Abstract
This paper characterizes the solution to differential games in the context of electoral competition between two political parties/politicians, in the presence of voters and a special interest group. The basic structure of the analytical model is similar to Lambertini (https://amsacta.unibo.it/4884/1/415.pdf, 2001, Dynamic games in economics. Springer, Berlin, pp 187–204, 2014), which is extended to model the involvement of a special interest group. Furthermore, voters not only vote but also care for the level of public good provision, while the interest group cares for the regulatory benefit in exchange for financial contribution for campaign expenditure. With a quadratic cost structure, we find that a closed-loop solution collapses to an open-loop equilibrium. Moreover, at the private optimum, the expenditure offered for public good provision, regulatory benefit rendered, voting support from voters, and financial contributions from special interest group received by any political party are always higher than at the social optimum. That is, political parties have the tendency to make excessive offers of expenditure on public good to grab a larger vote share to win the election. Consequently, voters vote retrospectively to the party that offers to overspend more. A higher private optimal regulatory benefit helps the political parties to receive higher financial contributions, which could be potentially used for election campaigns and indirectly contributes to enhance their vote share. The solutions to the control and state variables constitute steady-state saddle point equilibria at both private and social optima.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
The trio—Julius Caesar, Crassus, and Pompey—formed a group famously known as ‘the triumvirate,’ and they ruled the Roman Empire for many years. Crassus is also considered as one of the wealthiest in the world history in general, and Roman Empire in particular. In return, according to Plutarch, both Crassus and Pompey got tax breaks and land grants. In particular, Crassus accumulated a lot of wealth and power, a vast sum of 7,100 talents, had extensive real estate interests, and owned silver mines. He owned a huge number of slaves and had enormous wealth that he could fund his own army.
When the length of the electoral period is given (that is, the date of election is known), Nordhaus [44] relies on a discount factor, \(\mu \), which is positive, and calls it a decaying memory, where the recent pains are more painful than the past. Lambertini [37] also uses the discount factor \(\rho \) in the value function as negative and refers to the future date as more relevant than today, whereas for a given electoral period, Gavious and Mizrahi [22] work without any discount factor and state that if the date of election is sufficiently away, the party in power should invest the resources constantly.
Even if \(\rho \) exceeds \(\alpha _{2}\) and \(\beta _{2}\), \(\Delta (J)>0\)
If the Pontryagin-type necessary conditions for open-loop Nash equilibrium do not depend on the state variables, then the open loop Nash equilibrium, if it exists, is a degenerate feedback Nash equilibrium.
References
Austen-Smith D (1987) Interest groups, campaign contributions, and probabilistic voting. Public Choice 54(2):123–139
Basar T, Olsder G (1995) Dynamic noncooperative games. Academic Press, New York
Bennedsen M, Feldmann SE (2006) Informational lobbying and political contributions. J Public Econ 90(4):631–656
Bentley AF (1908) The process of government: a study of social pressures. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Bonomo M, Terra C (2010) Electoral cycles through lobbying. Econ Polit 22(3):446–470
Borooah V, Ploeg FVd (1983) Political aspects of the economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Bouton L, Conconi P, Pino F, Zanardi M (2014) Guns and votes (Technical Report). National Bureau of Economic Research
Bouton L, Conconi P, Pino FJ, Zanardi M (2013) The us senates failure to pass gun control legislation is the victory of an intense minority against an apathetic majority. LSE American Politics and Policy
Caplan B (2008) The myth of the rational voter: why democracies choose bad policies (New Edition). Princeton University Press, Princeton
Cellini R, Lambertini L (2007) A differential oligopoly game with differentiated goods and sticky prices. Eur J Oper Res 176(2):1131–1144
Chiang A (1992) Elements of dynamic optimization. McGraw-Hill, New York
Coate S (2004) Political competition with campaign contributions and informative advertising. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(5):772–804
Coughlin PJ, Mueller DC, Murrell P (1990a) A model of electoral competition with interest groups. Econ Lett 32(4):307–311
Denzau AT, Munger MC (1986) Legislators and interest groups: how unorganized interests get represented. Am Polit Sci Rev 80(01):89–106
Dockner E, Feichtinger G, Jørgensen S (1985) Tractable classes of nonzero-sum open-loop Nash differential games: theory and examples. J Optim Theory Appl 45(2):179–197
Epstein D, O’Halloran S (1995) A theory of strategic oversight: congress, lobbyists, and the bureaucracy. J Law Econ Org 11(2):227–255
Etzioni A (1985) Special interest groups versus constituency representation. Res Soc Mov Confl Change 8:171–195
Feichtinger G (1983) The Nash solution of an advertising differential game: generalization of a model by leitmann and schmitendorf. IEEE Trans Autom Control 28(11):1044–1048
Fershtman C (1987) Identification of classes of differential games for which the open loop is a degenerate feedback Nash equilibrium. J Optim Theory Appl 55(2):217–231
Fershtman C, Kamien MI (1990) Turnpike properties in a finite-horizon differential game: dynamic duopoly with sticky prices. Int Econ Rev 31(1):49–60
Fiorino N, Ricciuti R (2009) Interest groups and government spending in Italy, 1876–1913
Gavious A, Mizrahi S (2002) Maximizing political efficiency via electoral cycles: an optimal control model. Eur J Oper Res 141(1):186–199
Goldberg P, Maggi G (1999) Protection for sale: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 89(5):1135–55
Goss KA (2010) Disarmed: the missing movement for gun control in America. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Grossman GM, Helpman E (1994) Protection for sale. Am Econ Rev 84:833–50
Grossman GM, Helpman E (1995) Trade wars and trade talks. J Polit Econ 103:675–708
Grossman GM, Helpman E (1995) The politics of free trade agreements. Am Econ Rev 85:667–690
Grossman GM, Helpman E (1996) Electoral competition and special interest politics. Rev Econ Stud 63(2):265–286
Grossman GM, Helpman E (1999) Competing for endorsements. Am Econ Rev 89(3):501–524
Grossman GM, Helpman E (2001) Special interest politics. MIT Press, Cambridge
Huber J, Kirchler M (2013) Corporate campaign contributions and abnormal stock returns after presidential elections. Public Choice 156(1–2):285–307
Jørgensen S (1986) Sufficiency and game structure in Nash open-loop differential games. J Optim Theory Appl 50(1):189–193
Kapur D, Vaishnav M (2011) Quid pro quo: builders, politicians, and election finance in India. Center for Global Development (Working Paper No. 276). https://www.cgdev.org/sites/default/files/Kapur_Vaishnav_election_finance_India-FINAL-0313.pdf
Klompstra MB (1991) A nonzero-sum game with variable final time. In: Hämäläinen RP, Ehtamo HK (eds) Dynamic games in economic analysis. Lecture notes in control and information sciences, vol 157. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg, pp. 122–131
Kuttner R (ed) (1996) Ticking time bombs: the new conservative assaults on democracy. New Press, New York
Lambertini L (2001) Dynamic analysis of an electoral campaign. Retrieved from https://amsacta.unibo.it/4884/1/415.pdf. Accessed 16 Dec 2016
Lambertini L (2014) Dynamic analysis of an electoral campaign. In: Haunschmied J, Veliov VM, Wrzaczek S (eds) Dynamic games in economics, vol. 16. Springer, Berlin, pp 187–204
Leitmann G, Schmitendorf W (1978) Profit maximization through advertising: a nonzero sum differential game approach. IEEE Trans Autom Control 23(4):645–650
Lohmann S (1995) Information, access, and contributions: a signaling model of lobbying. Public Choice 85(3):267–284
Lohmann S (1998) An information rationale for the power of special interests. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(04):809–827
Magee CS (2007) Influence, elections, and the value of a vote in the us house of representatives. Econ Polit 19(3):289–315
Mehlmann A, Willing R (1983) On nonunique closed-loop Nash equilibria for a class of differential games with a unique and degenerated feedback solution. J Optim Theory Appl 41(3):463–472
Mitchell WC, Munger MC (1991) Economic models of interest groups: an introductory survey. Am J Polit Sci 35(2):512–546
Nordhaus WD (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42(2):169–190
Olson M (1974) The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press
Persson T (1998) Economic policy and special interest politics. Econ J 108(447):310–327
Potters J, Sloof R, Van Winden F (1997) Campaign expenditures, contributions and direct endorsements: the strategic use of information and money to influence voter behavior. Eur J Polit Econ 13(1):1–31
Potters J, Winden F (1992) Lobbying and asymmetric information. Public Choice 74(3):269–292
Prat A (2002) Campaign spending with office-seeking politicians, rational voters, and multiple lobbies. J Econ Theory 103(1):162–189
Sadiraj V, Tuinstra J, Van Winden F (2010) Identification of voters with interest groups improves the electoral chances of the challenger. Math Soc Sci 60(3):210–216
Schattschneider EE (1935) Politics, pressures and the tariff. Prentice-Hall, Inc., New York, p 301
Snyder JM, Ting MM (2008) Interest groups and the electoral control of politicians. J Public Econ 92(3):482–500
Stigler GJ (1975) The citizen and the state: essays on regulation, vol 720. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Truman DB (1962) The governmental process: political interests and public opinion. Alfred A. Knopf, New York
Wittman D (2007) Candidate quality, pressure group endorsements and the nature of political advertising. Eur J Polit Econ 23(2):360–378
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank Sugata Dasgupta, Amlan Gupta, Sonali Roy, Debabrata Pal, and two anonymous referees for detailed comments as well as the audience for their valuable comments at the Third International Conference on South Asian Economic Development—2017 at the South Asian University, February 23–24, 2017, New Delhi, and the Papers in Public Economics and Policy (PPEP)—2017 Conference at the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, March 23–24, 2017, New Delhi.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Manjhi, G., Mehra, M.K. A Dynamic Analysis of Special Interest Politics and Electoral Competition. Dyn Games Appl 9, 142–164 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-0241-2
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-018-0241-2
Keywords
- Electoral competition
- Interest group
- Political economy
- Regulatory benefit
- Financial contribution
- Differential games