Skip to main content
Log in

Affiliated marketing

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Information Systems and e-Business Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In information-intensive environments some firms may be sending their customers to other firms’ or affiliates’ websites in order to generate additional sales for their affiliates. Although this may provide a choice for the customers, from a firm’s point of view such strategies have the potential to cannibalize own sales. Hence, when customers purchase from other firms’ websites, the firm may loose its own customers. This study analyzes the optimality of such strategies using an analytical framework. The findings show that a firm may increase its prices and profit when its own customers purchase from other firm websites. An analysis of customer surplus and total welfare show that such strategies may have adverse effects. The results show that customer surplus and total welfare may decrease as a result of affiliations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Contrasting information-intensive environments to traditional markets reveals the increasing emphasis the firms put on affiliates in information-intensive environments. For example, according to a survey most traditional hotels are indifferent to using affiliate problems (Sigala 2003).

References

  • Amit R, Zott C (2001) Value Creation in E-Business. Strat Manage J 22:493–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biyalogorsky E, Gerstner E, Libai B (2001) Customer referral management: optimal reward programs. Mark Sci 20:82–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee P (2002) Interfirm alliances in online retailing. J Bus Res 57:714–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y, Iyer G, Padmanabhan V (2002) Referral infomediaries. Mark Sci 21:412–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daily Deal/The Deal (2008) It’s Splitsville for AOL. February 8

  • Galetta DF, Henry RM, McCoy S et al (2006) When the wait isn’t so bad: the interacting effects of website delay, familiarity and breadth. Inf Sys Res 17:20–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giaglis GM, Klein S, O’Keefe RM (2002) The role of intermediaries in electronic marketplaces: developing a contingency model. Inf Sys J 12:231–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helm S (2000) Viral marketing—establishing customer relationships by word-of-mouse. Electron Mark 10:158–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Japan Times (2006) Affiliate marketing now coming of age. August 15

  • Kwok T, Nguyen T, Lam L (2004) Tracking results from multichannel marketing programs on electronic commerce. In: Proceedings of the fourth ACM conference on Electronic Commerce, pp 260–261

  • Libai B, Biyalogorsky E, Gerstner E (2003) Setting referral fees in affiliate marketing. J Serv Res 5:303–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marketing (2007) A convincing argument. September 12, p 42

  • Marketing (2008a) Affiliate marketing. June 25, p 36

  • Marketing (2008b) Maximizing online spend. June 25, p 35

  • Retail Week (2006) Affiliate network pushes traffic to Evans Cycle. September 22, p 10

    Google Scholar 

  • Revolution (2008) Affiliate marketing clearly cost effective. June 19, p 53

  • Shin N (2001) Strategies for competitive advantage in electronic commerce. J Electron Comm Res 2:164–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigala M (2003) Implementing customer relationship management in the hotel sector: Does IT always matter? http://is2.lse.ac.uk/asp/aspecis/20030143.pd. Accessed 10 July 2008

  • Sismeiro C, Bucklin RE (2004) Modeling purchase behavior at an E-commerce web site. J Mark Res 41:306–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Tolga Akçura.

Appendix

Appendix

Notations are given in Table 2.

Table 2 Notation table

1.1 Proofs of Propositions 1 and 2

First, we find the location of the indifferent customer. By solving vxt−(1−δ)p 1−δ((1−x)t + p 2) = v−(1−x) tp 2, we find \(x=\frac{{(1-\delta)(-p_1+p_2+t)}}{{t(2-\delta)}} .\) The location of the indifferent customer helps us to identify the respective firm demands. By multiplying the demands with the prices we find profits. Due to affiliation, firm 1 may sent δ fraction of its customers to firm 2 and may charge a commission fee of c. Then, the firm profits are given by π1 = (1−δ)xp 1 + δx c and π2 = (1−x)p 2 + δx (p 2c). We solve the game using subgame perfect Nash. First, firms simultaneously set their prices. Note that the second order conditions hold since the second derivatives of profits with respect to prices equal \(-2\frac{{(1-\delta)^{2}}}{t(2-\delta)}.\) When we set the first derivatives of profits with respect to prices to zero we have the following equations:

$$ \begin{aligned} 2\frac{{\left(\delta-1 \right) ^{2}}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}} -\frac{{\left( 1-\delta \right) \left( \delta-1 \right) {\mit p_1}}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}+\frac{{\left( 1-\delta \right) \left(\delta-1 \right) \left( -{\mit p_1}+t+{\mit p2} \right)}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}-\frac{{\delta \left(\delta-1 \right) c}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}=&0\\ -\frac{{\left( \delta-1 \right) {\mit p_2}}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}+1-\frac{{\left( \delta-1 \right) \left(-{\mit p_1}+t+{\mit p_2} \right) }}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}+\frac{{\delta \left( \delta -1 \right) \left({\mit p_2}-c \right) }}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}+\frac{{\delta \left( \delta-1 \right) \left( -{\mit p_1}+t+{\mit p_2} \right)}}{{t \left( \delta-2 \right)}}=&0 \end{aligned} $$

By simultaneously solving the above equations we find the prices: \(p_1=1/3 \frac{{-3 \delta t+3 t+{\delta}^{2}t+3 {\delta}^{2}c-3 \delta c}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2}}}\) and \(p_2=1/3 \frac{{3{\delta}^{2}c-{\delta}^{2}t-3 \delta c+3 t}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2}}}\). When we insert these prices in the profit functions we find \(\pi_1=-1/9 \frac{{\left( -3 \delta+3+{\delta}^{2} \right) ^{2}t}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2} \left(\delta-2 \right) }}\) and \(\pi_2=-1/9 \frac{{{\delta}^{4}t-9 {\delta}^{3}c-6 {\delta}^{2}t+27 {\delta}^{2}c-18 \delta c+9 t}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2} \left( \delta-2 \right)}} .\) Firm 1 profit with respect to δ increases since the derivative equals to \(1/9 \frac{{\left( 3-\delta\right) \left(3-3 \delta+{\delta}^{ 2} \right) \left(1+\delta-{\delta}^{2} \right) t}}{{\left(2- \delta \right) ^{2} \left(1- \delta \right) ^{3}}} > 0.\) Hence, firm 1 finds it beneficial to set δ to the maximum value. By inserting the optimal prices, we see that the indifferent customer is located at \(x=1/3 \frac{{-3 \delta+3+{\delta}^{2}}}{{\left( \delta-2 \right) \left( \delta-1 \right)}}.\) Since \(x < 1,\) we need to have δ < 0.63. We also see that firm 1 profit does not increase with c, the firm weakly prefers setting c to zero. In order to see the profits without affiliation, we set δ to zero. This provides profits of t/2. However, we have already showed that a higher δ increases profits. Hence, both firms prefer to be affiliated.

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3

The profits with no affiliation equal to t/2 based on the above proposition. The incremental profit with affiliation is the difference between the optimal profit with affiliation and t/2. That is \(\pi_1-t/2=-1/18 \frac{{ \left( 2 \delta-3 \right) \left({\delta}^{2}-3\right) \delta t}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2} \left( \delta-2\right)}}\) and \(\pi_2-t/2=-1/18 \frac{{\left( 2 \delta-3 \right) \left( {\delta}^{2}+6 \delta-15 \right) \delta t}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2} \left(\delta-2 \right).}}\) The respective derivatives with respect to t equal to \(1/18 \frac{{\delta \left(3- 2 \delta \right) \left(3- {\delta}^{2} \right) }}{{\left(2- \delta \right) \left(1- \delta\right) ^{2}}}\) and \(1/18 \frac{{\delta \left(3- 2 \delta \right) \left(15- {\delta}^{2}-6 \delta \right) }}{{\left(2- \delta \right) \left(1- \delta\right) ^{2}}}\) which are positive. Hence, as t increases the incremental profit also increases and the profit potential due to affiliations increase. We also see that the derivatives of prices with respect to t for firm 1 and firm 2 equal to \(1/3\frac{{3+\delta^2-3\delta}}{{(1-\delta)^2}}\) and \(1/3\frac{{3-\delta^2}}{{(1-\delta)^2}},\) which are positive.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 4

When firms are not affiliated, both firms obtain half the market and the indifferent customer is located at 1/2. When firms are affiliated we see that the indifferent customer is located at \(x=1/3 \frac{{-3 \delta+3+{\delta}^{2}}}{{\left( \delta-2 \right) \left( \delta-1 \right)}}\) note that \( x-1/2=1/6{ \frac{{\delta \left(3- \delta \right) }}{{\left(2- \delta \right) \left(1- \delta \right)}}} > 0.\) Hence more customers prefer to visit firm 1. Firms unit sales are given by δx. We see that \(\delta x-1/2=1/6 \frac{{2 {\delta}^{3}-9 {\delta}^{2}+15 \delta-6}}{{\left( \delta-2 \right) \left(\delta-1 \right)}},\) which is positive when δ > 0.571. Similar arguments show that fewer customers initially want to visit firm 2. However, firm 2 unit sales is given by (1−δ)x + (1−x) which is higher than 1/2 when δ < 0.571.

1.4 Proof of Proposition 5

Customer surplus (CS) is found by integrating customer surplus over all customers. CS equals

$$ \int\limits_0^{x} ({v-(1-\delta)p_1-ty-\delta(p_2+t(1-y))} ){\rm d}y+\int\limits_{x}^{1} ({v-p_2-t(1-y)} ) {\rm d}y $$

This gives us \(CS=1/18 {\frac {-t{\delta}^{4}+18 v{\delta}^{3}+3 t{\delta}^{3}-72 v{\delta}^{2}+9 {\delta}^{2}t+90 v\delta-45 \delta t+45 t-36v}{ \left( \delta-1 \right) ^{2} \left( \delta-2 \right) }}.\) The derivative of customer surplus with respect to δ equals to \(-1/18 \frac{{t \left( \delta-3 \right) \left( {\delta}^{4}-4 { \delta}^{3}+17 {\delta}^{2}-48 \delta+45 \right) }}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{3} \left( \delta-2 \right) ^{2}}},\) which is negative. Hence, customer surplus decreases when δ is greater than zero. Total welfare (TW) equals to CS + π1 + π2. The derivative of TW with respect to δ equals to \( -1/18 \frac{{t \left( \delta-3 \right) \left( 5 {\delta}^{4}-20 {\delta}^{3}+31 {\delta}^{2}-24 \delta+9 \right)}}{{\left( \delta-1 \right) ^{3} \left( \delta-2 \right) ^{2}}}\) which is also negative. Hence, we see that total welfare also decreases with affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Akçura, M.T. Affiliated marketing. Inf Syst E-Bus Manage 8, 379–394 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10257-009-0118-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10257-009-0118-4

Keywords

Navigation