Skip to main content
Log in

On the Curvature of Homogeneous Functions

  • Technical Note
  • Published:
Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

    We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

    Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Abstract

Consider a quasiconcave, upper semicontinuous and homogeneous of degree \(\gamma \) function f. This paper shows that the reciprocal of the degree of homogeneity, \(1/\gamma \), can be interpreted as a measure of the degree of concavity of f. As a direct implication of this result, it is also shown that f is harmonically concave if \(\gamma \le -1\) or \(\gamma \ge 0\), concave if \(0\le \gamma \le 1\) and logconcave if \(\gamma \ge 0\). Some relevant applications to economic theory are given. For example, it is shown that a quasiconcave and homogeneous production function is concave if it displays nonincreasing returns to scale and logconcave if it displays increasing returns to scale.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Notes

  1. \(\mathbb {R} _{++}\equiv \left\{ y\in \mathbb {R}\mid y>0\right\} \).

  2. Strictly speaking, Crouzeix [7] proves this result in terms of convexity. Here, I phrase the results in terms of concavity because I apply the results to economics in which functions are more commonly assumed (quasi)concave in order to guarantee a maximum. Moreover, it should be noted that Crouzeix [7] also shows that f is a concave function when f is nonpositive for every x that belongs to the relative interior of \(\mathcal { X}\) (i.e., the interior of \(\mathcal {X}\) in the affine hull of \(\mathcal {X}\) ).

  3. I discuss the case \(f=0\) in Remark 3 but leave the remaining case \(f<0\) to future research.

  4. Balogh and Ewerhart [3] survey the origins of \(\rho \)-concavity and give Martos [14] credit of having introduced \(\rho \)-concavity. Martos [14] is written in Hungarian, where \(\rho \)-concavity is originally called \(\omega \)- concavity. Balogh and Ewerhart [3] give translations of relevant sections in Martos [14] into English. \(\rho \) (or \(\omega \))-concavity has also been referred to as \(\alpha \)-concavity in the mathematics literature (e.g., [13, 17]).

  5. But see e.g., [13].

  6. Specifically, by Jensen’s inequality, \(\partial M_{\rho }\left( y_{1},y_{2}\right) /\partial \rho \ge 0\). See also Hardy et al. ([10], Ch.2.9, p.26). And see e.g., ([5], Chapter III) where weighted power means and their properties are studied thoroughly.

  7. Indeed, the cases \(\lambda =0\) and \(\lambda =1\) trivially satisfy the definition of \(\rho \)-concavity regardless of whether the function is quasi-concave, homogeneous or upper semicontinuous. To see this consider \( \lambda =0\) (\(\lambda =1\) follows analogously), in which case the left-hand side of (1) in Definition 1.2 becomes \(f\left( \lambda x_{1}+\left( 1-\lambda \right) x_{2}\right) =f\left( x_{2}\right) \), while the right-hand side becomes \(\left[ \lambda f\left( x_{1}\right) ^{\frac{1}{ \gamma }}+\left( 1-\lambda \right) f\left( x_{2}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\gamma }} \right] ^{\gamma }=f\left( x_{2}\right) \), which of course trivially satisfies (1).

  8. See Section 3.5 in [4] for a detailed discussion of the properties of logconvex/logconcave functions and [2] about logconcave/logconvex probability distributions.

  9. This also follows as a special case of the results in Theorem 3.1 in Jehle and Reny [11] and [8, 15].

  10. See e.g., Bagnoli and Bergstrom [2] for conditions on distributions which guarantee logconcavity.

References

  1. Anderson, S.P., Renault, R.: Efficiency and surplus bounds in Cournot competition. J. Econ. Theory. 113, 253–264 (2003)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Bagnoli, M., Bergstrom, T.: Log-concave probability and its applications. Econ. Theory 26, 445–469 (2005)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Balogh, T.L., Ewerhart C.: On the origin of \(r-\)concavity and related concept. Working Paper No. 187, Department of Economics, University of Zurich (2015)

  4. Boyd, S., Vandenberghe, L.: Convex Optimization. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2004)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Bullen, P.S.: Handbook of Means and Their Inequalities, Chapter 3. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht (2003)

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  6. Caplin, A., Nalebuff, B.: Aggregation and social choice: a mean voter theorem. Econometrica 59, 1–24 (1991)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Crouzeix, J.P.: Conditions for convexity of quasiconvex functions. Math. Oper. Res. 5, 120–125 (1980)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Dalal, A.: Strict concavity with homogeneity and decreasing returns to scale. Atl. Econ. J. 28, 381–382 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Ewerhart, C.: Regular type distributions in mechanism design and \( \rho \)-concavity. Econ. Theory 53, 591–603 (2013)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  10. Hardy, G.H., Littlewood, J.E., Pólya, G.: Inequalities. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (1952)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  11. Jehle, G.A., Reny, P.J.: Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Prentice Hall, London (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  12. Kannai, Y.: Concavifiability and constructions of concave utility functions. J. Math. Econ. 4, 1–56 (1977)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Kennington, A.U.: Power concavity and boundary value problems. Indiana Univ. Math. J. 34, 687–704 (1985)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Martos, B.: Nemlineáris Programozási Módszerek Hatóköre. (Title in English: The Scope of the Methods of Nonlinear Programming). A Magyar Tudományos Akadémia Közgazdaságtudományi Intézétének Közleményei, MTA, Budapest (In Hungarian) (1966)

  15. Prada, J.P.: A note on concavity, homogeneity and nonincreasing returns to scale. Econ. Bull. 31, 100–105 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  16. Roeger, W.: Can imperfect competition explain the difference between primal and dual productivity measures? Estimates for U.S. manufacturing. J. Political Econ. 103, 316–330 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Rotem, L.: A sharp Blaschke-Santaló inequality for \(\alpha \)-concave functions. Geom. Dedicata 172, 217–228 (2014)

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  18. Simon, C.P., Blume, L.: Mathematics for Economists. W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., New York (1994)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Per Hjertstrand.

Additional information

Communicated by Juan-Enrique Martinez Legaz.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I would like to thank two reviewers for comments that greatly improved the paper, Magnus Henrekson and Gunnar Rosenqvist for encouragement, and Torsten Sö derbergs stiftelse for funding.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hjertstrand, P. On the Curvature of Homogeneous Functions. J Optim Theory Appl 198, 215–223 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-023-02249-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10957-023-02249-6

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation