Skip to main content
Log in

On a Dynamic Model of Cooperative and Noncooperative R and D in Oligopoly with Spillovers

  • Published:
Dynamic Games and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We developed a dynamic model of oligopoly in which firms’ R and D investments accumulate as R and D capital and have spillover effects. We showed that there exists a symmetric stable open-loop Nash equilibrium for each of the differential games under noncooperative R and D and cooperative R and D. We then showed that for small spillovers, each firm’s R and D investments are larger under R and D competition than under R and D cooperation. We further demonstrated that, in the limit, when the discount rate goes to zero, the stability condition for our dynamic game approaches the stability condition for the static two-stage game in d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (Am Econ Rev 78:1133–1137, 1988). However, we also showed that at the Markov perfect equilibrium, cooperative R and D investments are larger than noncooperative investments for all possible values of spillovers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See also Bernstein and Nadiri [5] and Jaffe [17].

  2. See also Reinganum [25].

  3. For early work on the theory of differential games, see Starr and Ho [27]. See also Basar and Olsder [4], Dockner et al. [13], and Kamien and Schwartz [19] for a full account of differential games.

  4. For the R and D investment level to be positive, \(9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma -2\alpha ^2(2-\beta )(1+\beta )\) must be positive. In our model, if \(\alpha \) is small or \(\gamma \) is large, or both, then the value of the depreciation rate that satisfies this condition can be quite large for any \(\beta \). I thank a referee for raising this point. See also footnote 5 below.

  5. In an empirical work on the rate of depreciation for knowledge capital, Pakes and Schankerman [21] argued that one needs to distinguish between physical assets and knowledge capital, and they obtained an estimate for the rate of depreciation of 0.25.

  6. In Henriques [16], the stability condition is given as \(\beta >\textstyle {3 \over 2}-\sqrt{\textstyle {7 \over 2}} \). The correct stability condition, however, is \(\beta >\textstyle {{3-\sqrt{7} } \over 2}\).

  7. Depending on parameter values, there might exist boundary solutions (see Remarks 1 and 2).

References

  1. Amir R (2000) Modelling imperfectly appropriable R&D via spillovers. Int J Ind Organ 18:1013–1032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Amir R, Evstigneev I, Wooders J (2003) Noncooperative versus cooperative R&D with endogenous spillover rates. Games Econ Behav 42:183–207

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Amir R, Jin J, Troege M (2008) On additive spillovers and returns to scale in R&D. Int J Ind Organ 26:695–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Basar T, Olsder B (1982) Dynamic noncooperative game theory. Academic Press, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Bernstein J, Nadiri M (1989) Research and development and intra-industry spillovers: an empirical application of dynamic duality. Rev Econ Stud 56:249–269

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Cassiman B, Veugelers R (2002) R & D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium. Am Econ Rev 92:1169–1184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Cellini R, Lambertini L (1998) A dynamic model of differentiated oligopoly with capital accumulation. J Econ Theory 83:145–155

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Cellini R, Lambertini L (2008) Weak and strong time consistency in a differential oligopoly game with capital accumulation. J Optim Theory Appl 138:17–26

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  9. Cellini R, Lambertini L (2009) Dynamic R&D with spillovers: competition vs cooperation. J Econ Dyn Control 33:568–582

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  10. Cohen W and Levin R (1989) Innovations and market Structure, Ch. 25 in Schmalensee R and Willig R (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, Vol. II, Elsevier, Amsterdam

  11. d’Aspremont C, Jacquemin A (1988) Cooperative and noncooperative R and D in duopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 78:1133–1137

    Google Scholar 

  12. De Bondt R, Slaets P, Cassiman B (1992) The degree of spillovers and the number of rivals for maximum effective R & D. Int J Ind Organ 10:35–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Dockner E, Jorgensen S, Long NV, Sorger G (2000) Differential games in economics and management science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  14. Hinloopen J (2000) Strategic R&D cooperatives. Res Econ 54:153–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Hinloopen J (2003) R&D efficiency gains due to cooperation. J Econ 80:107–125

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Henriques I (1990) Cooperative and noncooperative R and D in duopoly with spillovers: comment. Am Econ Rev 80:638–640

    Google Scholar 

  17. Jaffe A (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R & D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. Am Econ Rev 76:984–1001

    Google Scholar 

  18. Kamien M, Schwartz N (1980) Market structure and innovation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  19. Kamien M, Schwartz N (1991) Dynamic optimization. Elsevier, North Holland, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  20. Kamien M, Muller E, Zang I (1992) Research joint ventures and R & D cartels. Am Econ Rev 82:1293–1306

    Google Scholar 

  21. Pakes A and Schankerman M (1979) The rate of obsolescence of knowledge, research gestation lags and the private return to research resources, NBER Working Paper 346

  22. Petit M, Tolwinski B (1999) R&D cooperation or competition. Eur Econ Rev 43:185–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Reinganum J (1981) Dynamic games of innovation. J Econ Theory 25:11–21

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  24. Reinganum J (1982) A dynamic game for R and D: patent protection and competitive behavior. Econometrica 50:671–688

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  25. Reinganum J (1989) Timing of innovations: research, development, and diffusion, Ch. 14 in Schmalensee R and Willig R (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol I, Elsevier, Amsterdam

  26. Reynolds S (1987) Capacity investment, preemption, commitment in an infinite horizon model. Int Econ Rev 28:69–88

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  27. Starr AW, Ho YC (1969) Nonzero-sum differential games. J Optim Theory Appl 3:184–206

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  28. Suzumura K (1992) Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in an oligopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 82:1307–1320

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank the editor Luca Lambertini and two anonymous referees for insightful comments and helpful suggestions. I am grateful to Jim Y. Jin for his helpful comments and conversations. I would also like to thank Mihkel Tombak for valuable comments on an earlier version of the paper. The usual disclaimer applies. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from Nihon University.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shinji Kobayashi.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 5

Proof

Let \(V^i(y_i ,y_j )\) be the value function for firm \(i\). Feedback Nash equilibrium strategies must satisfy a system of Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations, \(\forall i\),

$$\begin{aligned} rV^i(y_i ,y_j )&= \mathop {\max }\limits _{x_i } \left\{ \pi _i (c_i ,\,c_j )-\frac{\gamma }{2}x_i^2 +\frac{\partial V^i(y_i ,y_j )}{\partial y_i }(x_i +\beta x_j -\delta y_i )\right. \nonumber \\&\qquad \quad \quad +\left. \frac{\partial V^i(y_i ,y_j )}{\partial y_j }(x_j +\beta x_i -\delta y_j ) \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(16)

Assuming symmetric strategies of the firms, we can set \(V^i(y_i ,y_j)=V(y_i ,y_j )\).

We may now suppose the value function takes the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} V(y_1 ,y_2 )=J+K_1 y_1 +\frac{1}{2}L_1 y_1 ^2+K_2 y_2 +\frac{1}{2}L_2 y_2 ^2+My_1 y_2 . \end{aligned}$$

Solving the maximization of the right-hand side of Eq. (16) yields

$$\begin{aligned} x_i^*=\left( {\frac{1}{\gamma }}\right) \left( {\frac{\partial V^i(y_i ,y_j )}{\partial y_i }+\frac{\partial V^i(y_i ,y_j )}{\partial y_j }\beta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(17)

Imposing symmetry, \(K_1 =K_2 =K,\;L_1 =L_2 =L\) and \(y_1 =y_2 =y\), we have

$$\begin{aligned} V(y_1 ,y_2 )=J+Ky+(L+M)y^2. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} x_i^*=\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )}{\gamma }}\right) ( {K+Gy}),\text{ where }\,\,G\equiv L+M. \end{aligned}$$
(18)

Substituting Eqs. (17) and (18) into Eq. (16) results in

$$\begin{aligned} r\left[ {J+2Ky+Gy^2} \right]&= \frac{(a-c)^2}{9}-\left( {\frac{\gamma }{2}}\right) \left( {\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )}{\gamma }}\right) ( {K+Gy})}\right) ^2\\&\quad +( {K+Gy})\left[ {2( {K+Gy})\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )^2}{\gamma }}\right) -2\delta y} \right] \end{aligned}$$

This equation must hold for any \(y\), and it follows that we have

$$\begin{aligned} rG&= \frac{\alpha ^2}{9}+\frac{3(1+\beta )^2}{2\gamma }G^2-2\delta G,\\ 2rK&= \frac{2\alpha (a-\bar{c})}{9}+\frac{3(1+\beta )^2KG}{\gamma }-2\delta K, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} rJ=\frac{(a-\bar{c})^2}{9}-\frac{3(1+\beta )^2K^2}{2\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$

From these equations, we have

$$\begin{aligned} G^*&= \frac{( {r+2\delta })\pm \sqrt{( {r+2\delta })^2-\frac{2\alpha ^2(1+\beta )^2}{3\gamma ^2}} }{\frac{3(1+\beta )^2}{\gamma ^2}},\\ K^*&= \frac{2\alpha (a-\bar{c})}{9( {2(r+\delta )-\frac{3(1+\beta )^2}{\gamma ^2}G^*})}, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} J^{*} =\frac{1}{r}\left[ {\frac{(a-\bar{c})^2}{9}}-{\frac{3(1+\beta )^2 K^{*2}}{2\gamma }} \right] . \end{aligned}$$

To ensure that \(x^*\ge 0\) for any \(y\), we must have \(K^*\ge 0\). Thus, we take a root

$$\begin{aligned} G^*=\frac{( {r+2\delta })-\sqrt{( {r+2\delta })^2-\frac{2\alpha ^2(1+\beta )^2}{3\gamma ^2}} }{\frac{3(1+\beta )^2}{\gamma ^2}}. \end{aligned}$$

Next, we seek a stability condition for the Markov perfect equilibrium. Substituting Eq. (18) into Eq. (2) yields

$$\begin{aligned} \dot{y}-\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )^2G}{\gamma }-\delta }\right) y-\frac{(1+\beta )^2K}{\gamma }=0. \end{aligned}$$
(19)

The complete solution to Eq. (19) is

$$\begin{aligned} y(t)&= \tilde{y}+(y^0-\tilde{y})e^{-\left( {\delta -\frac{(1+\beta )^2G^*}{\gamma }}\right) t},\\ \text{ where }\,\,\tilde{y}&= \frac{\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )^2K^*}{\gamma }}\right) }{\left( {\frac{(1+\beta )^2G^*}{\gamma }-\delta }\right) }. \end{aligned}$$

For this state trajectory to be asymptotically stable, we must have \(\delta >\frac{(1+\beta )^2G^*}{\gamma }.\) \(\square \)

Appendix 2: Proof of Proposition 8

The current-value Hamiltonian in this case is given by

$$\begin{aligned} H_i =\pi _i (c_i ,\,c_j )-\frac{1}{2}x_i^2 +\lambda _i (x_i +\beta _j x_j -\delta y_i )+\mu _i (x_j +\beta _i x_i -\delta y_j ),\;\,i,\,j=1,\,2,\,\;i\ne j. \end{aligned}$$

The necessary conditions for an open-loop Nash equilibrium are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial H_i }{\partial x_i }&= -x_i +\lambda _i +\beta _i \mu _i =0, \\ \dot{\lambda }_i&= r\lambda _i -\frac{\partial H_i }{\partial y_i } \\&= (r+\delta )\lambda _i -\frac{4( {a-2(\bar{c}_i -y_i )+(\bar{c}_j -y_j )})}{9},\, \\ \dot{\mu }_i&= r\mu _i -\frac{\partial H_i }{\partial y_j } \\&= (r+\delta )\mu _i +\frac{2( {a-2(\bar{c}_i -y_i )+(\bar{c}_j -y_j )})}{9},\, \\&\quad \mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\rightarrow \infty } \hbox {e}^{-rt}\lambda _i = 0,\, \\ \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\rightarrow \infty } \hbox {e}^{-rt}\mu _i = 0. \\ \end{aligned}$$

At the steady state, we have \(\dot{\lambda }_i =0, \quad \dot{\mu }_i =0,\) \(\dot{y}_i =0,\) and \(\dot{y}_j =0.\)

Thus, we have

$$\begin{aligned} (r+\delta )\lambda _i&= \frac{4( {a-2(\bar{c}_i -y_i )+(\bar{c}_j -y_j )})}{9},\\ (r+\delta )\mu _i&= -\frac{2( {a-2(\bar{c}_i -y_i )+(\bar{c}_j -y_j )})}{9},\\ x_i&= \frac{2(2-\beta _i )}{9(r+\delta )}( {a-2(\bar{c}_i -y_i )+(\bar{c}_j-y_j )}),\\ y_i&= \frac{x_i +\beta _j x_j }{\delta }, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} y_j =\frac{x_j +\beta _i x_i }{\delta }. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that we get

$$\begin{aligned} x_i^*=\frac{2(a-\bar{c})E_i \delta ( {9\delta (r+\delta )-2E_j ^2+2E_j F_j })}{( {9\delta (r+\delta )-2E_i ^2})\,( {9\delta (r+\delta )-2E_j ^2})-4E_i F_i E_j F_j }, \end{aligned}$$

where \(E_i \equiv 2-\beta _i\, \mathrm{and}\, F_i \equiv 2-\beta _i ,\,\;i,\,j=1,\,2,\,\;i\ne j.\)

Suppose that firm \(i\) has a smaller R and D spillover rate than firm \(j\), that is, \(\beta _i >\beta _j.\)

Since \(E_i -E_j <0\) and \(F_j -F_i <0\), we have \(9\delta (r+\delta )(E_i -E_j )+2E_i E_j ( {(E_i -E_j )+(F_j -F_i )})<0.\)

Thus, \(x_i <x_j \). \(\square \)

1.1 The Case of R and D Cooperation with Asymmetric Spillovers

The current-value Hamiltonian in this case is given by \(H_i^C =\pi _i (c_i ,\,c_j )+\pi _j (c_i ,\,c_j )-\frac{1}{2}x_i^2 -\frac{1}{2}x_j^2 +\lambda _i (x_i +\beta _j x_j -\delta y_i )+\mu _i (x_j +\beta _i x_i -\delta y_j ),\;\,i,\,j=1,\,2,\,\;i\ne j.\) Then, following the procedure in the proof of Proposition 2, we have the desired results.

Appendix 3: Proof of Proposition 9

1.1 The Case of R and D Competition

The current-value Hamiltonian in this case is given by

$$\begin{aligned} H_i =\pi _i -\frac{1}{2}x_i^2 +\mathop \sum \limits _{k=1}^n \lambda _i^k \left( x_k +\beta \mathop \sum \limits _{j\in N_{-k} } x_j -\delta y_k\right) . \end{aligned}$$

The necessary conditions for an open-loop Nash equilibrium are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial H_i }{\partial x_i }=&-x_i +\lambda _i^i +\beta \mathop \sum \limits _{j\in N_{-i} } \lambda _i^j =0, \\ \dot{\lambda }_i^i =&r\lambda _i^i -\frac{\partial H_i }{\partial y_i }\\ =&(r+\delta )\lambda _i^i -\frac{\partial \pi _i }{\partial y_i },\, \\ \dot{\lambda }_i^j =&r\lambda _i^j -\frac{\partial H_i }{\partial y_j }\\ =&(r+\delta )\lambda _i^j -\frac{\partial \pi _i }{\partial y_j }\quad \hbox {for every } \,j, \\ \mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\rightarrow \infty } \hbox {e}^{-rt}\lambda _{i}^{i} =&0,\, \\&and \\ \mathop {\lim }\limits _{t\rightarrow \infty } \hbox {e}^{-rt}\lambda _i^j =&0\quad \hbox {for every } \,j, \\ \end{aligned}$$

where

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _i }{\partial y_i }=\frac{2n\left( {a-nc_i +\mathop \sum \nolimits _{j\in N_{-i} } c_j }\right) }{(n+1)^2} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _i }{\partial y_j }=-\frac{2\left( {a-nc_i +\mathop \sum \nolimits _{j\in N_{-i} } c_j }\right) }{(n+1)^2}. \end{aligned}$$

At the steady state, we have \(\dot{\lambda }_i^i =0, \quad \dot{\lambda }_i^j =0\) for every \(j\), and \(\dot{y}_i =0\).

For a symmetric equilibrium, we get

$$\begin{aligned} y&= \frac{( {1+(n-1)\beta })\,x}{\delta },\\ (r+\delta )\lambda&= \frac{2n\left( {a-nc_i +\mathop \sum \nolimits _{j\in N_{-i} } c_j }\right) }{(n+1)^2}, \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} (r+\delta )\lambda ^j=-\frac{2\left( {a-nc_i +\mathop \sum \nolimits _{j\in N_{-i} } c_j }\right) }{(n+1)^2}\quad \hbox { for every j }. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that we have the following equilibrium values:

$$\begin{aligned} x^{N*}=\frac{2\delta ( {n-(n-1)\beta })(a-\bar{c})}{(n+1)^2\delta (r+\delta )-2( {n-(n-1)\beta })\,( {1+(n-1)\beta })} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} y^{N*}=\frac{2( {n-(n-1)\beta })\,( {1+(n-1)\beta })(a-\bar{c})}{(n+1)^2\delta (r+\delta )-2( {n-(n-1)\beta })\,( {1+(n-1)\beta })}. \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

1.2 The Case of R and D Cooperation

The current-value Hamiltonian in this case is

$$\begin{aligned} \mathop \sum \limits _{i=1}^2 \left[ {\pi _i (c_i ,\,c_j )-\frac{\gamma }{2}x_i^2 (t)} \right] +\mathop \sum \limits _{k=1}^n \lambda _i^k (x_k +\beta \mathop \sum \limits _{j\in N_{-k} } x_j -\delta y_k ). \end{aligned}$$

The rest of the analysis is similar to the proof of Proposition 3.

Thus, we can show \(x^{C*}=\frac{2\delta ( {1+(n-1)\beta })(a-\bar{c})}{(n+1)^2\delta (r+\delta )-2\,( {1+(n-1)\beta })^2}\).

Appendix 4: Proof of Proposition 12

At the open-loop Nash equilibrium, the R and D level \(x_\theta ^C \) under R and D cooperation is given by

$$\begin{aligned} x_\theta ^C =\frac{2\alpha \delta (1+\theta )(a-\bar{c})}{9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma -2\alpha ^2(1+\theta )^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} x^N-x_\theta ^C =\frac{2\alpha \delta (2-\beta )(a-\bar{c})}{9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma -2\alpha ^2(2-\beta )(1+\beta )}-\frac{2\alpha \delta (1+\theta )(a-\bar{c})}{9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma -2\alpha ^2(1+\theta )^2}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence,

$$\begin{aligned} x^N\mathop =\limits _<^> x_\theta ^C \Leftrightarrow 9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma [1-(\beta +\theta )]-2\alpha ^2(1+\theta )(2-\beta )(\theta -\beta )\mathop =\limits _<^> 0. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, if \(\frac{1}{2}<\beta \le \theta \), then \(1-(\beta +\theta )<0\). Thus, \(x^N<x_\theta ^C \).

If \(\beta \le \theta <\frac{1}{2}\), then \(1-(\beta +\theta )>0\). Thus,

$$\begin{aligned} x^N\mathop =\limits _<^> x_\theta ^C \Leftrightarrow 9\delta (r+\delta )\gamma \mathop =\limits _<^> \frac{2\alpha ^2(1+\theta )(2-\beta )(\theta -\beta )}{1-(\beta +\theta )} \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kobayashi, S. On a Dynamic Model of Cooperative and Noncooperative R and D in Oligopoly with Spillovers. Dyn Games Appl 5, 599–619 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-014-0117-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-014-0117-z

Keywords

Navigation