Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal replenishment and pricing decisions under the collect-on-delivery payment scheme

  • Regular article
  • Published:
OR Spectrum Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we study how the timing of payments affects joint replenishment and pricing decisions. Specifically, we consider a periodic review system in which consumers pay upon receiving their goods, referred to as the collect- on-delivery scheme, as opposed to paying when placing their orders, referred to as the instant payment scheme commonly assumed in the literature. We show that a base-stock list price policy is optimal without a fixed ordering cost, and provide a sufficient condition for an \((s, S, p)\) policy to be optimal with a fixed ordering cost. We also perform both analytical and numerical studies to compare the two schemes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aggarwal SP, Jaggi CK (1995) Ordering policies of deteriorating items under permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 46:658–662

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen L, Kök G, Tong J (2012) The effect of payment schemes on inventory decisions: the role of mental accounting. Manag Sci (forthcoming)

  • Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2004a) Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the finite horizon case. Oper Res 52(6):887–896

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2004b) Coordinating inventory control and pricing strategies with random demand and fixed ordering cost: the infinite horizon case. Math Oper Res 29(3):698–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen X, Simchi-Levi D (2012) Pricing and inventory management. In: Philips R, Ozalp O (eds) The Oxford handbook of pricing management. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Chen Y, Ray S, Song Y (2006) Optimal pricing and inventory control policy in periodic-review systems with fixed ordering cost and lost sales. Naval Res Logist 53(2):117–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federgruen A, Heching A (1999) Combined pricing and inventory control under uncertainty. Oper Res 47(3):454–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal SK (1985) Economic order quantity under conditions of permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 36:335–338

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta D, Wang L (2009) A stochastic inventory model with trade credit. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 11(1): 4–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Huh WT, Janakiraman G (2008) \((s, S)\) optimality in joint inventory-pricing control: an alternate approach. Oper Res 56(3):783–790

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger M, Leibold K (2004) Internet payment systems: the consumers’ view—results of the online-survey IZV7. Institute for Economic Policy Research, University of Karlsruhe, Section for Money and Currency

  • Maddah BS, Jaber MY, Abboud NE (2004) Periodic review (s,S) inventory model with permissible delay in payments. J Oper Res Soc 55:147–159

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development) (2006) Online payment systems for e-commerce. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/37/19/36736056.pdf

  • Petruzzi NC, Dada M (1999) Pricing and the newsvendor problem: a review with extensions. Oper Res 47(2):183–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rachamadugu R (1989) Effect of delayed payments (trade credit) on order quantities. J Oper Res Soc 40:805–813

    Google Scholar 

  • Song J-S, Tong J (2011) Payment schemes, financing costs, and inventory management. Working paper. Duke University, Durham

  • Thomas LJ (1974) Price and production decisions with random demand. Oper Res 22(3):513–518

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thowsen GT (1975) A dynamic, nonstationary inventory problem for a price/quantity setting firm. Naval Res Logist Q 22(3):461–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yano C, Gilbert S (2003) Coordinated pricing and production/procurement decisions: a review. In: Eliashberg J, Chakravarty A (eds) Managing business interfaces: marketing, engineering, and manufacturing perspectives. Kluwer, Norwell

  • Zabel E (1972) Multiperiod monopoly under uncertainty. J Econ Theory 5(3):524–536

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Dr. Qing Li in the Hong Kong University of Science and Technology for his many insightful suggestions to this paper. The authors are also grateful to the two anonymous reviewers and the managing editor for their constructive suggestions. This project is supported in part by Guangdong Natural Science Foundation under grant S2011040001069 and S2012040008081, and Hong Kong Research Grants Council Grants No. 622510 and 622811.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jie Zhang.

Appendix A

Appendix A

1.1 A.1 Proof of Lemma 4

Proof

Note that,

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dH(z,p_y(z))}{dz}&= \left\{ \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}+\frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}\left( -\frac{1}{d^{\prime }(p)}\right) \right\} |_{p=p_y(z)}\nonumber \\&= -[p_y(z)-\alpha c+h]+[(1-\alpha )p_y(z)+h+b]\bar{\Phi }(z) \nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{d(p_y(z))+\mu -(1-\alpha )\mathbf{\mathsf E}(-z+\epsilon _t)^{+}}{d^{\prime }(p_y(z))},\\ \frac{d^2H(z,p_y(z))}{dz^2}&= \frac{2-2(1-\alpha )\bar{\Phi }(z)}{d^{\prime }(p_y(z))}-[(1-\alpha )p_y(z)+h+b]\phi (z)\nonumber \\&\quad -\frac{[d(p_y(z))+\mu -(1-\alpha )\mathbf{\mathsf E}(-z+\epsilon _t)^{+}]d^{\prime \prime }(p_y(z))}{[d^{\prime }(p_y(z))]^3}.\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
(9)

If \(z\le 0\), then

$$\begin{aligned} d(p_y(z))+\mu -(1-\alpha )\mathbf{\mathsf E}(-z+\epsilon _t)^{+}=y-z+\mu -(1-\alpha )(-z+\mu )>0; \end{aligned}$$

otherwise if \(z>0\), then

$$\begin{aligned} d(p_y(z))+\mu -(1-\alpha )\mathbf{\mathsf E}(-z+\epsilon _t)^{+}\ge d(p_y(z))+\mu -(1-\alpha )[\mu -z\bar{\Phi }(z)]>0. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(H(z,p_y(z))\) is concave in \(z\) and hence, there exists a unique maximizer \(z(y)\) and \(p(y)=p_y(z(y))\). As \(H(z,p)\) is jointly continuous in \(z\) and \(p\), and \(p_y(z)\) is continuous in \(z\) for any given \(y\ge 0\), \(z(y)\) is continuous for \(y\in [0,+\infty )\). Then, \(p(y)\) is also continuous for \(y\in [0,+\infty )\).

Note that \(\lim \nolimits _{y\rightarrow +\infty }z(y)=\lim \nolimits _{y\rightarrow +\infty }(y-d(p(y)))=+\infty \). If \(z(y)\) is non-increasing in some interval within \([0,+\infty )\), then there must exist \(y_1<y_2\) such that \(z(y_1)=z(y_2)=z_0\). Thus, \(p_{y_1}(z_0)>p_{y_2}(z_0)\). Moreover, the derivative of (9) with respect to \(p_y(z)\) is

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \left\{ -1+(1-\alpha )\bar{\Phi }(z)-1+\frac{d(p)+\mu -(1-\alpha )\mathbf{\mathsf E}(-z+\epsilon _t)^{+}}{(d^{\prime }(p))^2}d^{\prime \prime }(p)\right\} \right| _{p=p_y(z)}\le -1. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, \(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_2}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}>\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_1}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}\) and hence, \(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_2}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}>0\) or,

\(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_1}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}<0\). The former implies \(z_0=y_2\) and the latter implies \(z_0=y_1-d(c)\), any of which contradicts \(z(y_1)=z(y_2)=z_0\). Therefore, \(z(y)\) increases in \(y\) for \(y\in [0,+\infty )\). \(\square \)

1.2 A.2 Proof of Lemma 5

Proof

We first consider the case \(0\le y_1\le y^*\). By Lemma 2, \(z_0\le z^*\) and then by Lemma 3,

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_1}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}&= \left\{ \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}+\frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}\left( -\frac{1}{d^{\prime }(p)}\right) \right\} _{z=z_0,p=p_0}\\&= \left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}\right| _{z=z_0,p=p_0}=\left. \frac{dH(z,\hat{p}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(H(z,p_{y_1}(z))\) is concave in \(z\) by Lemma 4, we have \(z(y_1)\ge z_0\) and hence, \(p(y_1)\ge p_0\). Similarly, for any \(y_2>y^*\), \(z_0>z^*\) and \(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_2}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z_0}<0\). Thus, \(p(y_2)<p_0\). Hereby, we complete the proof of the first part.

Note that for any \(y_1\in [0,y^*]\),

$$\begin{aligned}&\left. \frac{dH(z(y),p(y))}{dy}\right| _{y=y_1}\\&\quad =\left\{ \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}z^{\prime }(y)+\frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}p^{\prime }(y)\right\} _{y=y_1,z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)}\\&\quad =\left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}\right| _{z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)} - d^{\prime }(p)p^{\prime }(y)\left[ \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}\right. \\&\quad \quad +\left. \left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}\left( -\frac{1}{d^{\prime }(p)}\right) \right] \right| _{y=y_1,z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)}\\&=\left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial z}\right| _{z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)}=\left. \frac{d G_t(z,p_{y_1}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z(y_1)}\\&\quad \quad -\left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}\left( -\frac{1}{d^{\prime }(p)}\right) \right| _{z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)}. \end{aligned}$$

Since \(z(y_1)\ge z_0\), by Lemma 2 we have \(z(y_1)+d(\hat{p}(z(y_1)))\ge z_0+d(\hat{p}(z_0))=y_1=z(y_1)+d(p(y_1))\) and hence, \(p(y_1)\ge \hat{p}(z(y_1))\). Therefore, \(\left. \frac{\partial H(z,p)}{\partial p}\right| _{z=z(y_1),p=p(y_1)}\le 0\). Furthermore, \(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_1}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z(y_1)}\ge 0\) as \(p(y_1)\ge p_0>c\). Then,

$$\begin{aligned} \left. \frac{dH(z(y),p(y))}{dy}\right| _{y=y_1}&\ge 0. \end{aligned}$$

On the other hand, for any \(y_2>y^*\), \(\left. \frac{dH(z,p_{y_2}(z))}{dz}\right| _{z=z(y_1)}<0\) as \(p(y_2)<p_0<P^u\). Similarly, \(p(y_2)<\hat{p}(z(y_2))\) because \(z(y_2)<z_0\), and then \(\left. \frac{dH(z(y),p(y))}{dy}\right| _{y=y_2}<0\). Therefore, \(H(z(y),p(y))\) is quasi-concave in \(y\) and \(y^*\) is its maximizer. \(\square \)

1.3 A.3 Proof of Lemma 6

Proof

We prove the three parts one by one.

  1. 1.

    When \(y^*\le y_1<y_2\) and \(p_2\in [c,P^u]\) is given, let \(z_2=y_2-d(p_2)\) and \(y^{\prime }=z_2+d(\hat{p}(z_2))\). By Lemma 5,

    $$\begin{aligned} G(y_1,p(y_1)) \!=\! H(z(y_1),p(y_1)) \!\ge \! H(z(y_2),p(y_2)) \!=\! G(y_2,p(y_2)) \ge G(y_2,p_2). \end{aligned}$$

    If \(z(y_1)\le \max \{z_2,y^*\}\), \(p_1=p(y_1)\) satisfies all the requirements. Otherwise, if \(z(y_1)>\max \{z_2,y^*\}\), consider the following two cases.

    1. (a)

      If \(y^{\prime }\le y_1\), let \(p_1=d^{-1}(y_1-z_2)\). Then, we have \(d(\hat{p}(z_2))\le y_1-z_2=d(p_1)<y_2-z_2=d(p_2)\) and \(\hat{p}(z_2)\ge p_1>p_2\). By Lemma 2,

      $$\begin{aligned} G(y_1,p_1) = H(z_2,p_1) \ge H(z_2,p_2) = G(y_2,p_2), \end{aligned}$$

      and \(y_1-d(p_1)=z_2=y_2-d(p_2)\). Thus, \(p_1\) satisfies all the requirements.

    2. (b)

      If \(y^{\prime }>y_1\), then \(y^{\prime }>y_1\ge z(y_1)>y^*\). By Lemma 5, we have \(p(y^{\prime })\le \hat{p}(z_2)\) and hence,

      $$\begin{aligned} z_2 = y^{\prime }-d(\hat{p}(z_2))\ge y^{\prime }-d(p(y^{\prime }))=z(y^{\prime }). \end{aligned}$$

      Therefore, \(z(y^{\prime })\le z_2<z(y_1)\). However, this contradicts the monotonicity of \(z(y)\) from Lemma 4 as \(y^{\prime }>y_1\). So \(y^{\prime }>y_1\) cannot happen.

  2. 2.

    When \(y^*\ge y_1>y_2\) and \(p_2\in [c,P^u]\) is given, let \(z_2=y_2-d(p_2)\) and \(y^{\prime }=z_2+d(\hat{p}(z_2))\). If \(z_2\le z(y_1)\), let \(p_1=p(y_1)\) and it satisfies all the requirements. Otherwise, if \(z_2>z(y_1)\), consider the following two situations.

    1. (a)

      If \(y^{\prime }\ge y_1\), let \(p_1=d^{-1}(y_1-z_2)\), then we have \(d(p_2)=y_2-z_2<y_1-z_2=d(p_1)\le y^{\prime }-z_2=d(\hat{p}(z_2))\) and \(\hat{p}(z_2)\le p_1<p_2\). By Lemma 2,

      $$\begin{aligned} G(y_1,p_1) = H(z_2,p_1) \ge H(z_2,p_2) = G(y_2,p_2), \end{aligned}$$

      and \(y_1-d(p_1)=z_2=y_2-d(p_2)\). Thus, \(p_1\) satisfies all the requirements.

    2. (b)

      If \(y^{\prime }<y_1\), by the monotonicity of \(z(y)\) from Lemma 4, we have \(z(y^{\prime })<z(y_1)<z_2\). Therefore,

      $$\begin{aligned} d(\hat{p}(z_2)) = y^{\prime }-z_2 < y^{\prime }-z(y^{\prime }) = d(p(y^{\prime })), \end{aligned}$$

      and then \(\hat{p}(z_2)>p(y^{\prime })\). However, this contradicts Lemma 5 as \(y^{\prime }<y_1\le y^*\). So this situation cannot happen.

  3. 3.

    When \(t=T\), since \(R_T(y)\) is quasi-concave in \(y\), we know that \(R_T(y_T^1)\ge R_T(y_T^2)\). Then, we consider two systems that starts with \(y_t^1\) and \(y_t^2\), \(t<T\), and experience the same sample path of the random shocks. We further assume that the system starts with \(y_t^2\) follows the optimal decisions to attain \(R_t(y_t^2)\) and \(p_t^2\) is the optimal price. If \(y_t^2>y_t^1\ge y^*\), by part 1 of Lemma 6, there exists \(p_t^1\) such that \( G_t(y_t^1,p_t^1)\ge G_t(y_t^2,p_t^2)\) and \(x_{t+1}^1\le \max \{x_{t+1}^2,y^*\}\le \max \{y_{t+1}^2,y^*\}\). Otherwise, if \(y_t^2<y_t^1\le y^*\), since \(\max _p G(y,p)\) is quasi-concave in \(y\), there exists \(p_t^1\) such that \( G_t(y_t^1,p_t^1)\ge G_t(y_t^2,p_t^2)\) and \(x_{t+1}^1<y_t^1\le y^*\). In both cases, it can be either \(x_{t+1}^1\le y_{t+1}^2\) or \(y_{t+1}^2<x_{t+1}^1\le y^*\). If \(x_{t+1}^1\le y_{t+1}^2\), order up to \(y_{t+1}^2\) in period \(t+1\) and mimic the decisions of system \(2\) in the following periods for system 1. If \(y_{t+1}^2<x_{t+1}^1\le y^*\), no order is placed in period \(t+1\) in system \(1\). Still, by part 1 of Lemma 6, there exists \(p_{t+1}^1\) such that \(G_{t+1} (y_{t+1}^1,p_{t+1}^1)\ge G_{t+1}(y_{t+1}^2,p_{t+1}^2)\). We continue making decisions for system \(1\) in this way until \(x_s^1\le y_s^2\) for some \(s>t\) or the end of the horizon is reached. Therefore, in either case, system \(1\) is at most \(\alpha K\) worse than system \(2\). Since \(R_t(y_t^1)\) is the maximum profit of system \(1\) from period \(t\) to the end of horizon, we obtain the desired result. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Zhang, J., Zhang, R.Q. Optimal replenishment and pricing decisions under the collect-on-delivery payment scheme. OR Spectrum 36, 503–524 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-013-0321-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00291-013-0321-z

Keywords

Navigation