\hat{L} + 6{\mkern 1mu} \hat{L}^{2} - ((\hat{H} - \hat{L})^{2} + 8{\mkern 1mu} b - 8)\eta^{2} - 16{\mkern 1mu} (1 - b)\overline{a}\eta - 8\overline{a}^{2} b}}{{8(4 - \eta^{2} )(2b + 2 - {\mkern 1mu} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{5}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{5}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\).

  1. (4)

    When \(\eta > \sqrt 2\), we have that:

The platform will share information under all three introduction strategies. Thus, we can get the supplier’s preference by comparing his profits under AI, RI and UI strategies. The detailed proof process is also similar to that of Part (1).

First, we compare the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } - E\pi_{s}^{UI * }\) if \(\alpha < 1/2\), and the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } - E\pi_{s}^{UI * }\) if \(\alpha > 1/2\). By comparing \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * }\) and \(E\pi_{s}^{UI * }\), we can know that there exists \(C_{3} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{{{\mkern 1mu} 2(\alpha {\mkern 1mu} b + \alpha - 1){\mkern 1mu} ((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{(\eta^{2} - 4)(4{\mkern 1mu} b + 4 - M_{1} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{3}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } > E\pi_{s}^{UI * }\); when \(C > C_{3}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{AI * } < E\pi_{s}^{UI * }\). Furthermore, we compare the value of \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } - E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\). We can know that there exists \(C_{6} = {\mkern 1mu} \frac{{{\mkern 1mu} (1 - b)((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{2(4 - \eta^{2} )(2b + 2 - {\mkern 1mu} \eta^{2} )}}\), when \(C < C_{6}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } > E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\); when \(C > C_{6}\), \(E\pi_{s}^{RI * } < E\pi_{s}^{UN * }\).

Based on the above analysis, we can derive Proposition 4.

where \(\rho_{3} { = }\frac{1}{2}{ + }\sqrt {\frac{{(2\alpha - 1)(2(1 + b)(H + L) - 4(1 + b)\eta )^{2} }}{{2(H - L)^{2} (2b + 2 - \eta^{2} )(3 + b - 2b\alpha - 2\alpha )}}}\), \(C_{j1} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {C_{1} } & {\eta < \eta_{1} } \\ {C_{2} } & {\eta_{1} < \eta < \sqrt 2 } \\ {C_{3} } & {\sqrt 2 < \eta < \overline{\eta }} \\ \end{array} } \right.\), and \(C_{j2} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {C_{4} } & {\eta < \eta_{2} } \\ {C_{5} } & {\eta_{2} < \eta < \sqrt 2 } \\ {C_{6} } & {\sqrt 2 < \eta < \overline{\eta }} \\ \end{array} } \right.\),

Proof of Proposition 5

  1. (1)

    The impact of the strategy of introduction with agency selling on the platform.

    1. (i)

      When \(\alpha < 3/4\), \(b < b_{1}\), and \(\eta < \eta_{1}\), we compare the platform’s profit under the AN and UN strategies.

      \(E\pi_{o}^{AN * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } = \frac{{f(\rho )_{1} }}{{8(1 + b)(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} }}\), where \(f(\rho )_{1} = A_{1} \rho^{2} + B_{1} \rho + E_{1}\) is a quadratic equation of \(\rho\), \(A_{1} = - 4b(H - L)^{2} (4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} < 0\), \(B_{1} = - A_{1} > 0\), and \(\Delta = B_{1}^{2} - 4A_{1} E_{1} = 16(1 + b)A_{1} f(\eta )_{1} (H + L - 2\eta )^{2}\), and \(f(\eta )_{1} = ((2{\mkern 1mu} \alpha^{2} - 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha + 1)b^{2} + (4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha^{2} - 12{\mkern 1mu} \alpha + 3)b + 2{\mkern 1mu} \alpha^{2} - 8{\mkern 1mu} \alpha + 4)\eta^{4} + 8(1 + b)^{2} \left( {3\alpha - 1} \right)\eta^{2} - 16(1 + b){\mkern 1mu} (2\alpha b - b + 2\alpha )\). It is easy to verify that \(sign(E\pi_{o}^{AN * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } ) = sign(f(\rho )_{1} )\). Let the unique solution of \(f(\rho )_{1} = 0\) equals \(\rho_{4} = \frac{1}{2} + \sqrt {\frac{{4(1 + b)(H + L - 2\eta )^{2} f(\eta )_{1} }}{{b(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (H - L)^{2} (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} }}}\), we have that: if \(\rho < \min (\rho_{4} ,1) = \overline{\rho }_{4}\), \(f(\rho )_{1} > 0\), \(E\pi_{o}^{AN * } > E\pi_{o}^{UN * }\); if \(\rho > \rho_{4}\), \(E\pi_{o}^{AN * } < E\pi_{o}^{UN * }\).

    2. (ii)

      When \(\max (0,\eta_{1} ) < \eta < \sqrt 2\), we compare the platform’s profit under the AI and UN strategies.

      \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } = \frac{{f(\rho )_{2} }}{{16(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} }}\), where \(f(\rho )_{2} = A_{2} \rho^{2} + B_{2} \rho + E_{2}\) is a quadratic equation of \(\rho\), \(A_{2} = - 4(H - L)^{2} (4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} f(\eta )_{2}\), \(B_{2} = - A_{2}\), and \(\Delta_{2} = B_{2}^{2} - 4A_{2} E_{2} = 32A_{2} f(\eta )_{1} (H + L - 2\eta )^{2}\), and \(f(\eta )_{2} = ((2\alpha - 1)b + 2\alpha - 3)^{2} \eta^{4} + 4(2(2\alpha - 1)b^{2} + 8(\alpha - 1)b + 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha - 6)\eta^{2} + 4(5 - 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha )b^{2} + 32(1 - \alpha )b - 16\alpha + 12\). It is easy to verify that \(sign(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UN * } ) = sign(f(\rho )_{2} )\). Let the unique solution of \(f(\rho )_{2} = 0\) equals \(\rho_{5} = \frac{1}{2} + \sqrt {\frac{{8(H + L - 2\eta )^{2} f(\eta )_{1} }}{{(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (H - L)^{2} f(\eta )_{2} }}}\), we have that: if \(\rho < \min (\rho_{5} ,1) = \overline{\rho }_{5}\), \(f(\rho )_{2} > 0\), \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } > E\pi_{o}^{UN * }\); if \(\rho > \rho_{5}\), \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } < E\pi_{o}^{UN * }\).

    3. (iii)

      When \(\eta > \sqrt 2\), we compare the platform’s profit under the AI and UI strategies.

      \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UI * } = \frac{{ - f(\eta )_{1} ((\hat{H} - \eta )^{2} + (\hat{L} - \eta )^{2} )}}{{(4 - \eta^{2} )^{2} (4b + 4 - ((1 - 2\alpha )b + 3 - 2\alpha )\eta^{2} )^{2} }}\). It is easy to verify that \(sign(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } - E\pi_{o}^{UI * } ) = sign( - f(\eta )_{1} )\). Let the unique solution of \(f(\eta )_{1} = 0\) equal \(\eta_{5}\) when \(\eta > \sqrt 2\), we can derive that: if \(\alpha > 1/2\) and \(b > b_{5}\), it satisfies that \(\eta_{5} < \overline{\eta }\). Therefore, we can find that when \(\sqrt 2 < \eta < \min (\eta_{5} ,\overline{\eta })\), it satisfies \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } > E\pi_{o}^{UI * }\); when \(\alpha > 1/2\), \(b > b_{5}\), and \(\eta_{5} < \eta < \overline{\eta }\), it satisfies \(E\pi_{o}^{AI * } < E\pi_{o}^{UI * }\), where \(b_{5}\) is the unique solution of the equation \(f(b) = (2\alpha^{2} - 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha + 1)b^{3} + 2(3{\mkern 1mu} \alpha^{2} - 2{\mkern 1mu} \alpha )b^{2} + (6\alpha^{2} - 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha + 3)b + 2\alpha^{2} - 4\alpha = 0\) and \(\eta_{5} = \sqrt {\frac{{4{\mkern 1mu} b^{2} - 12{\mkern 1mu} (1 + b)^{2} \alpha + 8{\mkern 1mu} b + 4 + 4{\mkern 1mu} \sqrt {(\alpha {\mkern 1mu} b + \alpha - 1)^{2} (1 + b)(4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha {\mkern 1mu} b + 4{\mkern 1mu} \alpha - b + 1)} }}{{2{\mkern 1mu} (1 + b)^{2} \alpha^{2} - 4(b^{2} + 3{\mkern 1mu} b + 2)\alpha + b^{2} + 3{\mkern 1mu} b + 4}}}\).

Combining (i)(ii)(iii), we can derive Proposition 5(1).

where \(\tilde{\rho } = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\overline{\rho }_{4} } & {\alpha < 3/4,b < b_{1} ,\eta < \eta_{1} } \\ {\overline{\rho }_{5} } & {\max (\eta_{1} ,0) < \eta < \sqrt 2 } \\ \end{array} } \right.\), \(\underset{\raise0.3em\hbox{$\smash{\scriptscriptstyle\thicksim}$}}{\rho } = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\rho_{4} } & {\alpha < 3/4,b < b_{1} ,\eta < \eta_{1} } \\ {\rho_{5} } & {\max (\eta_{1} ,0) < \eta < \sqrt 2 } \\ \end{array} } \right.\).

  1. (2)

    The impact of the strategy of introduction with reselling on the platform.

When \(\eta < \eta_{2}\), we compare the platform’s profit under the RN and UN strategies. When \(\eta_{2} < \eta < \sqrt 2\), we compare the platform’s profit under the RI and UN strategies. When \(\eta > \sqrt 2\), we compare the platform’s profit under the RI and UI strategies. It is easy to verify that \(E\pi_{o}^{R * } > E\pi_{o}^{U * }\) in these regions, so we have omitted the detailed proof process.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tian, Y., Dan, B., Liu, M. et al. Strategic introduction for competitive fresh produce in an e-commerce platform with demand information sharing. Electron Commer Res 23, 2907–2941 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-022-09598-w

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-022-09598-w

Keywords