Abstract
We consider an agency problem where a firm (she) hires a manager (he) who has related managerial expertise to implement a new project. The manager’s managerial expertise is his private information and characterized as an uncertain variable. The revenue brought about by the project in the future is also assumed to be uncertain. In light of these challenges, this paper investigates the impacts of the manager’s risk attitude and the type-and-effort dependent outside option on the optimal compensation contracts under different information structures. Through developing the manager’s decision criterion based on his risk attitude instead of the expected-utility-maximization criterion, we find that, if the manager is conservative and the outside option’s revenue uncertainty is sufficiently high, the optimal commission rate will be distorted upwards under asymmetric managerial expertise information compared with that under symmetric managerial expertise information. Our analysis also confirms that the existence of a type-and-effort dependent outside option distorts up the compensation structure tailored at a fixed outside option. We further show that, comparing with the setting of a fixed outside option when the manager is aggressive, the presence of a type-and-effort dependent outside option results in a surprising phenomenon that the manager’s private information makes no distortion of the firm’s profit.




Similar content being viewed by others
Explore related subjects
Discover the latest articles, news and stories from top researchers in related subjects.References
Bergmann, R., & Friedl, G. (2008). Controlling innovative projects with moral hazard and asymmetric information. Research Policy, 37(9), 1504–1514.
Chao, R. O., Lichtendahl, K. C., & Grushka-Cockayne, Y. (2014). Incentives in a stage-gate process. Production and Operations Management, 23(8), 1286–1298.
Chen, Y. J. (2013). Risk-incentives trade-off and outside options. OR Spectrum, 35(4), 937–956.
Dutta, S. (2003). Capital budgeting and managerial compensation: Incentive and retention effects. The Accounting Review, 78(1), 71–93.
Dutta, S. (2008). Managerial expertise, private information, and pay-performance sensitivity. Management Science, 54(3), 429–442.
Ellsberg, D. (1961). Risk, ambiguity, and the savage axioms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75(4), 643–669.
Gao, J., Yang, X., & Liu, D. (2016). Uncertain shapley value of coalitional game with application to supply chain alliance. Applied Soft Computing. doi:10.1016/j.asoc.2016.06.018.
Goldmanis, M., & Ray, K. (2014). Sorting effects of performance pay. Management Science, 61(2), 335–353.
He, Z., Li, S., Wei, B., & Yu, J. (2013). Uncertainty, risk, and incentives: Theory and evidence. Management Science, 60(1), 206–226.
Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.
Huang, K. W. (2010). A parametric curve analysis for the risk-return tradeoff in an agency problem. Working paper, National University of Singapore.
Lan, Y., Zhao, R., & Tang, W. (2014). A fuzzy supply chain contract problem with pricing and warranty. Journal of Intelligent & Fuzzy Systems, 26(3), 1527–1538.
Liu, B. (2007). Uncertainty theory (2nd ed.). Berlin: Springer.
Liu, B. (2009). Some research problems in uncertainty theory. Journal of Uncertain Systems, 3(2), 83–94.
Liu, B. (2013). Extreme value theorems of uncertain process with application to insurance risk model. Soft Computing, 17(4), 549–556.
Liu, Y., & Ha, M. (2010). Expected value of function of uncertain variables. Journal of Uncertain Systems, 4(3), 181–186.
Liu, Y., Chen, X., & Ralescu, D. A. (2015). Uncertain currency model and currency option pricing. International Journal of Intelligent Systems, 30(1), 40–51.
Manso, G. (2011). Motivating innovation. The Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1823–1860.
Mihm, J. (2010). Incentives in new product development projects and the role of target costing. Management Science, 56(8), 1324–1344.
Mu, R., Lan, Y., & Tang, W. (2013). An uncertain contract model for rural migrant workers employment problems. Fuzzy Optimization and Decision Making, 12(1), 29–39.
Prendergast, C. (2002). The tenuous trade-off between risk and incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), 1071–1102.
Wu, X., Zhao, R., & Tang, W. (2014). Uncertain agency models with multi-dimensional incomplete information based on confidence level. Fuzzy Optimization and Decision Making, 13(2), 231–258.
Xiao, W., & Xu, Y. (2012). The impact of royalty contract revision in a multistage strategic R&D alliance. Management Science, 58(12), 2251–2271.
Yang, K., Zhao, R., & Lan, Y. (2014). The impact of risk attitude in new product development under dual information asymmetry. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 76(10), 122–137.
Yang, K., Zhao, R., & Lan, Y. (2016). Impacts of uncertain project duration and asymmetric risk sensitivity information in project management. International Transactions in Operational Research, 23(4), 749–774.
Acknowledgements
This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grant Nos. 71271151, 71301114 and 71471126, and the Specialized Research Fund for the Doctoral Program of Higher Education of China under Grant No. 20130032110015.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix: Proofs
Appendix: Proofs
Proof of Proposition 1
Based on the expected value criterion, the firm’s expected profit
Based on the critical value criterion, if the manager accepts the contract, his \(\alpha \)-utility
If the manager refuses the contract and opts for the outside option, his \(\alpha \)-utility
where the manager always maximizes his profit by exerting an effort
Because the firm’s expected profit is deceasing in the fixed payment \(w_0\), at optimality, the individual rationality constraint should be binding, i.e., \(\pi _1(\theta ,\theta )=\pi _2(\theta )\). Thus,
Substituting the fixed payment into the firm’s objective function, we obtain
which is concave in \(e_{1}\). Thus, we yield the manager’s optimal effort level \(e_1^{SO}=1\) for the firm’s project by using the first-order condition \(\partial \pi _F^{SO}/\partial e_{1}=0\). By substituting this optimal effort level into the firm’s simplified problem above, we simplify the firm’s problem to
Because the objective function is piecewise linear in \(w_1(\theta )\), we focus on the corner point solutions \(w_1(\theta )\in \{0,1\}\). To ensure the firm can get a positive and maximum profit, if \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\) and \(a_1>a_2\), the optimal incentive compensation rate is \(w_1^{SO}(\theta )=1\); if \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\) and \(a_1,a_2>0\), the optimal incentive compensation rate is \(w_1^{SO}(\theta )=0\). Following the determinate optimal incentive commission rate \(w_1^{SO}\), the corresponding optimal fixed payment \(w_0^{SO}\) for the manager can be derived immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 2
If the manager accepts the contract, the manager will choose his own effort \(e_1^{SU}\) to maximize his \(\alpha \)-profit
which is concave in \(\hat{e}_1\). The maximum is completely characterized by the first-order condition \(e_1^{SU}=w_1(\theta )\). Furthermore, because the firm’s profit is deceasing in the fixed payment \(w_0(\theta )\), at optimality, the incentive compatibility constraint should be binding, i.e., \(\pi _1=\pi _2\). By substituting \(e_1^{SU}\) and \(e_{2}\) into the incentive compatibility constraint, we can rewrite the incentive compatibility constraint as
After substituting the fixed payment \(w_0\) and \(e_1^{SU}\) into the objective function, the firm’s problem can be rewritten as
There are two cases: (i) \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\) and (ii) \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\). To ensure the firm can get a positive and maximum profit, for case (i), we can obtain \(w_1^{SU}=1\) and \(a_1>a_2\). For case (ii), by the first-order condition, we can obtain \(w_1^{SU}=1+(1-2\alpha )a_1\) and \(a_{11}<a_{2}\) where \(a_{11}=a_{1}-(\alpha -\frac{1}{2}a_{1}^{2})\).
Following the determinate optimal incentive commission rate \(w_1^{SU}\), the optimal fixed payment \(w_0^{SU}\) and the optimal effort level \(e_{1}^{SU}\) for the manager can be obtained immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Before giving the Proof of Proposition 3, we first simplify the expressions of both the incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection and individual rationality constraint in Case AO. Define \(\Psi (\theta ,\theta )=\pi _1(\theta ,\theta )-\pi _2(\theta )\).
Lemma 1
A compensation contract satisfies the incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection and individual rationality constraint if and only if
-
(i)
\(\displaystyle \frac{\mathrm {d} w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }+(\theta +e+(1-2\alpha )a_1)\frac{\mathrm {d}w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d}\theta }=0,\quad \forall \theta \in [\underline{\theta },\overline{\theta }];\)
-
(ii)
\(\displaystyle \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }\geqslant 0,\quad \forall \theta \in [\underline{\theta },\overline{\theta }];\)
-
(iii)
\(\displaystyle \Psi \left( \overline{\theta },\overline{\theta }\right) =0\).
Proof of Lemma 1
the incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection can be written as
which means that \(\pi _1(\theta ,{\hat{\theta }})\) obtains its maximal value at \(\pi _1(\theta ,\theta )\), i.e., the manager can obtain his maximal profit \(\pi _1(\theta ,{\hat{\theta }})\) if and only if \(\hat{\theta }=\theta \). In other words, the manager with managerial expertise \(\theta \) has no incentive to pretend to be a that with idea value \({\hat{\theta }}\). Thus, \(\pi _1(\theta ,{\hat{\theta }})\) satisfies the first-order condition (i.e., local incentive compatibility constraint) \(\frac{\partial \pi _1(\theta ,{\hat{\theta }})}{\partial {\hat{\theta }}}\bigm |_{{\hat{\theta }}=\theta }=0\) and the second-order condition \(\frac{\partial ^{2} \pi _1(\theta ,{\hat{\theta }})}{\partial {\hat{\theta }}{2}}\bigm |_{{\hat{\theta }}=\theta }\leqslant 0\). The local incentive compatibility constraint
If we further differentiate the local incentive compatibility constraint with respect to \(\theta \), we can obtain
By the second-order condition, we derive
On the basis of (2) and (3), we gain the monotonicity condition
Suppose, next, that both the local incentive compatibility and monotonicity conditions hold. Then it must be the case that all the manager’s incentive compatibility conditions hold. To see this result, without loss of generality, suppose that \(\hat{\theta }>{\theta }\). by integrating the local incentive compatibility condition (1) and using the monotonicity condition (4), we can obtain
Simplifying inequality above yields
That is to say
On the other hand, if \(\hat{\theta }<{\theta }\), by integrating the local incentive compatibility condition (1) and using the monotonicity condition (4), we can also obtain
Simplifying inequality above yields
That is to say
This result establishes the equivalence between the monotonicity condition together with the local incentive compatibility condition and the full set of the manager’s incentive constraints.
For part (iii),
Differentiating \(\Psi \) with respect to \(\theta \) yields
The individual rationality constraint is equivalent to
The constraint is binding under the optimal mechanism because the firm will reap the redundant profit, so that \(\Psi (\overline{\theta },\overline{\theta })=0\).\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 3
Because
and
we can derive
Combining the definition of \(\pi _1(\theta ,\theta )\) yields
By substituting the fixed wage into the objective function, we can derive
We can use the first-order condition \(\partial \pi _F^{AO}/ \partial e_{1}=0\) to yields the first-best effort level. As a result, \(e_{1}^{AO}=1\). Substitute it into the objective function and ignore the monotonicity constraint in Lemma 1. The firm’s problem can be rewritten as
Because the objective function is piecewise linear in \(w_1(\theta )\), we focus on the corner point solutions \(w_1(\theta )\in \{0,1\}\). To ensure the firm can get a positive and maximum profit, if \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\) and \(a_1>a_2\), the optimal incentive compensation rate is \(w_1^{SO}(\theta )=1\); if \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\) and \(a_{12}<a_2\), there are two cases: (i) \(\underline{\theta }\leqslant \theta <\theta _1\) and (ii) \(\theta _1\leqslant \theta \leqslant \overline{\theta }\). For case (i), we can obtain \(w_1^{AO}(\theta )=0\). For case (ii), we can obtain \(w_1^{AO}(\theta )=1\). Following the determinate optimal incentive commission rate \(w_1^{SO}\), the corresponding optimal fixed payment \(w_0^{SO}\) for the manager can be obtained immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Before giving the Proof of Proposition 4, we first simplify the expressions of both the incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection and individual rationality constraint in Case AU.
Lemma 2
A compensation contract satisfies the incentive compatibility constraint for adverse selection and individual rationality constraint if and only if
-
(i)
\(\displaystyle \frac{\mathrm {d} w_0(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }+(\theta +(1-2\alpha )a_1)\frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }+w_1(\theta )\frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }=0,\quad \forall \theta \in [\underline{\theta },\overline{\theta }];\)
-
(ii)
\(\displaystyle \frac{\mathrm {d} w_1(\theta )}{\mathrm {d} \theta }\geqslant 0,\quad \forall \theta \in [\underline{\theta },\overline{\theta }];\)
-
(iii)
\(\displaystyle \Psi \left( \overline{\theta },\overline{\theta }\right) =0\).
Proof of Lemma 2
For parts (i) and (ii), if the manager’s true managerial expertise is \(\theta \) but he selects the contract \((w_0({\hat{\theta }}),w_1({\hat{\theta }}))\), his \(\alpha \)-profit
By the first-order condition, the manager maximizes his profit by exerting an effort
His profit under this optimal effort
Similarly, if the manager selects the contract \((w_0(\theta ),w_1(\theta ))\) based on his true managerial expertise \(\theta \), his profit
The rest of the proof is similar to the Proof of Lemma 1. Therefore, the proof of the lemma is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 4
Through the similar method used in the Proof of Proposition 3, the firm’s problem can be rewritten as
The first-order variation and the second-order variation of the firm’s expected profit are derived as
and
If \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\), it exists a unique optimal solution \(w_1^{AU}(\theta )=1\). To ensure the firm has a positive profit, \(a_1\) and \(a_2\) must satisfy \(a_{1}>a_2\).
On the other hand, if \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\), there are two cases: (i) \(\underline{\theta }\leqslant \theta <\theta _1\) and (ii) \(\theta _1\leqslant \theta \leqslant \overline{\theta }\). For case (i), we can obtain \(w_1^{AU}(\theta )=1+(1-2\alpha )a_1+h(\theta )\). For case (ii), we can obtain \(w_1^{AU}(\theta )=1\). To ensure the firm has a positive profit, \(a_1\) and \(a_2\) must satisfy \(a_{13}<a_2\), where \(a_{13}=a_1-\frac{1}{2(2\alpha -1)}\int ^{\theta _1}_{\underline{\theta }}[(1-2\alpha )a_1+h(\theta )]^2f(\theta )\mathrm {d}\theta \). Following the determinate optimal incentive commission rate \(w_1^{AU}\), the corresponding optimal fixed payment \(w_0^{AU}\) and the optimal effort level \(e^{AU}_1\) can be obtained immediately. The proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 5
If \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\), \(\mathrm {IV_1}=0\). If \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\), \(\mathrm{{IV_1}}=(2\alpha -1)(1-F(\theta _1))a_1+\int ^{\theta _1}_{\underline{\theta }}{F(\theta )}\mathrm {d}\theta \geqslant 0.\) Differentiating \(\mathrm {IV_1}\) with respect to \(\alpha \) yields
where the inequality follows from the fact that \(a_1\geqslant 0\). Therefore, the proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 6
Similar to the Proof of Proposition 5. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 7
Similar to the Proof of Proposition 5. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 8
Similar to the Proof of Proposition 5. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 9
If \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\), \(\mathrm {IV_1=IV_2=EV_1=EV_2=0}\). If \( \alpha >\frac{1}{2}\), \(\mathrm {IV_1}-\mathrm {IV_ 2}= [1-F(\theta )][1-(1-(2\alpha -1)a_1)^2]+\int _{\underline{\theta }}^{\theta _1}F(\theta )[1-(2\alpha -1)a_1]\mathrm {d}\theta +\frac{1}{2}\int _{\underline{\theta }}^{\theta _1}h(\theta )^2 f(\theta )\mathrm {d}\theta \geqslant 0\) and \(\mathrm {EV_1}-\mathrm {EV_2}\geqslant \frac{1}{2}-\frac{1}{2}[(1-(2\alpha -1)a_1)^2]+\frac{1}{2}\int _{\underline{\theta }}^{\theta _1}(1+h(\theta )^2)f(\theta )\mathrm {d}\theta \geqslant 0\). Furthermore, \(\mathrm {EV_2}-\mathrm {IV_1}\geqslant (2\alpha -1)a_1\left[ 1-\frac{1}{2}(2\alpha -1)a_1F(\theta )\right] \geqslant 0\), so that \(\mathrm {EV_1}\geqslant \mathrm {EV_2} \geqslant \mathrm {IV_1} \geqslant \mathrm {IV_2}\geqslant 0\). Therefore, the proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 10
If \(\alpha \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\), by differentiating the firm’s profits with respect to \(a_1\) and \(a_2\) in four information cases, we obtain \(\partial \pi _F^{SO}/\partial a_1=\partial \pi _F^{SU}/\partial a_1=\partial \pi _F^{AO}/\partial a_1=\partial \pi _F^{AU}/\partial a_1=1-2\alpha \geqslant 0\) and \( \partial \pi _F^{SO}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{SU}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{AO}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{AU}/\partial a_2=2\alpha -1 \leqslant 0\), respectively. If \(\alpha >\frac{1}{2}\), by differentiating the firm’s profits with respect to \(a_2\) and \(a_1\) in four information cases, we obtain \( \partial \pi _F^{SO}/\partial a_1=0\), \(\partial \pi _F^{SU}/\partial a_1=(1-2\alpha )((1-2\alpha )a_1-1)<0\), \(\partial \pi _F^{AO}/\partial a_1=(1-2\alpha )(1-F(\theta ))<0\), \(\partial \pi _F^{AU}/\partial a_1<(1-2\alpha )(1-F(\theta ))<0\) and \(\partial \pi _F^{SO}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{SU}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{AO}/\partial a_2=\partial \pi _F^{AU}/\partial a_2=2\alpha -1>0\), respectively. Therefore, the proof of the proposition is complete. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 11
Similar to the Proof of Proposition 10.\(\square \)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Chen, Z., Lan, Y. & Zhao, R. Impacts of risk attitude and outside option on compensation contracts under different information structures. Fuzzy Optim Decis Making 17, 13–47 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10700-016-9263-7
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10700-016-9263-7