Abstract
This paper revisits Strulik’s model of growth with insecure property rights. In this model, different social groups devote some effort to control a share of the capital stock. We show that a slight variation in the modeling of strategic interactions results in the coexistence of savings and efforts to control a share of the capital stock. We also study the effects of a change in the number of social groups on growth. We also show that an increase in social fractionalization may lead to less effort devoted to control capital and to a higher growth rate.

Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
In the literature on the depletion of common resources, it is possible to accumulate some privately and safely held capital, but there is no costly competition to access the resources.
They also write that: “ethnicity is possibly a marker for organizing similar individuals along opposing lines.”
We do not focus on perpetual growth. We could obtain endogenous growth by assuming a Romer [13] like technology.
Strulik shows that conflict and growth can coexist in an economy populated by two groups of unequal sizes. Here, we do not need to assume a difference in size to obtain the coexistence result.
Physical feasibility implies that \(\sum _{i=1}^{n} \phi (\tau ^i_{t}, \varvec{\tau }^{-i}_{t}) = 1\).
We thank a referee for noticing that Strulik’s production function, namely \(f(k,l) = kl\), is not a special case of our production function when \(\alpha = 1\). To obtain Strulik’s specification from a Cobb–Douglas function, we could set: \(y_t = (A_t k_t)^{\alpha }(B_t l_t)^{1-\alpha }\) where, following Frankel [5] and Romer [13], \(A_t = l_t\), and \(B_t = k_t\). Generally, it is assumed that the decision maker is unaware of the specifications of \(A_{t}\) and \(B_{t}\), except if he is a social planner. That a social group behaves as a social planner is not strictly impossible, but this is probably a strong assumption.
In “Appendix A,” we show that under our specific assumptions the values of the agents’ objectives involved in the feedback Nash are always well defined.
That the objective is well defined is established in Appendix.
The data are available in Feenstra et al. [4] available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt The capital stock is evaluated at constant 2011 national prices (in mil. 2011 US$).
Recall that Strulik uses a continuous time setting. We translate his modeling assumptions in a discrete time setting.
The crucial hypothesis in this theorem is an invertibility condition which is satisfied in our case since \((1-\delta )+\sum _{j=1}^{n} f_1^j \frac{g(\tau ^j_{t})}{\sum _{h=1}^{n} g(\tau ^h_{t})} \ne 0\). Moreover, it is clear that the multiplier \(\lambda _0 \) in the cited Theorem 2.2 is different from zero in our case, so we have set it equal to one.
In the following expression, \(f^j_{1}\) stands for \(f'_{1}\left( \frac{ g(\tau ^j_{t}) }{ \left( \sum _{h=1}^{n} g(\tau ^h_{t}) \right) } k_{t}, 1-\tau ^j_{t} \right) \).
The fractionalization index gives the probability that two people drawn at random from the society will belong to different groups [3]. That is, if \(n_{i}\) is the population share of group i, the fractionalization index is \( \sum _{i=1}^{m} n_i (1-n_i)\). Another measure of social fragmentation is the polarization index P introduced by Esteban and Ray [7], where \(P = \sum _{i=1}^m \sum _{j=1}^m n_i^2 n_j d_{ij}\), with \(d_{ij}\) being the intergroup perceived distance. The R index is a special case of the P index where \(d_{ij} = 1\) when \(i \not = j\) [9]. Theses indexes are briefly discussed in Ray and Esteban [12], Sect. 5.1. In our symmetric society, the fractionalization and the R indexes have the same value.
Moreover, recall that our setting slightly differs from Strulik’s: we use a Cobb–Douglas function, whereas Strulik uses the production function \(A k_{i} (1-\tau ^{i})\), and we consider a general g(.) function, whereas Strulik concentrates on the case \(g(\tau ) = \alpha +\tau \) (Strulik, ibid, page footnote 3, however, indicates that most of his results can be obtained with more general contest success functions).
Our analysis has been cast in a neo-classical setting preventing perpetual growth. But we can recover our results (regarding predation time and savings) in a perpetual growth setting by assuming that \(y_t = (k_t)^{\alpha }(B_t l_t)^{1-\alpha }\) and that each social group takes \(B_t = k_{t}\) as given. Everything would be as if \(y_t = C_t k_t^{\alpha }l_t^{1-\alpha }\) (with \(C_t \equiv k_t^{1- \alpha }\)). In particular, the predation game would remain unchanged. Only the savings game would be different (although we could use the same methods to find the equilibrium savings). People would still save a part of individual production, but in equilibrium, production would be a linear function of capital.
References
Benhabib J, Rustichini A (1996) Social conflict and growth. J Econ Growth 1:125–142
Blot J, Hayek N (2014) Infinite-horizon optimal control in the discrete-time framework. Springer, New York
Bruk SI, Apenchenko VS (eds) (1964) Atlas narodov mira. Academy of Science, Moscow
Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn world Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–3182
Frankel M (1962) The production function in allocation and growth: a synthesis. Am Econ Rev 55(3):296–319
Gonzales FM (2012) The use of coercion in society: insecure property rights, conflicts and economic backwardess. In: Garfinkel MR, Skaperdas S (eds) Oxford handbook of the economics of peace and conflict
Joan E, Debraj R (1994) On the measurement of polarization. Econometrica 62:819–52
Lindner I, Strulik H (2008) Social fractionalization, endogenous predation norms, and economic development. Economica 75(298):244–58
Montalvo JG, Reynal-Querol M (2005) Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil war. Am Econ Rev 95:796–816
Ogilvie S, Carus AW (2014) Institutions and economic growth in historical perspective. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth, vol 2A, Chapter 8. Elsevie, Amsterdam, pp 403–513
Polachnek S, Sevastionava D (2012) Does conflict disrupt growth? Evidence of the relationship between political instability and national economic performance. J Int Trade Econ Dev Int Comp Rev 21(3):361–388
Ray D, Esteban J (2017) Conflict and development. Ann Rev Econ 9:263–93
Romer P (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Political Econ 94(5):1002–1037
Rouillon S (2017) Cooperative and noncooperative extraction in a common pool with habit formation. Dyn Games Appl 7(3):468-49
Stokey NL, Lucas RE, Prescott EC (1989) Recursive methods in economic dynamics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Strulik H (2008) Social composition, social conflict and economic development. Econ J 118:1145–1170
Tornell A, Lane PR (1999) The voracity effect. Am Econ Rev 89:22–46
Vahabi M (2015) The political economy of predation: manhunting and the economics of escape. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Vahabi M (2016) A positive theory of the predatory state. Publ Choice 168(3–4):153–175
Van Long N (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, Singapore
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
We thank two anonymous referees as well as the Editor, Georges Zaccour, for useful comments on a previous version of this paper. We also thank Susan Crettez for very helpful remarks on this version.
A Definition of the Objective
A Definition of the Objective
In this section, we check that the sum used to define the value function is meaningful. We recall that the value function \(V: \mathbb {R}^+ \rightarrow \mathbb {R} \cup \lbrace \infty \rbrace \) is defined by
where
and \(\psi = (1/n)^{\alpha }(1-\tau )^{1-\alpha }\).
It will be useful to bound all feasible sequences of capital stocks. To do this, observe that for all t
One can check that \(\bar{k}_{t} = n^{\frac{1-\alpha ^t}{1-\alpha }} k_{0}^{\alpha ^t}.\)
Now, observe that since \(\ln c_{t}\) is concave, for all positive \(\hat{c}\) and for all positive \(c_{t}\) one has
It follows that for all nonnegative \(c_{t}\), we have
where \(A = 1/\hat{c}\) and \(B = \max \lbrace 0, \ln \hat{c} -1 \rbrace \). Therefore, we have
Since \(\bar{k}_{t}^{\alpha }\) is a concave function, we also have for all positive \(\hat{k}\)
so that
where \(\gamma = \alpha \hat{k}^{\alpha -1}\) and \(\gamma ' = (1-\alpha ) \hat{k}^{\alpha }\).
Now, notice that
We thus have
Assuming \(n \beta \gamma <1\), we see that \(\lim _{T \rightarrow + \infty } \sum _{t=0}^T \beta ^t U^+(c_{t}) \) is well defined, and so is \(\lim _{T \rightarrow + \infty } \sum _{t=0}^T \beta ^t U(c_{t})\).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Crettez, B., Hayek, N. & Morhaim, L. Growth and Insecure Private Property of Capital. Dyn Games Appl 9, 1042–1060 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-00294-9
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-00294-9