Skip to main content
Log in

A robust behavioral portfolio selection: model with investor attitudes and biases

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Operational Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study develops a behavioral portfolio selection model that uses a robust estimator for expected returns in order to produce portfolios with less need to change over consecutive periods. We also consider investor attitudes toward risk through spectral risk measure as well as investor expectations on future returns by means of the Black–Litterman model, and finally, our model includes a varying risk aversion depending on investor behavioral biases and his latest realized return. In order to evaluate the proposed model and make comparisons possible, we conducted a survey on investor biases and attitudes along with market data of Tehran Stock Exchange. The results reveal that although our model is not mean–variance efficient, it recommends portfolios that are robust, well diversified, and have less utility loss compared to a famous behavioral portfolio model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The argument on subadditivity can refer to assets as well. Nevertheless, this argument for assets has been studied thoroughly in conventional finance. Hence, we propose no contribution on that. However, as mental accounts are an exclusive feature of behavioral portfolio models, we discuss the subadditivity argument on them.

  2. It should be mentioned that finding investors with basic investment knowledge and willingness to participate in academic surveys is difficult in TSE, therefore, we tried to keep as much respondents as possible in the final calculations by holding meetings in person with at most three of them in each session; each meeting took about 45 min–1 h, which means we had about 115 hours in meetings from January to August of 2015.

References

  • Acerbi C (2001) Risk aversion and coherent risk measures: a spectral representation theorem. arXiv preprint arXiv:cond-mat/0107190

  • Acerbi C (2002) Spectral measures of risk: a coherent representation of subjective risk aversion. J Bank Financ 26:1505–1518

    Google Scholar 

  • Adam A, Houkari M, Laurent J (2008) Spectral risk measures and portfolio selection. J Bank Financ 32:1870–1882

    Google Scholar 

  • Albadvi A, Chaharsooghi SK, Esfahanipour A (2007) Decision making in stock trading: an application of PROMETHEE. Eur J Oper Res 177(2):673–683

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander GJ, Baptista AM (2002) Economic implications of using a mean-VaR model for portfolio selection: a comparison with mean–variance analysis. J Econ Dyn Control 26:1159–1193

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander GJ, Baptista AM (2004) A comparison of VaR and CVaR constraints on portfolio selection with the mean–variance model. Manag Sci 50(9):1261–1273

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander GJ, Baptista AM (2011) Portfolio selection with mental accounts and delegation. J Bank Financ 35:2637–2656

    Google Scholar 

  • Alexander GJ, Baptista AM, Yan S (2015) Portfolio selection with mental accounts and estimation risk. J Empir Financ 41:161–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Amenc N, Le Sourd V (2005) Portfolio theory and performance analysis. Wiley, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Artzner P et al (1999) Coherent measures of risk. Math Financ 9(3):203–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Baptista AM (2012) Portfolio selection with mental accounts and background risk. J Bank Financ 36(4):968–980

    Google Scholar 

  • Berkelaar AB, Kouwenberg R, Post T (2004) Optimal portfolio choice under loss aversion. Rev Econ Stat 86(4):937–987

    Google Scholar 

  • Bilbao-Terol A et al (2015) Multi-criteria decision making for choosing socially responsible investment within a behavioral portfolio theory framework: a new way of investing into a crisis. Ann Oper Res 247:549–580

    Google Scholar 

  • Björk T, Murgoci A, Zhou X (2014) mean–variance portfolio optimization with state dependent risk aversion. Math Financ 24(1):1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Litterman R (1991) Asset allocation: combining investor views with market equilibrium. J Fixed Income 1(2):7–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandt M, Wang K (2003) Time-varying risk aversion and unexpected inflation. J Monet Econ 50:1457–1498

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunel JLP (2011) Goal-based wealth management in practice. J Wealth Manag 14(3):17–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier M, Nagel S (2008) Do wealth fluctuations generate time-varying risk aversion? Micro-evidence on individuals’ asset allocation (digest summary). Am Econ Rev 98(3):713–736

    Google Scholar 

  • Canner N, Mankiw N, Weil D (1997) An asset allocation puzzle. Am Econ Rev 87:181–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen G, Kim K (2007) Trading performance, disposition effect, overconfidence, representativeness bias, and experience of emerging market investors. J Behav Decis Mak 20(4):425–451

    Google Scholar 

  • Choueifaty Y, Coignard Y (2008) Toward maximum diversification. J Portf Manag 35(1):40–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Choueifaty Y, Froidure T, Reynier J (2013) Properties of the most diversified portfolio. J Invest Strateg 2(2):49–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Cillo A, Delquié P (2014) Mean-risk analysis with enhanced behavioral content. Eur J Oper Res 239:764–775

    Google Scholar 

  • Cronbach L (1951) Coefficient alpha and the internal structure of tests. Psychometrika 16:297–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Das S, Statman M (2009) Beyond mean–variance: portfolios with derivatives and non-normal returns in mental accounts. Available at SSRN 1782309

  • Das S, Statman M (2013) Options and structured products in behavioral portfolios. J Econ Dyn Control 37(1):137–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Das S et al (2010) Portfolio optimization with mental accounts. J Financ Quant Anal 45(2):311–334

    Google Scholar 

  • De Giorgi EG (2009) Goal-based investing with cumulative prospect theory and satisficing behavior. Department of Economics, University of St. Gallen, St. Gallen

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd K, Cotter J (2007) Exponential spectral risk measures. Available at SSRN. https://ssrn.com/abstract=998456

  • Dowd K, Cotter J, Sorwar G (2008) Spectral risk measures: properties and limitations. J Financ Serv Res 34(1):61–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Esfahanipour A, Goodarzi M, Jahanbin R (2016) Analysis and forecasting of IPO underpricing. Neural Comput Appl 27(3):651–658

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabozzi FJ et al (2007a) Robust portfolio optimization and management. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabozzi FJ et al (2007b) Robust portfolio optimization. J Portf Manag 33(3):40–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Fabozzi FJ, Huang D, Zhou G (2010) Robust portfolios: contributions from operations research and finance. Ann Oper Res 176:191–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Fellner G (2009) Illusion of control as a source of poor diversification: experimental evidence. J Behav Financ 10(1):55–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher K, Statman M (1997) The mean: variance-optimization puzzle: security portfolios and food portfolios. Financ Anal J 53(4):41–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Fragkiskos A (2014) What is portfolio diversification? Altern Invest Anal Rev. Available at SSRN. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2331475, pp 8–18

  • Garbade K (1986) Assessing risk and capital adequacy for Treasury securities. ln: Topics in money and securities markets. Bankers Trust, New York

  • Grable J, Lytton R, O’neill B (2006) Risk tolerance, projection bias, vividness, and equity prices. J Invest 15(2):68–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Grootveld H, Hallerbach WG (2004) Upgrading value-at-risk from diagnostic metric to decision variable: a wise thing to do? In: Szegö G (ed) Risk measures for the 21st century. Wiley, New York, pp 33–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Paiella M (2008) Risk aversion, wealth, and background risk. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(6):1109–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Halek M, Eisenhauer J (2001) Demography of risk aversion. J Risk Insur 68(1):1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Holt C, Laury S (2002) Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am Econ Rev 92(5):1644–1655

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull JC (2015) Risk management and financial institutions, 4th edn. Prentice Hall, Hoboken

  • Jorion P (2007) Value at risk: the new benchmark for managing financial risk, 3rd edn. New York

  • Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47(2):263–291

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalyvas L, Dritsakis N, Gross C (1996) Selecting value-at-risk methods according to their hidden characteristics. Oper Res Int J 4(2):167–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Krokhmal P, Palmquist J, Uryasev S (2002) Portfolio optimization with conditional value-at-risk objective and constraints. J Risk 4(2):1–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Kühberger A (1998) The influence of framing on risky decisions: a meta-analysis. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 75(1):23–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Leavens DH (1945) Diversification of investments. Trusts Estates 80(5):469–473

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu J et al (2015) Robust multi-period portfolio model based on prospect theory and ALMV-PSO algorithm. Expert Syst Appl 42:7252–7262

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Financ 7(1):77–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Momen O, Esfahanipour A, Seifi A (2016) Revised mental accounting: a behavioral portfolio selection. In: 12th international conference on industrial engineering (ICIE 2016). January 25–26, Tehran, Iran

  • Momen O, Esfahanipour A, Seifi A (2017) Prescriptive portfolio selection: a compromise between fast and slow thinking. Qual Res Fnanc Mark 9(2):98–116. doi: 10.1108/QRFM-11-2016-0044

    Google Scholar 

  • Morin R, Suarez A (1983) Risk aversion revisited. J Financ 38(4):1201–1216

    Google Scholar 

  • Mousavi S, Esfahanipour A, Zarandi MHF (2014) A novel approach to dynamic portfolio trading system using multitree genetic programming. Knowl Based Syst 66:68–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Nevins D (2004) Goals-based investing: integrating traditional and behavioral finance. J Wealth Manag 6(4):8–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Palczewski A (2016) Black–Litterman model for continuous distributions. Available at SSRN. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2744621, pp 1–33

  • Pan CH, Statman M (2012) Questionnaires of risk tolerance, regret, overconfidence, and other investor propensities. J Invest Consult 13(1):54–63

    Google Scholar 

  • Pompian MM (2006) Behavioral finance and wealth management. How to build optimal portfolios that account for investor biases. Wiley, New Jersey

  • Rockafellar RT, Uryasev S (2000) Optimization of conditional value-at-risk. J Risk 2:21–41

    Google Scholar 

  • Roszkowski M, Snelbecker G (1990) Effects of “framing” on measures of risk tolerance: financial planners are not immune. J Behav Econ 19(3):237–246

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahm CR (2012) How much does risk tolerance change? Q J Financ 2(4):1250020-1–1250020-38

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharma S (1996) Applied multivariate techniques. Wiley, New York

  • Sharpe WF (1966) Mutual fund performance. J Bus 39(1):119–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaw K (1996) An empirical analysis of risk aversion and income growth. J Labor Econ 14(4):626–653

    Google Scholar 

  • Shefrin H, Statman M (2000) Behavioral portfolio theory. J Financ Quant Anal 35(2):127–151

    Google Scholar 

  • Siebenmorgen N, Weber M (2003) A behavioral model for asset allocation. Financ Mark Portf Manag 17(1):15–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva A Da (2009) The Black–Litterman model for active portfolio management. J Portf Manag 35(2):61–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Sjöberg L, Engelberg E (2009) Attitudes to economic risk taking, sensation seeking and values of business students specializing in finance. J Behav Financ 10(1):33–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Statman M, Thorley S, Vorkink K (2006) Investor overconfidence and trading volume. Rev Financ Stud 19(4):1531–1565

    Google Scholar 

  • Treynor JL (1965) How to rate management of investment funds. Harvard Bus Rev 43(1):63–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Vissing-Jorgensen A (2003) Perspectives on behavioral finance: does“ irrationality” disappear with wealth? Evidence from expectations and actions. NBER Macroecon Annu 18:139–194

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Akbar Esfahanipour.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (XLSX 175 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Momen, O., Esfahanipour, A. & Seifi, A. A robust behavioral portfolio selection: model with investor attitudes and biases. Oper Res Int J 20, 427–446 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12351-017-0330-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12351-017-0330-9

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification

Navigation