Skip to main content
Log in

Intelligent information sharing among manufacturers in supply networks: supplier selection case

  • Published:
Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Decision making in highly distributed supply networks has become more complex in globally dynamic markets. Despite extensive previous work on supply network decisions, it is still necessary to develop advanced tools for selective collection, management, and sharing of relevant information. In this research, a new intelligent, distributed, and autonomous information sharing protocol is modelled and applied to analytically determine supplier information sharing among manufacturers. Information sharing with all manufacturers is neither sensible nor realistic, since it requires high communication/implementation costs and cannot guarantee a positive return to all parties. Our Intelligent Supplier Information Sharing (ISIS) protocol supports each manufacturer’s decision-making process on selective information sharing. It does so by analyzing the expected sharing benefit while estimating the value of other parties’ information. Through a negotiation process, the appropriate price for shared information that each manufacturer has to pay is also determined. Numerical examples illustrate the performance of the ISIS protocol. Compared to no sharing and complete sharing of information, selective sharing recommended by ISIS yields relatively higher profits. For the case analyzed, profit increase by ISIS is, on average, 15.5 % higher than with complete information sharing, and this advantage holds even under changing conditions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Anussornnitisarn, P., & Nof, S. Y. (2003). E-work: The challenge of the next generation ERP systems. Production Planning and Control, 14(8), 753–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, M. W., & Miller, C. J. (2000). Analysis of the virtual enterprise using distributed supply chain modeling and simulation: An application of e-SCOR. Winter Simulation Conference Proceedings, 1, 352–355.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barratt, M. (2004). Understanding the meaning of collaboration in the supply chain. Supply Chain Management, 9(1), 30–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, C. R., & Rogers, D. S. (2008). A framework of sustainable supply chain management: Moving toward new theory. International Journal of Physical Distribution & Logistics Management, 38(5), 360–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Catalano, C. E., Camossi, E., Ferrandes, R., Cheutet, V., & Sevilmis, N. (2009). A product design ontology for enhancing shape processing in design workflows. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 20(5), 553–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceroni, J. A., & Nof, S. Y. (2002). A workflow model based on parallelism for distributed organizations. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 13(6), 439–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceroni, J. A., Matsui, M., & Nof, S. Y. (1999). Communication-based coordination modeling in distributed manufacturing systems. International Journal of Production Economics, 60–61(1), 281–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, H.-C., Chen, M.-C., & Mao, C.-K. (2010). The evolutionary process and collaboration in supply chains. Industrial Management & Data Systems, 110(3), 453–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christodoulopoulos, K., Sourlas, V., Mpakolas, I., & Varvarigos, E. (2009). A comparison of centralized and distributed meta-scheduling architectures for computation and communication tasks in grid networks. Computer Communications, 32(7–10), 1172–1184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chungoora, N., Young, R., Gunendran, G., Palmer, C., Usman, Z., Anjum, N., et al. (2013). A model-driven ontology approach for manufacturing system interoperability and knowledge sharing. Computers in Industry, 64(4), 392–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobson, G., & Pinker, E. J. (2006). The value of sharing lead time information. IIE Transactions, 38, 171–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ertogral, K., & Wu, S. D. (2000). Auction-theoretic coordination of production planning in the supply chain. IIE Transactions, 32(10), 931–940.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Union (EU) competition rules. http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/competition/firms/l26062_en.htm.

  • Frank, L. (2004). Architecture for integration of distributed ERP systems and e-commerce systems. Industrial Management and Data Systems, 104(5), 418–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gavirneni, S., Kapuscinski, R., & Tayur, S. (1999). Value of information in capacitated supply chains. Management Science, 45(1), 16–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J. K., & Swatman, P. M. C. (1998). Efficient consumer response (ECR): A survey of the Australian grocery industry. Australian Journal of Information Systems, 5(2), 32–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, B., & Iravani, S. M. R. (2005). Production control policies in supply chains with selective-information sharing. Operations Research, 53(4), 662–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, G. Q., Lau, J. S. K., Mak, K. L., & Liang, L. (2005). Distributed supply-chain project rescheduling: Part I—impacts of information-sharing strategies. International Journal of Production Research, 43(24), 5107–5129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaber, M., Badr, Y., & Biennier, F. (2006). Distributed information system for the supply chain integration. International conference on information & communication technologies: From theory to applications (IEEE Cat. No. 06EX1220C), 6.

  • Jain, R., Chandrasekaran, A., & Erol, O. (2010). A framework for end-to-end approach to systems integration. International Journal of Industrial and Systems Engineering, 5(1), 79–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jardim-Goncalves, R., Sarraipa, J., Agostinho, C., & Panetto, H. (2011). Knowledge framework for intelligent manufacturing systems. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 22(5), 725–735.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jeong, I.-J., & Leon, V. J. (2002). Decision-making and cooperative interaction via coupling agents in organizationally distributed systems. IIE Transactions, 34(9), 789–802.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorgensen, C. R., Nelson, B., & Ratheal, S. (2014). Policy enabled information sharing system. U.S. Patent No. 8,825,611.

  • Lambert, D. M., & Cooper, M. C. (2000). Issues in supply chain management. Industrial Marketing Management, 29, 65–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, H. L., & Whang, S. (2000). Information sharing in a supply chain. International Journal of Manufacturing Technology and Management, 1(1), 79–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, G., Yang, H., Sun, L., & Sohal, A. S. (2009). The impact of IT implementation on supply chain integration and performance. International Journal of Production Economics, 120(1), 125–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Min, H., & Yu, W. B. (2008). Collaborative planning, forecasting and replenishment: Demand planning in supply chain management. International Journal of Information Technology and Management, 7(1), 4–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nof, S. Y. (2003). Design of effective e-work: Review of models, tools, and emerging challenges. Production Planning and Control, 14(8), 681–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachuri, S., Subrahmanian, E., Bouras, A., Fenves, S., Foufou, S. J., & Sriram, R. D. (2008). Information sharing and exchange in the context of product lifecycle management: Role of standards. Computer-Aided Design, 40(7), 789–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raghunathan, S. (2003). Impact of demand correlation on the value of and incentives for information sharing in a supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 146, 634–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Renewable Choice Energy. (2012a). Quick guide to understanding your Walmart sustainability index score. http://www.renewablechoice.com/assets/media/WalmartQuickGuide.pdf Accessed 31 May 2013.

  • Renewable Choice Energy. (2012b). The growing trend of sustainability scorecards: Why it makes sense to get on board. White Paper.

  • Sahin, F., & Robinson, E. P. (2002). Flow coordination and information sharing in supply chains: Review, implications, and directions for future research. Decision Sciences, 33(4), 505–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Semiconductor component manufacturers. http://ftp.itl.co.uk/HomePages/PAULREYNOLDS/semi.htm

  • Seok, H., & Nof, S. Y. (2011a). Decision support protocol for sustainability issues in supply networks. Proceedings of the 2011 industrial engineering research conference, Reno.

  • Seok, H., & Nof, S. Y. (2011b). The HUB-CI initiative for cultural, education and training, and healthcare networks. Proceedings of 21st international conference on production research, Stuttgart, Germany.

  • Seok, H., & Nof, S. Y. (2014a). Dynamic coalition reformation for adaptive demand and capacity sharing. International Journal of Production Economics, 147, 136–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seok, H., & Nof, S. Y. (2014b). Collaborative capacity sharing among manufacturers on the same supply network horizontal layer for sustainable and balanced returns. International Journal of Production Research, 52(6), 1622–1643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seok, H., Nof, S. Y., & Filip, F. G. (2012). Sustainability decision support system based on collaborative control theory. Annual Reviews in Control, 36(1), 85–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, W., Maturana, F., & Norrie, D. H. (2000). MetaMorph II: An agent-based architecture for distributed intelligent design and manufacturing. Journal of Intelligent Manufacturing, 11(3), 237–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shin, H. J. (2007). Collaborative production planning in a supply-chain network with partial information sharing. International Journal of Advanced Manufacturing Technology, 34(9–10), 981–987.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, L., & Nagi, R. (1997). Design and implementation of a virtual information system for agile manufacturing. IIE Transactions, 29(10), 839–857.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, G. (1997). Supply-chain operations reference model (SCOR): The first cross-industry framework for integrated supply-chain management. Logistics Information Management, 10(2), 62–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Troussier, N., Belkadi, F., Eynard, B., Messaadia, M., & Gidel, T. (2010). Supplier-oriented and product lifecycle management framework to support virtual organisations. International Journal of Product Development, 12(1), 49–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Umble, E. J., Haft, R. R., & Umble, M. M. (2003). Enterprise resource planning: Implementation procedures and critical success factors. European Journal of Operational Research, 146(2), 241–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uppin, M. S., & Hebbal, S. S. (2010). Multi agent system model of supply chain for information sharing. Contemporary Engineering Sciences, 3(1), 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waller, M., Johnson, M. E., & Davis, T. (1999). Vendor-managed inventory in the retail supply chain. Journal of Business Logistics, 20(1), 183–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wylie, L. (1990). A vision of next generation MRP II. Gartner Group, Scenario S-300-339.

  • Yao, D.-Q., Yue, X., & Liu, J. (2008). Vertical cost information sharing in a supply chain with value-adding retailers. Omega, 36(5), 838–851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yingzhao, S., & Jing, L. (2009). Information sharing model of supply chain based on third party logistics providers. ISECS international colloquium on computing, communication, control, and management (CCCM) (pp. 139–143).

  • Yoon, S.-W., & Nof, S. Y. (2010). Demand and capacity sharing decisions and protocols in a collaborative network of enterprises. Decision Support Systems, 49(4), 442–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, D. Y., Cao, X., Wang, L., & Zeng, Y. (2012). Mitigating the risk of information leakage in a two-level supply chain through optimal supplier selection. Journal of Intelligent manufacturing, 23(4), 1351–1364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, N., & Zhao, W. (2007). Privacy-preserving data mining systems. Computer, 40(4), 52–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Support by the PRISM Center (Production, Robotics, and Integration Software for Manufacturing and Management) at Purdue University and by the Kimberly-Clark Corporation, Latin American Operations (LAO) is acknowledged. Also, this work was supported in part by the Hongik University new faculty research support fund.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hyesung Seok.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Theorem 1:

Consider company A’s position; all of company A’s information is known and partial information about company B’s suppliers is provided \(\left( \overline{{{x_k ^{B}}}}\right) \). For convenience, all \(w_k ^{A}\) and \(w_k ^{B}\) are set as one because they do not affect the relationship between VI and expected profit-increase.

  • Case 1: \(m=1, n\ge 1 \)

In this case, partial information is the same as complete information. Hence, ISIS protocol is not necessary.

  • Case 2: \(m=2,\,n=1\)

    For convenience, simplified notations, \(x_1 \) and \(x_2 \) are used instead of \(x_{1,1} ^{A}\) and \(x_{2,1} ^{A}\); also, \(y_1 \) and \(y_{2} \)are used instead of \(x_{1,1} ^{B}\) and \(x_{2,1} ^{B}\); and \(\mu \) and \(\sigma \) are regarded as \(\mu _k \) and \(\sigma _k \), respectively. \(x_1 \) and \(x_2 \) are identified as follows: \(x_1 =min\left( {x_1 ,x_2 } \right) \) and \(x_2 =max\left( {x_1 ,x_2 } \right) \). In this case, \(VI^{B}\) is represented as in Eq. (12) by using Eq. (10).

$$\begin{aligned} VI^{B}=\bar{y}-\bar{x} =\left( {y_1 +y_2 } \right) /2-\left( {x_1 +x_2 } \right) /2 \end{aligned}$$
(12)

Because \(x_1 \), \(x_2 \), \(y_1 \), and \(y_2 \) are assumed to follow a Normal distribution (according to the assumptions in the notation), company A’s expected profit-increase can be estimated in two cases, as shown below.

  1. i.

    \(x_2 \le \bar{y}\)

    $$\begin{aligned} E\left( {p^{A}} \right)= & {} \int _{-\infty }^{\bar{{y}}} {\frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }\sigma }} \cdot \left( {2\bar{{y}}-y_1 -x_2 } \right) \nonumber \\&\times \cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{{y}}-y_1 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) dy_1 \nonumber \\&+ \int _{\bar{{y}}}^\infty \frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }\sigma }\cdot \left( {y_1 -x_2 } \right) \nonumber \\&\times \cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{{y}}-y_1 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) dy_{1}\nonumber \\= & {} \frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\cdot \left\{ {\sigma +\sqrt{\pi \cdot }\left( {{\bar{y}}-x_2 } \right) } \right\} \end{aligned}$$
    (13)
  2. ii.

    \(x_2 >\bar{y}\)

    $$\begin{aligned} E\left( {p^{A}} \right)= & {} \int _{-\infty }^{2{\bar{y}}-x_2} \frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }\sigma }\cdot (2\bar{{y}}-y_1 -x_2 )\nonumber \\&\times \cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{{y}}-y_1 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) dy_1 +\int _{2{\bar{y}}-x_2 }^{x_2 } 0\cdot dy_1\nonumber \\&+\int _{x_2 }^{\infty }\frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }\sigma }\cdot \left( {y_1 -x_2 } \right) \nonumber \\&\times \cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{{y}}-y_1 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) dy_1\nonumber \\= & {} \frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\cdot \left\{ \sqrt{\pi }\cdot \left( {\bar{{y}}-x_2 } \right) \cdot \left( {erf\left( {\frac{\bar{{y}}-x_2 }{\sigma }} \right) +1} \right) \right. \nonumber \\&+\left. \sigma \cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{{y}}-x_2 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) \right\} \end{aligned}$$
    (14)

    \(\therefore \) In both cases,

    $$\begin{aligned} \partial \left( {E\left( {p^{A}} \right) } \right) /\partial \left( {\bar{y}-x_2 } \right) >0 \end{aligned}$$
    (15)

    \(E\left( {p^{A}} \right) \) increases as the value of \(\bar{y}-x_2 \) is larger. It means that \(E\left( {p^{A}} \right) \) increases as \(VI^{B}\) increases.

  • Case 3: \(m\ge 2,\,n=2\)

The number of sustainability factors does not affect the relationship between VI and expected profit-increase because \(w_k ^{A}\) and \(w_k ^{B}\) are consistently considered in calculating both \(VI^{B} \quad \left( {VI^{A}} \right) \) and \(\left( {p^{A}} \right) \quad \left( {E\left( {p^{B}} \right) } \right) \). Hence, the result is the same as in Case 2.

  • Case 4: \(m\ge 3,\,n=1\)

As in Case 2, we use simplified notation as \(x_1 ,\,x_2 ,\ldots ,\,x_m \,\hbox {and}\,y_1 ,\,y_{2 } ,\ldots ,y_m \) instead of \(x_{1,1}^{A}\), \(x_{2,1} ^{A},\ldots ,x_{m,1} ^{A}\) and \(x_{1,1} ^{B}\), \(x_{2,1} ^{B},\ldots ,x_{m,1} ^{B}\); and \(\mu \) and \(\sigma \) are regarded as \(\mu _k \) and \(\sigma _k \), respectively. To find out the posterior distribution of \(y_1 ,\ldots ,\,y_m \), the case when n is 2 is considered.

Set u as in Eq. (16).

$$\begin{aligned} y_1 +y_2 =x_1 +x_2 +2\cdot VI^{B}=u \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Then, \(E\left( {p^{A}} \right) \) can be calculated as shown below.

$$\begin{aligned} E\left( {p^{A}} \right)= & {} r\cdot \left\{ {max \left( {y_1 ,\,y_2 } \right) -x_2 } \right\} ^{+}\cdot Pr(Y_1 =y_1 , Y_2 =y_2 ) \nonumber \\= & {} r\cdot \left\{ {max \left( {y_1 ,\,y_2 } \right) -x_2 } \right\} ^{+}\nonumber \\&\times \cdot Pr(Y_1 =y_1 ,\,Y_2 =u-y_1 ) \end{aligned}$$
(17)

The posterior distribution of \(y_1 \) and \(y_2 \) is represented as shown in Eq. (18e) by the following procedure.

$$\begin{aligned}&Pr \left( {Y_1 =y_1,\,Y_2 =y_2 |y_1 +y_2 =u} \right) \qquad u\sim N(2\mu , \sqrt{2}\sigma )\end{aligned}$$
(18a)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad =Pr \left( {Y_1 =y_1 ,\,Y_2 =u-y_1 |y_1 +y_2 =u} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(18b)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad =Pr \left( {Y_1 =y_1 ,\,Y_2 =u-y_1 } \right) /Pr \left( {y_1 +y_2 =u} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(18c)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \propto Pr \left( {Y_1 =y_1 ,\,Y_2 =u-y_1 } \right) \end{aligned}$$
(18d)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \propto exp\left( {-\frac{1}{2\sigma ^{2}}\left\{ {(y_1 -\mu )^{2}+\left( {\left( {u-y_1 } \right) -\mu } \right) ^{2}} \right\} } \right) \end{aligned}$$
(18e)

The result can be further represented as in Eqs. (19) and (20) by summarizing with \(\hbox {y}_1.\)

$$\begin{aligned}&\Pr \left( {Y_1 =y_1 ,\,Y_2 =y_2 |y_1 +y_2 =u} \right) \propto exp\left( {-2(y_1 -u/2)^{2}} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(19)
$$\begin{aligned}&\therefore \left( {{\begin{array}{l} {y_1 } \\ {y_2 } \\ \end{array} }} \right) \sim \mathbf{N}\left( {\left( {{\begin{array}{l} {\frac{u}{2}} \\ {\frac{u}{2}} \\ \end{array} }} \right) ,\left( {{\begin{array}{ll} {\left( {\frac{\sigma }{\sqrt{2}}} \right) ^{2}}&{} {\left( {\frac{\sigma }{\sqrt{2}}} \right) ^{2}} \\ {\left( {\frac{\sigma }{\sqrt{2}}} \right) ^{2}}&{} {\left( {\frac{\sigma }{\sqrt{2}}} \right) ^{2}} \\ \end{array} }} \right) } \right) \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Through the same procedure, the posterior distribution of \(y_1,\,y_2 ,\ldots ,y_n \) in case n is larger than 2 is as in Eq. (23).

$$\begin{aligned}&{\bar{x}}=\left( {x_1 +x_2 +\ldots +x_n } \right) /n,{\bar{y}}=\left( {y_1 +y_2 +\ldots +y_n } \right) /n \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned}&u=n*\bar{y} =n*\left( {\bar{x} +VI^{B}} \right) \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned}&\left( {{\begin{array}{l} {y_1 } \\ \vdots \\ {y_n } \\ \end{array} }} \right) \sim \mathbf{N}\left( {\left( {{\begin{array}{l} {u/n} \\ \vdots \\ {u/n} \\ \end{array} }} \right) ,\left( {{\begin{array}{lll} {\left( {\sigma /{\sqrt{n}}} \right) ^\mathbf{2}}&{} \ldots &{} \vdots \\ \vdots &{} \ldots &{} \vdots \\ \vdots &{} \ldots &{} {\left( {\sigma /{\sqrt{n}}} \right) ^\mathbf{2}} \\ \end{array} }} \right) } \right) \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(23)

As \(VI^{B}\) increases, the probability that \(y_1 ,\ldots ,y_n \) will be larger also increases. It means that company A has more chance to yield a profit by finding better supplier based on company B’s information as \(VI^{B}\) increases, i.e., \(E\left( {p^{A}} \right) \) increases as \(VI^{B}\) is larger.

  • Case 5: \(m\ge 3,\,n\ge 2\)

The result is the same as in Case 4 by the same reason explained in Case 3.

Also, based on the proof of Theorem 1, there is a consistent relationship between variance of suppliers’ sustainability scores \((\sigma _k ^{2})\) and expected profit-increase by the information sharing as shown below.

Proof of Theorem 2:

Theorem 2 is intuitively proven. As \(\sigma _k \) is larger, the possibility to find better supplier fitting to each manufacturer’s preference from the other company’s suppliers increases; especially, when the number of suppliers each manufacturer knows is smaller, the expected benefit from the sharing is significantly increased as \(\sigma _k \) is larger. Further mathematical proof is as follows.

Assume that all sustainability factors follow a same Normal distribution to simplify, i.e., \(\upmu \) and \(\upsigma \) are regarded as \(\mu _k \) and \(\sigma _k \), respectively. And, consider five cases, same as in the proof of Theorem 1.

  • Case 1: \(m=1,\,n\ge 1\)

In this case, partial information is the same as complete information. Therefore, there is no meaning to a larger \(\upsigma \).

  • Case 2: \(m=2,\,n=1\)

With the same settings in Case 2 in the proof of Theorem 1, Eqs. (13) and (14) are obtained, and used to consider the effect of larger \(\upsigma \) as below. Eq. (24) is the derivative of Eq. (13) with respect to \(\sigma \); and Eq. (25) is the derivative of Eq. (14) with respect to \(\sigma \).

  1. i.

    \(x_2 \le \bar{y}\)

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \left( {E\left( {p^{A}} \right) } \right) }{\partial \sigma }=\frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }}>0 \end{aligned}$$
    (24)
  2. ii.

    \(x_2 >\bar{y}\)

    $$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \left( {E\left( {p^{A}} \right) } \right) }{\partial \sigma }=\frac{r}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\cdot exp\left( {-\frac{\left( {\bar{y}-x_2 } \right) ^{2}}{\sigma ^{2}}} \right) >0 \end{aligned}$$
    (25)

    Therefore, as \(\sigma \) increases, the profit-increase of company A is also increased. This result is also the same for company B.

  • Case 3: \(m\ge 2,\,n=2\)

The number of sustainability factors does not affect the relationship between \(\sigma \) and expected profit-increase for the same reason explained in Case 3 in the proof of Theorem 1.

  • Case 4: \(m\ge 3,\,n=1\)

With the same settings in Case 4 in the proof of Theorem 1, Eq. (23) is obtained, and used to consider the effect of larger \(\sigma \). As \(\sigma \) increases, the probability that \(y_1 ,\ldots ,y_n \) will be large also increases. It means that company A has more chance to yield a profit by finding better supplier from company B’s information as \(\upsigma \) increases. In the case of company B, this result is also the same.

  • Case 5: \(m\ge 3,\,n\ge 2\)

The result is the same as in Case 4 by the same reason explained in Case 3.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Seok, H., Nof, S.Y. Intelligent information sharing among manufacturers in supply networks: supplier selection case. J Intell Manuf 29, 1097–1113 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10845-015-1159-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10845-015-1159-9

Keywords

Navigation