Skip to main content
Log in

Designing free software samples: a game theoretic approach

  • Published:
Information Technology and Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a vertical differentiation game-theoretic model that addresses the issue of designing free software samples (shareware) for attaining follow-on sales. When shareware can be reinstalled, cannibalization of sales of the commercial product may ensue. We analyze the optimal design of free software according to two characteristics: the evaluation period allotted for sampling (potentially renewable) and the proportion of features included in the sample. We introduce a new software classification scheme based on the characteristics of the sample that aid consumer learning. We find that the optimal combination of features and trial time greatly depends on the category of software within the classification scheme. Under alternative learning scenarios, we show that the monopolist may be better off not suppressing potential shareware reinstallation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Learning can be broadly defined here as acquiring information about previously unknown characteristics of the product, or learning how to use the product in an effective manner (i.e. training).

  2. The issue of product sales cannibalization is also studied in Takeyama [13]. She hows that a durable-good monopolist may indeed choose to cannibalize its own high-end product by offering goods of lesser quality, which results in a consumer welfare improving equilibrium. Haruvy and Prasad [6] analyze sales cannibalization in the context of network effects. They find that when software products benefit from network effects, these effects may play a role in mitigating the cannibalization of sales. However, they do not consider the case of network effects having an adverse impact on sales. In particular, a large base of free software users may create an incentive for newcomers to keep using the free sample rather than buying the actual product.

  3. Cakanyildirim and Dalgic [2] study demonstration strategies that promote information products. The strategic variables used in their model are demo features and the length of the demo phase. Heiman and Muller [8] show how the demonstration phase may vary in length depending on how competitive the industry is, and depending on whether the demonstration is personalized or not.

  4. Software & Information Industry Association’s website at http://www.siia.net/piracy..

  5. For a good introduction on vertical product differentiation, see Sutton [12].

  6. Coase [4] and Stokey [11] are the classic articles regarding the analysis of the standard durable good monopolist. More recently, Dhebar [5] studies how the speed of improvement of the intrinsic quality of software (or other durable good products) affects the dynamics of sales.

  7. Source: “Scale or Scope: that is the M&A Question in Software”, Deloitte Consulting, 2005.

  8. In extensive form game terminology, a stage is a collection of periods defined by which player’s turn it is to play strategically.

  9. To simplify the analysis we assume that while the consumer tests the sample during the evaluation period, which could be less than the full game period; she makes his decision to buy (or not to buy) the product or re-use the sample only at the end of period 1. In Sect. 5, we examine other types of learning processes, which may result in different segments of consumers buying in different periods.

  10. Note that the one-period utility obtained from using the full commercial version is θ since the commercial product provides all the features (s = 1) and gives the full trial time (t = 1). However, a consumer may still face a time constraint, even though full features and full trial time are being given to him. This time constraint arises from the effort the consumer must spend in reinstalling the sample, as we will see later.

  11. Our characterization of learning is congruent with Heiman and Muller’s [7] approach. They argue that demonstrations (length or trial time) reduce the purchasing risk and thus possibly increase the probability of purchase at any given price. In our model, the likelihood of purchase is impacted not only by trial time but also by the sample’s features.

  12. Recall that the utility for the commercial product θ is obtained at the end of each game period.

  13. In the unlikely instance where the monopolist would give out the full-blown version of the product as the sample, we observe that the utility from buying the product outright is less than that of evaluating the sample and then buying. The main reason for that difference is that expected payoffs are updated based on new information in the latter case. On the other hand, if there were perfect information about the product, no updating would take place and the two cases would yield the same payoff.

  14. Note that the learning function V is assumed to also affect the utility obtained from reinstalling the sample, since the consumer may develop a greater appreciation for the sample itself, once the learning period is completed.

  15. It is important to note that in our framework when the monopolist gives the full commercial product as a free sample (s = 1, t = 1) with no reinstallation restriction (d = 1), demand collapses and the price is zero. However, in the case where d = 1, we recognize that trial time is actually of no consequence for the consumer. This boundary case can be easily accommodated by modifying the sample’s definition to state that the minimum trial time t 0 is always 1 when d = 1.

  16. Parker and Van Alstyne [10] also introduce a classification scheme for information product design. They classify information goods as strategic complements or substitutes according to their ability to generate network externalities.

  17. Furthermore, all these characteristics are of interest to the consumer mainly prior to the purchase decision. Once the product is purchased it is too late so to speak, since consumers must now contend with the difficulties of learning how to operate the product. Tests featured in consumer magazines are another way to reveal some of the products characteristics to prospective buyers.

  18. This classification is not exclusively tied to the specific functional form we used to model learning, since the parameters have very natural and general interpretations.

  19. It is also important to note that as shown in Appendix A (Case 1), the local optima (trial time and proportion of features) are independent of both the consumer’s and the monopolist’s discount rates, since in our framework profit maximization amounts to maximizing staticconsumer demand. However, the monopolist’s discount rate does play a role in determining the global optimum (conclusion of Case 2).

  20. Obviously there are other circumstances when free samples should not be given. Case 2 in Appendix A shows that this could happen if the cost of distribution is significant and the monopolist is impatient.

  21. The concept of multi-period learning may seem misleading at first, since a ‘period’ can be arbitrarily defined to fit any length necessary. However, the choice of the industry standard regarding the maximum evaluation period must be determined in part by how long it takes consumers on average to learn about the product. In addition, a monopolist may choose to extend the evaluation period to expand demand, when for example there is a wide dispersion of learning abilities in the consumer population.

  22. However, this loss may itself be mitigated, when for example, the monopolist is able to prevent further reinstallation of the sample.

  23. We still assume here that the consumer will only buy at the end of a game period (maximum industry standard), rather than at the end of trial time. In that instance, the monopolist profits are always occurring at the end of the game period. Thus, a delay in collecting revenues is possible, but it only depends on the maximum trial duration.

  24. Implicitly, we are assuming that a monopolist can prevent 100% reinstallation at a zero fixed cost, via human monitoring for example.

  25. The proof in Appendix B assumes that consumers cannot buy beyond period 2. Given the nature of scenario (1), the optimal solutions for trial time and proportion of features remain identical as in the basic model.

References

  1. G.E. Belch and M.A. Belch, Introduction to Advertising and Promotion Management, Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  2. M. Cakanyildirim and T. Dalgic, Using demonstration to promote information products, working paper, University of Texas at Dallas (2002).

  3. S.-Y. Choi, D.O. Stahl and A.B. Whinston, The Economics of Electronic Commerce, McMillan Technical Publishing (1997). Available at: http://www.smartecon.com/products/catalog/eecflyer.asp

  4. R.H. Coase, Durability and monopoly, Journal of Law and Economics 15 (1972) 143–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. A. Dhebar, Durable-goods monopolists, rational consumers, and improving products, Marketing Science 13(13) (1994) 100–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. E. Haruvy and A. Prasad, Optimal freeware quality in the presence of network externalities: an volutionary game theoretical approach, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 11 (2001) 231–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. A. Heiman and E. Muller, Using demonstration time to increase new product acceptance: controlling demonstration time, Journal of Marketing Research 33 (1996) 422–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. A. Heiman and E. Muller, The effects of competition and costs on demonstration strategies in the Software Industry, Mimeo, Tel Aviv University (2001).

  9. M.L. Katz and C. Shapiro, Network externalities, competition, and compatibility, American Economic Review 75(3) (1985) 424–440.

    Google Scholar 

  10. G.C. Parker and M.W. Van Alstyne, Information complements, substitutes, and strategic product design, working paper, Economics Dept., University of Michigan (2000).

  11. N. Stokey, Rational expectations and durable goods pricing, Bell Journal of Economics 12 (1981) 12–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. S. John, Vertical product differentiation, AER Papers and Proceedings (1986) pp. 393–398.

  13. L.N. Takeyama, Strategic vertical differentiation and durable goods monopoly, Journal of Industrial Economics 50(1) (2002) 43–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. J. Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press, Cambridge Mass. (1988).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giri Kumar Tayi.

Appendices

Appendix A: Basic model proofs

Below, we analyze the Subgame Perfect equilibria of the basic game. Using Proposition 1 we can rule out as an equilibrium the case where a monopolist would offer a free sample and consumers decline using the free sample and buy the product right away. One interesting insight from this proposition is that the payoff to the consumer from buying without receiving a sample or buying while declining to use the free sample must be the same.

Case 1

(A free sample is offered) The solution (\({s^\ast,t^\ast}\)) is such that \({s_{0}\leq s^\ast\leq 1}\) and \({t_{0}\leq t^\ast \leq 1}\).

By backward induction, the consumers who use the sample and then buy (B) must have their payoffs satisfy: (1) \({\delta{U}-\delta {P}+\delta ^{2}\theta {V}/(1-\delta) > \delta {U}+{d}UV\delta ^{2}/(1-\delta)}\) (Sampling and Buy > Sampling and Reinstall Sample). Condition (1) is equivalent to \({\theta > {(1-\delta)P}/{\delta {K}(s,t)}}\); where \({{K}(s,t)=[{1- ds({(1+t)}/{2}})]{V} > 0}\). The demand function is given by \({D(P,t,s)= {N}[1- \Psi ((1-\delta)P/\delta{K})]}\).

The monopolist’s profit is \({\Pi_{1}={D}(P,t,s)\times[P-c]-{F}-{N}\gamma c}\). The optimal solution for the price P *1 satisfies the following first order condition:

$$ \frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial P}=\frac{\partial {D}}{\partial P} \left[{P-c} \right]+{D}=0 $$
(1)

Solving Eq. 1 leads to:

$$ P_1^\ast =\frac{c}{2}+\frac{\delta {K}^{\ast}\theta_{\rm H}} {2(1-\delta)} $$
(2)

To insure that any demand exists, we check that \({\theta_{H} > (1-\delta)P_1^\ast /\delta {K}^{\ast}}\), which is implied by \({\theta_{\rm H} > {((1-\delta)}/{\delta})c}\) when \({{K}^{\ast} > 1}\); where the variable K * represents the function \({K(\cdot}\)) evaluated at the point (s *, t *). The monopolist’s optimal profit is \({\Pi _1^\ast=({{N}}/({\theta_{\rm H} -\theta_{\rm L}}))\times ({\delta {K}^{\ast}}/{4(1-\delta )})\times [{\theta_{\rm H}-(({(1-\delta )c})/{\delta {K}^{\ast}})}]^2-{F}- {N}\gamma c.}\)

The optimal proportion of features s * is given by the following necessary first order conditions depending on whether the solution is a corner or interior one:

$$ \left\{ {{\begin{array}{l} {s^\ast =s_0}\\ {s^\ast =\bar {s}}\\ {s^\ast =1}\\ \end{array}}}\right.\frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial s}=\frac{\partial \mbox{D}}{\partial s}\left[ {P-c} \right]\left\{ {{\begin{array}{l} { < 0}\\ {=0}\\ { > 0}\\ \end{array} }} \right. \quad {\begin{array}{l} {(3\hbox{a})}\\ {(3\hbox{b})}\\ {(3\hbox{c})}\\ \end{array} } $$

with \({\frac{\partial {D}}{\partial s}={N}\times \frac{P}{{K}^{2}}\times \Psi'()\times\frac{\partial K}{\partial s}}\). Thus, Eqs. 3a, b, c become (given t *):

$$ \left\{{{\begin{array}{l} {s^\ast =s_0} \\ {s^\ast =\bar{s}}\\ {s^\ast =1}\\ \end{array}}} \right.\frac{\partial K}{\partial s}=-{d}\left( {\frac{1+t^\ast }{2}} \right)V^\ast +\left[{1-{d}s\frac{1+t^\ast}{2}} \right]\frac{\partial V}{\partial s}\left\{{{\begin{array}{l} { < 0} \\ {=0} \\ { > 0} \\ \end{array} }} \right. \quad {\begin{array}{l} {(4\hbox{a})}\\ {(4\hbox{b})}\\ {(4\hbox{c})}\\ \end{array}} $$

Similarly, the optimal trial time t * is given by the following first order conditions:

$$ \left\{{{\begin{array}{l} {t^\ast =t_0}\\ {t^\ast =\bar{t}}\\ {t^\ast =1} \\ \end{array}}} \right.\frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial t}=\frac{\partial {D}}{\partial t}\left[{P-c} \right]\left\{ {{\begin{array}{l} { < 0}\\ {=0}\\ { > 0}\\ \end{array}}} \right. \quad {\begin{array}{l} {(5\hbox{a})}\\ {(5\hbox{b})}\\ {(5\hbox{c})}\\ \end{array}} $$

Again, Eqs. 5a, b, c become (given s *):

$$ \left\{{{\begin{array}{l} {t^\ast =t_0}\\ {t^\ast =\bar{t}}\\ {t^\ast =1} \\ \end{array}}} \right.\frac{\partial K}{\partial t}=-\frac{{d}s^\ast }{2}V^\ast +\left[ {1-{d}s^\ast \frac{1+t}{2}} \right]\frac{\partial V}{\partial t}\left\{ {{\begin{array}{l} { < 0}\\ {=0}\\ { > 0}\\ \end{array}}} \right. {\begin{array}{l} {(6\hbox{a})}\\ {(6\hbox{b})}\\ {(6\hbox{c})}\\ \end{array} } $$

Since fixed costs are assumed independent of the sample’s actual values for s and t, our (local) optimal proportion of features and optimal trial time are determined at the margin by maximizing static demand. Maximizing demand in our framework translates into maximizing the function \({K(\cdot}\)), which pins down the trade-off between the impact of learning on the desirability of purchasing the product versus the attractiveness of sample reinstallation.

Thus, our solutions are maximizing the function \({K(\cdot)}\) given the parameter values. Regarding interior solutions, a series of simple algebraic manipulations respectively using (4b) and (6b) leads to:

$$ \bar {s}(t^{\ast})=\frac{1}{d(1+t^{\ast})}- \frac{(1-\alpha)}{2\alpha}t^{\ast}-\frac{1}{2\alpha A} $$
(7)
$$ \bar {t}(s^{\ast})=\frac{1}{ds^{\ast}}-\frac{\alpha }{2(1-\alpha)}s^{\ast}-\frac{1+A(1-\alpha)}{2A(1-\alpha)} $$
(8)

It is important to note that the proportion of features s * and the trial time t * cannot jointly be interior solutions at the same time, since we can easily show that the Hessian is not negative semi-definite at the point (\({\bar {s},\bar{t}}\)). In fact, the pair (\({\bar{s},\bar {t}}\)) represents a saddle point solution in the feasible space.

Case 1.1

(s *, t *) = (1,1) will be true if (4c) and (6c) hold.

It is easy to see that (4c) is equivalent to \({1 < \bar{s}(1)}\) and (6c) is equivalent to \({1 < \bar {t}(1)}\). These two conditions will be satisfied when d is close to zero (reinstallation cost is infinite).

Case 1.2

(\({s^\ast ,t^\ast )=(s_{0},t_{0})}\) will be true if (4a) and (6a) hold.

Both conditions are equivalent to having \({s_{0} > \bar {s}(t_0)}\) and \({t_{0} > \bar {t}(s_0)}\). These conditions will be satisfied even when d is large (reinstallation cost is low) but not arbitrarily close to 1; α is in a compact range (not too close to either 0 or 1); and some or all of the following hold: A, s 0 and t 0 are large. Moreover, when A is small then α must be large, and vice versa.

Case 1.3

\({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)=(1,{t}_{0})}\) will be true if (4c) and (6a) hold.

These conditions are equivalent to \({1 < \bar {s}(t_0)}\) and \({t_{0} > \bar {t}(1)}\) as well as \({(1-\alpha)(1-t_{0}) < \alpha}\). These conditions are satisfied if \({\alpha}\) is large, t 0 and d small; and both A and s 0 are either large or small in tandem (d must be close to 0 when A and s 0 are both small). The conditions A and s 0 being either large or small together insure that \({{K}(1,t_{0})\geq \hbox{max}\{{K}(s^\ast ,t^\ast);s^\ast \in \{s_{0},\bar{s},1\}; t^\ast \in \{t_{0},\bar{t},1\}\}}\).

Case 1.4

\({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)=(s_{0},1)}\) will be true if (4a) and (6c) hold.

These conditions are equivalent to \({{s}_{0} > \bar {s}(1)}\) and \({1 < \bar {t}(s_0)}\) implying \({2(1-\alpha) > \alpha s_{0}}\). These conditions are satisfied when α and s 0 are small. A higher value for A will make the condition on α less binding.

Case 1.5

\({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)=(\bar {s},t_{0})}\) will be true if (4b) and (6a) hold. The latter condition is equivalent to \({t_{0} > \bar {t}(\bar{s})}\) and both conditions imply that \({(1-\alpha)(1+t_{0}) < \alpha \bar{s}}\). This will be true when α and A are large and s0 and d are small. The condition s0 small is necessary otherwise, case 1.2 would dominate.

Case 1.6

\({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)=(s_{0},\bar{t})}\) will be true if (4a) and (6b) hold. The first condition is equivalent to \({s_{0} > \bar {s}(\bar{t})}\) and both conditions imply \({(1-\alpha)(1+\bar{t}) > \alpha s_{0}}\). This is true when α is small, A and s0 are large and d is large enough.

Case 1.7

(Not a solution) (s*, t*) = (\({\bar {s},1)}\) will be true if (4b) and (6c) hold. This pair cannot be a solution. The latter condition is equivalent to \({\bar{t}(\bar{s}) > 1}\) and both conditions imply that \({(1-\alpha)(1+t_{0}) > \alpha \bar{s}}\) which will be true if α is small, A and t0 large, with d not too small. This solution is dominated by (s0, t*) with \({t^\ast \in\{t_{0} ,\bar{t}, 1\}}\). The idea being that if A is large and α is small, reducing the sample features does not reduce its marketing power, while at the same time it prevents sample re-use.

Case 1.8

(Not a solution)\({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)=(1,\bar{t})}\) will be true if (4c) and (6b) hold. Again, this pair cannot be a solution. The first condition is equivalent to \({\bar{s}(\bar{t}) > 1}\) and both conditions imply that \({(1-\alpha)(1+\bar{t}) < \alpha}\); which will be true if α and A are large and d small. This solution is dominated by picking (s*, t0) with \({s^\ast \in \{s_{0},\bar{s},1\}}\). The idea being that if α is large, trial time plays a minor role, and hence reducing it does not lower the attractiveness of the product since A is large.

Case 2

(No Free Sample is Given) Assume that the monopolist strategy space is limited to picking a proportion of features s < s 0. Since the proportion of features is below the minimum, then V = 1. Thus, the function \({{K}=1-{d}s({(({1+t})/{2})})}\) takes values in the interval [0,1]. It is easy to see that the demand \({D(P, t, s)}\) is decreasing in s and t. By not distributing a free sample, the monopolist is also not incurring the cost \({N\gamma c}\) of making and distributing copies of the sample. Thus, the optimal response for the monopolist is to set \({s^\ast}\) and \({t^\ast = 0}\). Moreover, the standard first order condition for selecting the optimal price \({P_2^\ast}\) leads to \({P_2^\ast =({c}/{2})+({\delta \theta_{\rm H}}/{2(1-\delta)})}\), and the profit is \({\Pi_2^\ast ={{N}}/({\theta_{\rm H}-\theta_{\rm L}})({\delta }/{4(1-\delta)})[ {\theta}_{\rm H} -({(1-\delta)}/{\delta}) c]^2}-F\). Lastly, for the demand to exist we need \({\theta_{\rm H} > ({(1-\delta )c}/{\delta})}\).

We need to check that selecting \({s^\ast}\) and \({t^\ast = 0}\) is optimal over the global strategy space. This will be the case if \({\Pi _2^\ast > \delta_{\rm m}\Pi _1^\ast}\) where \({\Pi _1^\ast}\) is the maximum profit generated in Case 1. It is easy to check that \({\Pi _2^\ast > \delta _{\rm m}\Pi _1^\ast}\) when γ large, δ m small and \({K^{\ast} < 1}\). The latter will be true when the learning parameter A is small and/or s 0 is close to 1, and/or t 0 is close to 1, and/or the reinstallation cost is low (d large), and/or α is small. Otherwise, the solutions \({s_{0 }\le s^\ast \leq 1}\) and \({t_{0 }\le t^\ast \leq 1}\) explored in Case (1) are optimal over the global strategy space, i.e. including selecting s < s 0 and t < t 0, under contrary assumptions. □

Appendix B: Multi-period learning proofs

Case 1

(2-period learning) We assume that in addition to the strategies that were available before, consumers can also buy the product in period 2; but not beyond that period. Below, we analyze the equilibrium where two sequential market demands co-exit with one segment of consumers who prefer buying at the end of period 1, and another segment who will buy after two periods.

Subcase 1.1

The solution \({(s^\ast ,t^\ast)}\) is such that \({s_{0}\leq s^\ast \leq 1}\) and \({t_{0}\leq t^\ast \leq 1}\).

To keep the notations lighter we examine the consumers payoffs from the standpoint of present values at the end of period 1 (after sampling), and not the beginning of stage 1 as was done in the basic model. By backward induction, the consumers who will use the sample and then buy (B) at end of period 1 must have their payoffs satisfy the following conditions; given that learning occurs according to the learning function L 1:

  1. (1)

    \({{U}-{P}+ \delta \theta {V}+\delta^{2}\theta \lambda {V}/(1-\delta) > {U}+\delta d {UV}+\delta ^{2}d {U} \lambda {V}/(1-\delta)}\) (Buy at end period 1 > Not-Buy)

  2. (2)

    \({{U}-{P}+ \delta \theta {V}+\delta ^{2}\theta \lambda {V}/(1-\delta) > {U}-\delta {P}+ \delta d {UV} +\delta^{2}\theta \lambda {V}/(1-\delta)}\) (Buy at end period 1 > Buy at end of period 2) . By backward induction, consumers who will use the sample and then buy (B) at end of period 2 must have their payoffs satisfy:

  3. (3)

    \({{U}-\delta {P}+ \delta d {UV} +\delta ^{2}\theta \lambda {V}/(1-\delta) > {U}+\delta d {UV}+\delta^{2}d {U} \lambda {V}/(1-\delta)}\) (Buy at end period 2 > Not-Buy)

Note that conditions (2) and (3) imply condition (1).

Condition (3) is equivalent to \({\theta > \bar {\theta}_1={((1-\delta)P)}/{\lambda \delta {K}(s,t)}}\); where \(K(\cdot)\) is defined as before in the basic model. Condition (2) is equivalent to \({\theta > \bar {\theta}_2 ={(1-\delta )P}/{\delta {K}(s,t)}}\). It is easy to show that \({\bar{\theta}_2 > \bar {\theta}_1}\) since \({\lambda > 1}\). More importantly, the segment of consumers that satisfy \({\theta > \bar {\theta}_2}\) will buy at the end of period 1, and the segment of consumers satisfying \({\bar{\theta}_2 > \theta > \bar{\theta}_1}\), will buy in the second period. The demand from consumers buying in period 1 is \({{D}_{1}({P}, t,s)={N}[1-\Psi(\bar{\theta}_2)]}\). The residual demand from consumers buying in period 2 is \({{D}_{2}({P}, t,s)={N}[\Psi(\bar \theta_2)-\Psi(\bar{\theta}_1)]}\). The monopolist’s profit (valued at end of period 1) is \({\Pi = [{D}_{1}+\delta_{\rm m}{D}_{2}]\times [{P}-c]-F-N\gamma c}\); which is the present value of profits obtained from the total demand. Let us denote the total demand by \({{D}=[{D}_{1}+\delta_{m}{D}_{2}]}\). The optimal solution for the price \({P^\ast}\) is found using the following first order condition:

$$ \frac{\partial \Pi}{\partial P}=\frac{\partial {D}}{\partial P}\left[{P-c}\right]+{D}=0 $$
(9)

Solving Eq. 9 leads to:

$$ P^\ast =\frac{c}{2}+\frac{\delta {K}^{\ast}{\theta }_{\rm H}}{2(1-\delta)}\times \frac{\lambda}{\lambda-\delta_m (\lambda -1)} $$
(10)

Given the expression for the total demand and the price above, the monopolist’s optimal profit is given by \({\Pi ^\ast=({{N}}/({\theta_{\rm H}-\theta_{\rm L} }))\times ({\delta {K}^{\ast}}/{(4(1-\delta))})\times ({\lambda}/({\lambda -\delta_m (\lambda -1)}))\times [{\theta_{\rm H}-({\lambda-\delta_m (\lambda -1)})/{\lambda}\times ({(1-\delta )c})/{\delta {K}^{\ast}}}]^2-{F}- {N}\gamma c.}\)

Just as was done in Appendix A, it is straightforward to show that maximizing the profit function is equivalent to maximizing the function \({K(\cdot)}\) with respect to trial time and proportion of features. Therefore, the solutions (\({s^\ast ,t^\ast}\)) are the same as the ones described in Appendix A.

Subcase 1.2

The solution (\({s^\ast ,t^\ast}\)) is such that \({s^\ast < s_{0}}\) and \({t^\ast < t_{0}}\). This sub-case is the same as in Appendix A.

Case 2

(One-period learning; no reinstallation possible) Since the sample is essentially non-durable it is straightforward to show that the optimal solution (\({s^\ast,t^\ast) =(1,T}\)). The consumers that sample and buy must satisfy \({U-P+\delta^{\rm T}\lambda ^{\rm T-1}{V}_{\rm max}\theta /(1-\delta^{\rm T}) > U}\); since no reinstallation is possible; and given that learning occurs according to the learning function L 2: where \({{V}_{\rm max} =A(\alpha +(1-\alpha)T)+1}\). Maximizing profit with respect to price gives:

$$ P_3^\ast=\frac{c}{2}+\frac{\lambda^{T-1}\delta ^TV_{\rm max} \theta_{\rm H}}{2(1-\delta^T)}, $$
(11)

Again, given the assumption that completely preventing the unauthorized reinstallation of free samples is costless for the monopolist (independent of d), the monopolist’s optimal profit must given by \({\Pi_3^\ast =({{N}}/({\theta_{\rm H} -\theta_{\rm L}}))\times ({\lambda^{T-1}\delta ^T{V}_{\rm max}}/({4(1-\delta ^T)}))\times [{\theta_{\rm H}-({(1-\delta ^T)c})/{\lambda^{T-1}\delta^T{V}_{\rm max}}}]^2-F-N \gamma c}\). Comparing Case 1 with Case 2, we surmise that Case 1 will be favored by the monopolist when \({\delta_{m}\Pi^\ast > \delta ^{T}_{m}\Pi_3^\ast}\). This is true when the following sufficient condition holds:

$$ \frac{\delta {K}^{\ast}}{(1-\delta)}\times \frac{\lambda }{\lambda -\delta_m (\lambda -1)} > \frac{\lambda^{T-1}\delta ^T{V}_{\rm max}}{(1-\delta ^T)} $$
(12)

Let \({\bar{T}(A, d, \alpha , t_0,\delta , \delta_{m}, \lambda)}\) be such that:

$$ \frac{\lambda^{\bar{T}-1}\delta^{\bar{T}}\bar{V}_{\rm max}} {(1-\delta^{\bar{T}})}= \frac{\delta {K}^{\ast}} {(1-\delta)}\times \frac{\lambda}{\lambda -\delta_m(\lambda-1)} $$
(13)

A solution \({\bar{T}}\) exists if the RHS of (12) is monotonic in T, and under other conditions on the parameters defined below. Thus (12) is equivalent to:

$$ \frac{\lambda^{\bar{T}-1}\delta^{\bar{T}}{\bar {{V}}}_{\rm max}} {(1-\delta^{\bar T})} > \frac{\lambda^{T-1}\delta^T{V}_{\rm max}} {(1-\delta^T)} $$
(14)

From Eq. 14, we can see that Case 1 will be favored when \({T\geq \bar {T}({A}, d, \alpha ,t_0, \delta , \delta _{m}, \lambda)}\) as long as \({{\partial({\lambda^{T-1}\delta^T{V}_{\rm max}}/{(1-\delta^T)})}/{\partial T} < 0}\). It is easy to check that this latter derivative being negative is implied by λ close to 1. Moreover, these conditions with δ m small and d large are also sufficient for the value of \({({\delta{K}^{\ast}}/{(1-\delta)})\times({\lambda}/({\lambda -\delta_m(\lambda -1))})}\) to be contained in the interval of minimum and maximum values for the function \({{\lambda^{T-1}\delta ^T{V}_{\rm max}}/{(1-\delta ^T)}}\). Furthermore, basic comparative statics on Eq. 13 reveals that \({\bar{T}}\) must be increasing in A, \({\alpha, s_0, t_0}\); since d is assumed large. However, the effect of raising the discount rate \({\delta}\) on \({\bar{T}}\) is ambiguous.

On the other hand, \({{\partial({\lambda ^{T-1}\delta^T{V}_{\rm max}}/{(1-\delta^T)})}/{\partial T} > 0}\), implies that Case 1 will be favored when \({\bar{T}({A}, d, \alpha, t_0, \delta,\delta_{m},\lambda) \quad \ge T}\). It is easy to check that this latter derivative being positive is implied by \({\lambda}\) large. Moreover, these conditions with \({\delta_{m}}\) small and d small are also sufficient for the value of \({({\delta{K}^{\ast}}/{(1-\delta)})\times ({\lambda}/{(\lambda -\delta_m (\lambda -1))})}\) to be contained in the interval of minimum and maximum values for the function \({{\lambda^{T-1}\delta^T{V}_{\rm max}}/{(1-\delta^T)}}\). The comparative statics from (13) follows from the same argument as before. It shows that \({\bar {T}}\) must be decreasing in A, \({\alpha, s_0}\) and \({t_0}\), and increasing in \({\delta}\); especially when d is assumed small. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Faugère, C., Tayi, G.K. Designing free software samples: a game theoretic approach. Inf Technol Manage 8, 263–278 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10799-006-0002-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10799-006-0002-6

Keywords

Navigation