Skip to main content
Log in

Cash-back rewards versus equity-based electronic loyalty programs in e-commerce

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Information Systems and e-Business Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Loyalty is a crucial part of today’s business because retaining a customer is generally less expensive than attracting a new one. This relationship also holds true in e-commerce. Most of the e-loyalty programs available on the Internet utilize cash-back rewards. A new type of e-loyalty program in which customers are offered a fraction of merchant firm’s equity is emerging recently. The profitability of this approach versus cash-back reward programs is still an open question. In this paper, we first survey current e-loyalty programs, and then develop a two-period duopoly model in which one of the firms gives customers a small fraction of its equity and the other offers cash-back reward for a purchase. We derive analytical conditions to compare the total profits generated through each loyalty program. In particular, we find that equity-based e-loyalty programs provide higher total profits than those of cash-back programs in markets where it is difficult for customers to switch between firms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Abbreviations

A :

the firm offering customers a fraction of its unit share for each purchase

B :

the firm offering customers cash-back reward for each purchase

α, (1 − α):

market shares of firm A and B at the end of the first period, respectively

c :

constant marginal cost of the product sold by the firms

θ:

switching cost parameter of customers

s :

switching cost of customers distributed uniformly on the interval [0,θ]

R :

constant reservation price of customers

Z :

processing fee charged by the online intermediary

p A1, p A2 :

price of firm A’s product in the first and second period, respectively

ɛ A1, ɛ A2 :

fraction of firm A’s unit share offered in the first and second period, respectively

d A1 :

firm A’s outstanding number of stocks in the first period

S A1, S A2 :

firm A’s unit stock price in the first and second period, respectively

p B1, p B2 :

price of firm B’s product in the first and second period, respectively

m B1, m B2 :

amount of cash-back reward given by B in the first and second period, respectively

Q AA , Q BB :

number of firm A’s and B’s loyal customers in the second period, respectively

Q AB , Q BA :

number of customers switching from B to A, and A to B in the second period, respectively

Π * A2 , Π * B2 :

optimum profits of firm A and B in the second period, respectively

Π * A , Π * B :

optimum total profits of firm A and B, respectively

Π *Δ :

difference between the optimum total profits of firm A and B, Π * A  − Π * B

References

  • Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organization. Am Econ Rev 62:777–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Baye MR, Morgan J, Scholten P (2004) Price dispersion in the small and in the large: evidence from an Internet price comparison site. J Ind Econ 52(4):463–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beggs A, Klemperer PD (1992) Multi-period competition with switching costs. Econometrica 60(3):651–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y (1997) Paying customers to switch. J Econ Manag Strategy 6(4):877–897

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen P-Y, Hitt LM (2002) Measuring switching costs and the determinants of customer retention in Internet enabled businesses: a study of the online brokerage industry. Inf Syst Res 13(3):255–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devaraj S, Fan M, Kohli R (2003) E-loyalty—elusive ideal or competitive edge. Commun ACM 46(9):184–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Figueiredo JM (2000) Finding sustainable profitability in electronic commerce. Sloan Manage Rev 41(4):41–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman TL (1999) Amazon.you. New York Times, 26 February, A21

  • Gans N (2002) Customer loyalty and supplier quality competition. Manage Sci 48(2):207–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holstrom B (1982) Moral hazard in teams. Bell J Econ 13:324–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen MC, Murphy KJ (1990) CEO incentives—it’s not how much you pay, but how. Harv Bus Rev 68(3):138–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson EJ, Moe WW, Fader PS, Bellman S, Lohse J (2004) On the depth and dynamics of World Wide Web shopping behavior. Manage Sci 50(3):299–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim B, Shi M, Srinivasan K (2001) Reward programs and tacit collusion. Mark Sci 20(2):99–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim B, Shi M, Srinivasan K (2004) Managing capacity through reward programs. Manage Sci 50(4):503–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer PD (1987a) Markets with consumer switching costs. Q J Econ 102(2):375–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klemperer PD (1987b) The competitiveness of markets with switching costs. Rand J Econ 18(1):138–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miedich SJ, Melicher RW (1985) Corporate sales growth rates and stockholder returns: a risk-return market analysis. Rev Bus Econ Res 20:34–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Nerlove M (1968) Factors affecting differences among rates of return on investments in individual common stocks. Rev Econ Stat 50(3):312–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padilla AJ (1992) Mixed pricing in oligopoly with consumer switching costs. Int J Ind Organ 10(3):393–411

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reichheld F, Schefter P (2000) E-loyalty: your secret weapon on the Web. Harv Bus Rev 78(4):105–113

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinartz W, Kumar V (2002) The mismanagement of customer loyalty. Harv Bus Rev 80(7):86–94

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith MD, Brynjolfsson E (2001) Consumer decision making at an Internet shopbot: brand still matters. J Ind Econ 49(4):541–558

    Google Scholar 

  • Stano M (1976) Monopoly power, ownership control, and corporate performance. Bell J Econ 7(2):672–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kemal Altinkemer.

Additional information

We are grateful for the valuable comments and suggestions by the participants of the AMCIS 2004 Doctoral Consortium, New York City; the Big Ten IS Research Consortium 2004 at the Michigan State University; EURO/INFORMS 2003, Istanbul, Turkey; WISE 2002, Barcelona, Spain; and ICTEC 2002, Montreal, Canada. We are also indebted to the faculty at the Krannert Graduate School of Management for their indispensable inputs.

Appendix (Proofs of Lemmas and Propositions)

Appendix (Proofs of Lemmas and Propositions)

Proof of Lemma 1: Firm A issues ɛ A2 (Q AA + Q AB ) number of new stocks in the second period in addition to its d A1 number of stocks in the first period. The dilution effect states that firm A’s total market value in the first period, d A1 S A1, should be equal to its total market value in the second period, [d A1 + ɛ A2 (Q AA + Q AB )]S A2. Thus,

$$ \begin{aligned} d_{A1} S_{A1} &= {\left[{d_{A1} + \varepsilon_{A2} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}} \right]}S_{A2}\\ \Rightarrow S_{A2} &= \frac{{d_{A1} S_{A1}}}{{d_{A1} + \varepsilon_{A2} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}}}\\ \end{aligned} $$

In addition to the dilution effect, firm A’s second-period stock price is affected by the changes in its market share between the two periods. Denoting the ratio of change in market share by γ, we obtain:

$$ \gamma = \frac{Firm\,A's\,2nd\,period\,market\,share - Firm\,A's\,1st\,period\, market\,share}{Firm\,A's\,1st\,period\,market\,share} $$
$$ \gamma = \frac{\frac{Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}}{N} - \alpha}{\alpha} = \frac{Q_{AA} + Q_{AB} - \alpha N}{\alpha N} $$

Hence, the updated value of S A2 above is calculated as:

$$ S_{A2} = \frac{{d_{A1} S_{A1}}}{{d_{A1} + \varepsilon_{A2} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}}}{\left({1 + \gamma} \right)} = \frac{{d_{A1} S_{A1}}}{{d_{A1} + \varepsilon_{A2} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}}}{\left({\frac{{Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}}}{{\alpha N}}} \right)} = \frac{{d_{A1} S_{A1} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}}}{{\alpha N{\left[{d_{A1} + \varepsilon_{A2} {\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}} \right]}}} $$

Proof of Lemma 2: Using the information presented in Fig. 2, we calculate the total numbers of firm A’s loyal and switching customers in the second period, Q AA and Q BA , as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{AA} &= \alpha N{\int\limits_{p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z}^\theta \frac{1}{\theta}} \, ds\\ Q_{AA} &= \frac{{\alpha N}}{\theta}{\left[{\theta - {\left({p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z} \right)}} \right]}\\ & = \alpha N{\left({1 - \frac{{p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z}}{\theta}} \right)}\\ Q_{BA} &= \alpha N{\int\limits_0^{p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z} {\frac{1}{\theta}}} ds = \frac{{\alpha N}}{\theta}{\left({p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z} \right)}\\ \end{aligned}$$

Similarly, we calculate the total numbers of firm B’s loyal and switching customers in the second period, Q BB and Q AB , as follows:

$$ Q_{BB} = {\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N{\left({1 - \frac{{p_{B2} - p_{A2} + \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - m_{B2}}}{\theta}} \right)} $$
$$ Q_{AB} = \frac{{{\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N}}{\theta}{\left({p_{B2} - p_{A2} + \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - m_{B2}} \right)} $$

Proof of Lemma 3: We first insert the values of S A2, Q AA , Q BA , Q BB , and Q AB from the Eqs. (1), (4), (5), (6), and (7) into the following maximization problems:

$$ {\mathop {\Pi^{*}_{A2} = {\mathop {Max}\limits_{\varepsilon_{A2}}}}\limits} \Pi_{A2} = {\left({p_{A2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - c} \right)}{\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)} $$
$$ {\mathop {\Pi^{*}_{B2} = {\mathop {Max}\limits_{m_{B2}}}}\limits} \Pi_{B2} = {\left({p_{B2} - m_{B2} - c} \right)}{\left({Q_{BB} + Q_{BA}} \right)} $$

We then solve the following equations together to find the optimum values of ɛ A2 and m B2.

$$ \frac{{\partial \Pi_{A2}}}{{\partial \varepsilon_{A2}}} = 0\quad{\hbox{and}}\quad\frac{{\partial \Pi_{B2}}}{{\partial m_{B2}}} =0 $$

Simultaneous solution of the two equations above gives us m * B2 as follows:

$$ m^{*}_{B2} = p_{B2} - c - \frac{1}{3}{\left[{\alpha Z + {\left({2 - \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right]} $$
(A.1)

The solution for ɛ* A2 requires further work since it appears as a function of Q AA and Q AB :

$$ \varepsilon^{*}_{A2} = \frac{{\alpha Nd_{A1} {\left[{3{\left({p_{A2} - c} \right)} + \alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right]}}}{{{\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)}{\left[{3d_{A1} S_{A1} - \alpha N{\left({3{\left({p_{A2} - c} \right)} + \alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right)}} \right]}}} $$
(A.2)

To solve for ɛ* A2 independent from Q AA and Q AB , we first find the optimum values of Q AA and Q AB by inserting Eqs. (1), (A.1) and (A.2) into the following equations:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{AA} &= \alpha N{\left({1 - \frac{{p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z}}{\theta}} \right)}\quad{\hbox{and}}\\Q_{AB} &= \frac{{{\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N}}{\theta}{\left({p_{B2} - p_{A2} + \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - m_{B2}} \right)} \end{aligned}$$

After simplifications of algebra, we obtain:

$$ Q^{*}_{AA} = \frac{{\alpha N}}{{3\theta}}{\left[{4\theta - 3Z + 2\alpha {\left({Z - \theta} \right)}} \right]}\;{\hbox{and}}\; Q^{*}_{AB} = \frac{{2{\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N}}{{3\theta}}{\left[\!\frac{\theta}{2} + {\alpha {\left({Z - \theta} \right)}} \!\right]} $$
(A.3)

Inserting these values back into Eq. (A.2) gives us the value of ɛ* A2:

$$ \varepsilon^{*}_{A2} = \frac{{3\alpha \theta d_{A1} {\left[{3{\left({p_{A2} - c} \right)} + \alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right]}}}{{{\left[{\alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right]}{\left[{\alpha N{\left({3{\left({p_{A2} - c} \right)} + \alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right)} - 3d_{A1} S_{A1}} \right]}}} $$
(A.4)

Finally, by inserting Eqs. (A.3) and (A.4) into (1), we can find S * A2 as follows:

$$ S^{*}_{A2} = \frac{{{\left[{\alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right]}{\left[{\alpha N{\left({3{\left({p_{A2} - c} \right)} + \alpha Z - {\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta} \right)} - 3d_{A1} S_{A1}} \right]}}}{{9\alpha \theta d_{A1}}} $$
(A.5)

The values of Q * BA and Q * BB can be found similarly by inserting Eqs. (A.1), (A.4), and (A.5) into the following equations:

$$ \begin{aligned}Q_{BA} &= \frac{{\alpha N}}{\theta}{\left({p_{A2} - p_{B2} + m_{B2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} + Z} \right)}\quad{\hbox{and}}\\Q_{BB} &= {\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N{\left({1 - \frac{{p_{B2} - p_{A2} + \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - m_{B2}}}{\theta}} \right)} \end{aligned}$$

which leads to:

$$ Q^{*}_{BA} = \frac{{\alpha N}}{{3\theta}}{\left[{3Z - \theta - 2\alpha {\left({Z - \theta} \right)}} \right]}\quad{\hbox{and}}\quad Q^{*}_{BB} = \frac{{2{\left({1 - \alpha} \right)}N}}{{3\theta}}{\left[{\theta - \alpha {\left({Z - \theta} \right)}} \right]} $$
(A.6)

Proof of Lemma 4: We can find the second-period optimum profit of firm A, Π* A2, by inserting Eqs. (A.3), (A.4), and (A.5) into:

$$ {\mathop {\Pi^{*}_{A2} =}\limits} {\mathop {Max}\limits_{\varepsilon_{A2}}} \Pi_{A2} = {\left({p_{A2} - \varepsilon_{A2} S_{A2} - c} \right)}{\left({Q_{AA} + Q_{AB}} \right)} $$

After simplifications, firm A’s optimum profit in the second period reduces to the following form:

$$ \Pi^{*}_{A2} = \frac{N}{{9\theta}}{\left[{{\left({1 + \alpha} \right)}\theta - \alpha Z} \right]}^{2} $$

Similarly, firm B’s second-period optimum profit is found by inserting (A.1) and (A.6) into:

$$ {\mathop {\Pi^{*}_{B2} = {\mathop {Max}\limits_{m_{B2}}}}\limits} \Pi_{B2} = {\left({p_{B2} - m_{B2} - c} \right)}{\left({Q_{BB} + Q_{BA}} \right)} $$

which results the required equation for Π* B2 :

$$ \Pi^{*}_{B2} = \frac{N}{{9\theta}}{\left[{{\left({2 - \alpha} \right)}\theta + \alpha Z} \right]}^{2} $$

Proof of Lemma 5: To find ɛ* A1 and m * B1, we solve the following first-order conditions simultaneously by using Eqs. (20) and (21). Further simplifications lead to the expressions in (22) and (23).

$$ \frac{{\partial \Pi_{A}}}{{\partial \varepsilon_{A1}}} = 0\quad{\hbox{and}}\quad\frac{{\partial \Pi_{B}}}{{\partial m_{B1}}} = 0 $$

Proof of Proposition 1: The optimum total firm profits, Π* A and Π* B , are calculated by inserting Eqs. (22) and (23) into (20) and (21). Simplification of the resulting algebra leads to (24) and (25).

Proof of Proposition 2: Subtracting Eq. (25) from (24) gives us the difference between the optimum total firm profits, Π* Δ. Further simplification of the resulting algebra leads to the inequality in (26).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Altinkemer, K., Ozcelik, Y. Cash-back rewards versus equity-based electronic loyalty programs in e-commerce. Inf Syst E-Bus Manage 7, 39–55 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10257-007-0062-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10257-007-0062-0

Keywords

Navigation