Abstract
Altruism in social networks was traditionally considered based on user relationships and requirements. The capability of a user to help has seldom been taken into account while studying altruism. Also, to the best of our knowledge, no quantitative analysis has been made to determine the benefits of altruism. Here we quantitatively study the amount of altruism of users based on the help extended by users to each other and the benefits they reap because of being altruistic. Results indicate that a network in which 90 % users have capabilities that are above average contains 90 % altruistic users, while a network containing 50 % of users with above-average capabilities contains only 50 % altruistic users. Results also indicate that altruistic users (the good guys) reap more benefits than selfish users and free riders (i.e., finish first).




Similar content being viewed by others
References
Barnes JA (1969) Networks and political processes. In: Book chapter: social networks in urban situations. Manchester University Press, Manchester, pp 51–76
Brown WM, Consedie MS, Magai C (2005) Altruism relates to health in an ethnically diverse sample of older adults. J Gerontol Psychol Sci 60B(3):143–152
Byrne T (2010) How to use internal collaboration and social networking technology. http://www.inc.com/guides/2010/03/internal-collaboration-and-social-media-technology.html (Online)
Carnegie D (1937) How to win friends and influence people. Simon and Schuster, New York
Chumra T, Engel C (2010) At the mercy of the prisoner next door: using an experimental measure of selfishness as a criminological tool. Technical report #2010_27. Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods, Working Paper Series. http://ideas.repec.org/p/mpg/wpaper/2010_27.html (Online)
Engel C (2010) An experimental contribution to the theory of customary (international) law. Max Planck Institute for the Research on Collective Goods, Bonn (Preprint). http://www.coll.mpg.de/pdf_dat/2010_13online.pdf (Online)
Fowler JH, Cristakis NA (2010) Cooperative behavior cascades in human social networks. Nature 107(12):5334–5338
Gershaw AD (2012) Altruism and the holiday spirit. Homework Help. http://www.jiksha.com/social_studies/psychology/altruism.html (Online)
Gintis H (2000) Game theory evolving: a problem-centered introduction to modeling strategic behaviour. Princeton University, Princeton
Gotta M (2011) Mapping our friendships over time and space: the future of social network analysis. In: Perceptions on collaborative and social thinking. http://mikeg.typepad.com/perceptions/2011/02/interesting-study-worth-reading-long-range-food-for-thought-as-generational-shifts-change-the-nature-of-participation-in-the.html (Online)
Hoover JN (2007) Social networks: time waster or the next big thing in collaboration. Information Week. http://www.informationweek.com/news/global-cio/trends/showArticle.jhtml?articleID=201808149
Indexmundi (2009) Color coded world map: population below poverty line-World. http://www.indexmundi.com/map/?=v69 (Online)
Kraut RE, Egido C, Gallegher J (1990) Patterns on contact and communication in scientific research collaboration. In: Book chapter: intellectual teamwork: social and technological foundations of cooperative work. Laurence Elbaum, Hillside, pp 149–172
Kumpula JM, Onnela JP, Saramaki J, Kaski K, Kertesz J (2007) Emergence of communities in weighted networks. Phys Rev Lett 99:228701. doi:10.1103/PhysRevLett.99.228701
Leider S, Mbius MM, Rosenblat T, Do Q (2009) What do we expect from our friends? Technical report #2009.14, East Asian Bureau of Economic Research, microeconomics working papers. http://ideas.repec.org/p/eab/microe/2396.html (Online)
Levine DK (1998) Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments. Rev Econ Dyn 1(3):593–622
Ley M (2009) DBLP-some lessons learned. In: Proc., very large database endowment (VLDB’09)
McDonald DW (2003) Recommending collaboration with social networks: a comparative evaluation. In: Proc., ACM conf. on human factors in computing systems (CHI’2003)
Meyer CD (2010) Matrix theory and applied linear algebra, SIAM
Nandi TK, Rochelandet F (2008) The incentives for contributing digital contents over P2P networks: an empirical investigation. Rev Eco Res Copyr Issues 5(2):19–35
Newman MEJ, Park J (2003) Why social networks are different from other types of networks. Phys Rev E 68:036122. doi:10.1103/PhysRevE.68.036122
Nowak MA, Sigmund K (1998) Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nat Lett 393(11):573–577
Ntarmos N, Trantafillou P (2004) AESOP:altruism-endowed self-organizing peers. In: Proc., intl. conf. on databases, information systems and peer-to-peer computing (DBISP2P’04)
Okasha S (2005) Altruism, group selection and correlated interaction. Brit J Philos Sci 56(4):703–725
Sigmund K, Nowak MA (2001) Tides of tolerance. Nat News Rev 414(22):402–403
Slonim R, Garbarino E (2007) Increases in trust and altruism from partner selection. Springer J Exptl Econ 11(2):134–153
Sylwester K, Roberts G (2010) Cooperators benefit through reputation-based partner choice in economic games. Biol Lett 6(5):659–662
Vassilakis DK, Vassalos V (2007) Modelling real P2P networks: the effect of altruism. In: Proc., IEEE intl. conf. on peer-to-peer computing
Vassilakis DK, Vassalos V (2009) An analysis of peer-to-peer networks with altruistic peers. Springer J Peer-to-Peer Netw Appl 2(2):109–127
Wade N (2011) Supremacy of a social network. http://www.nytimes.com/2011/03/15/science/By15humans.html?_r=1&src=dayp (Online)
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix: Optimal \(h _{i}^{*}\) and \(e_{{ij}}^{*}\)
Appendix: Optimal \(h _{i}^{*}\) and \(e_{{ij}}^{*}\)
We present the details of the analysis in obtaining the expressions for \(h _{i}^{*}\) and \(e_{{ij}}^{*}\) in (11) and (12), respectively. The optimal \(h _{i}^{*}\) and \(e_{{ij}}^{*}\) are obtained by solving for \(\mathcal{H}\) in (7), i.e., by computing
Thus, \(\mathcal{H}\) can be obtained if the inverse of \(\mathcal{A}\) in (8) is computed. The following definitions from matrix theory will be used in the analysis to obtain \(\mathcal{A}^{-1}. \)
Definition 5
(Meyer 2010) A permutation matrix, \(\mathcal{P}_{n}\) is an n × n matrix whose entries are all 0’s and 1’s, such that every row and column has exactly one 1 in it.
Definition 6
An n × n permutation matrix, \(\mathbf{P}_{k}, \) is called the kth circulant matrix, if \(\mathbf{P}_{k}\) is obtained by k cyclic permutations of the rows of the n × n identity matrix, \(\mathbf{I}_{n}. \)
Lemma 1
(Meyer 2010)
-
1.
\(\mathbf{P}_{1}^{k}=\mathbf{P}_{k}.\)
-
2.
\(\mathbf{P}_1^{n}=\mathbf{I}_{n}.\)
-
3.
\(\mathbf{P}_k^{-1}=\mathbf{P}_{n-k}.\)
Let \(\mathbf{C}\) and \(\mathbf{D}^T\) be n 2 × n and n × n 2 matrices, respectively, defined as follows:
Then, \(\mathcal{A}\) in (8) can be written as \(\mathcal{A}=\mathbf{I}_{n^{2}}+\mathbf{C}\mathbf{D}^{\rm T}.\) Using the Sherman–Morrison–Woodbury formula (Meyer 2010), \(\mathcal{A}^{-1}\) can be determined as
From (20), and (3) in Lemma 1, \(\mathbf{D}^{\rm T}\mathbf{C}=n\mathbf{I}_{n},\) i.e., \(\mathbf{I}_{n}+ \mathbf{D}^{\rm T}\mathbf{C}= (n+1)\mathbf{I}_{n},\) which when applied to (21) yields
From (19) and (22), \(h_{i}^{*}(t_{i},\mathbf{c})\) and \(e_{ij}^{*}(t_{j},\mathbf{c})\) can be obtained as the expressions given by (11) and (12), respectively.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Anand, S., Chandramouli, R., Subbalakshmi, K.P. et al. Altruism in social networks: good guys do finish first. Soc. Netw. Anal. Min. 3, 167–177 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13278-012-0061-0
Received:
Revised:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13278-012-0061-0