Skip to main content
Log in

An allocation game model with reciprocal behavior and its applications in supply chain pricing decisions

  • S.I.: CLAIO 2014
  • Published:
Annals of Operations Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Commonly, people are much nicer in response to friendly actions and much nastier and even brutal in response to hostile actions. In social psychology, such a phenomenon is called reciprocity. As an extension of the standard Stackelberg game, we propose a new allocation game framework with consideration of such reciprocal behavior. Specifically, we consider a situation in which the follower evaluates the leaders intention based on the leaders action and then may take either a positive or negative reciprocal action. We also apply the new framework in a supply chain pricing problem to investigate the impact of the retailer’s reciprocal behavior on pricing decisions, obtaining the following interesting results. First, the supplier should take into account the retailers personality and offer a wholesale price based on it. Second, while the retailer can benefit from his reciprocal behavior, the supplier suffers in most cases. Finally, the retailers reciprocal behavior can help alleviate the double marginalization effect, and thus lead to a performance improvement in the whole supply chain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public-goods experiments: Kindness or confusion? The American Economic Review, 85(4), 891–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker-Peth, M., Katok, E., & Thonemann, U. W. (2013). Designing buyback contracts for irrational but predictable newsvendors. Management Science, 59(8), 1800–1816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, J., Dickhaut, J., & McCabe, K. (1995). Trust, reciprocity, and social history. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). Anomalies: Ultimatums, dictators and manners. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 209–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini, R. B. (1993). Influence: Science and practice (3rd ed.). New York: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cui, T., Raju, J. S., & Zhang, Z. J. (2007). Fairness and channel coordination. Management Science, 53(8), 1303–1314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R., Croson, D., & Ren, Y. (2011). The overconfident newsvendor. Working Paper, University of Texas at Dallas.

  • Dufwenberg, M., & Kirchsteiger, G. (2004). A theory of sequential reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 47(2), 268–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Kirchsteiger, G., & Riedl, A. (1993). Does fairness prevent market clearing? An experimental investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(2), 437–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2002). Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Human nature, 13(1), 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., & Fischbacher, U. (2006). A theory of reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 54(2), 293–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: The economics of reciprocity. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. The American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frazier, G. L. (1983). Interorganizational exchange behavior in marketing channels: A broadened perspective. Journal of Marketing, 47(4), 68–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., & Falk, A. (2002). Reputation and reciprocity: Consequences for the labour relation. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 104(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., & Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(4), 367–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W. (1995). On ultimatum bargaining experiments–A personal review. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 27(3), 329–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T. H., & Zhang, J. (2008). Designing pricing contracts for boundedly rational customers: Does the framing of the fixed fee matter? Management Science, 54(4), 686–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katok, E., & Pavlov, V. (2013). Fairness in supply chain contracts: A laboratory study. Journal of Operations Management, 31(3), 129–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, M., Petruzzi, N. C., & Zhang, J. (2016). Overconfident competing newsvendors. Management Science, (forthcoming)

  • Loch, C. H., & Wu, Y. (2008). Social preferences and supply chain performance: An experimental study. Management Science, 54(11), 1835–1849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macneil, I. R. (1980). The new social contract: An inquiry into moddern contractual relations. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Offerman, T. (2002). Hurting hurts more than helping helps. European Economic Review, 46(8), 1423–1437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raju, J., & Zhang, Z. J. (2005). Channel coordination in the presence of a dominant retailer. Marketing Science, 24(2), 254–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ren, Y., & Croson, R. (2013). Overconfidence in newsvendor orders: An experimental study. Management Science, 59(11), 2502–2517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., & Erev, I. (1995). Learning in extensive-form games: Experimental data and simple dynamic models in the intermediate term. Games and Economic Behavior, 8(1), 164–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schweitzer, M. E., & Cachon, G. P. (2000). Decision bias in the newsvendor problem with a known demand distribution: Experimental evidence. Management Science, 46(3), 404–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, X. (2008). Bounded rationality in newsvendor models. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 10(4), 566–589.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1988). Anomalies: The ultimatum game. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2(4), 195–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tidd, K. L., & Lockard, J. S. (1978). Monetary significance of the affiliative smile: A case for reciprocal altruism. Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society, 11(6), 344–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, X., & Niederhoff, J. A. (2014). Fairness in Selling to the Newsvendor. Production and Operations Management, 23(11), 2002–2022.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Qinglong Gou.

Additional information

This work was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant nos. 71271111, 71271198, 71110107024 and 71471086).

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Lemma 1

To maximum the retailer’s profit, we get the first and second derivatives with respect to retail price p about Eq. (17):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{R}}{\partial p}=-2p+w+a, \end{aligned}$$
(31)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{R}}{\partial p^{2}}=-2<0. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

From Eq. (32) we know that \(\pi _{R}\) gets its maximum when \(\partial \pi _{R}/\partial p =0\). Letting Eq. (31) equal to 0 we have

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{p}(w)=\frac{a+w}{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting \(\tilde{p}(w)\) into Eqs. (16) and (17), we obtain Eqs. (19) and (20) in Lemma 1.

1.2 Proof of Lemma 2

Given the retailer’s best response shown in Lemma 1, we have the supplier’s profit function in Eq. (20).

Then, the first and second derivatives of \(\pi _S\) with respect to wholesale price w are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{S}}{\partial w}=-w+\frac{a}{2} \end{aligned}$$
(33)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}}{\partial w^{2}}=-1, \end{aligned}$$
(34)

respectively.

Since \(\frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}}{\partial w^{2}}<0\) we know that \(\pi _S\) gets its maximum value at \(\frac{\partial \pi _{S}}{\partial w}=0\), i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} w^*=\frac{a}{2}. \end{aligned}$$

Substituting the above equation into Eqs. (18)–(20), we obtain Eqs. (22) and (23) in Lemma 2.

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

The reciprocal retailer is to maximize his utility given by Eq. (25).

The first and second derivatives of Eq. (25) with respect to p are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial U_{R}}{\partial p}=-2(1+\alpha )p+(1+\alpha )(a+w)-\gamma w, \end{aligned}$$
(35)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2} U_{R}}{\partial p^{2}}=-2(1+\alpha )<0. \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Then, letting Eq. (35) equal to 0 we get the optimal response of the retailer, i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} p^{r}(w)=\frac{a+w}{2}-\frac{\gamma w}{2(1+\alpha )}. \end{aligned}$$
(37)

(I) When \(0\le w\le \frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), Eq. (37)\(<a\), so we just need to compare \(p^{r}(w)\) with w. Thus, we have:

(1A) while \(\gamma _{2}\ge 2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\), and \(w\le \frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\), \(p^{r}(w)\ge w\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at \(p^{r}(w)\);

(1B) while \(\gamma _{2}<2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\), and \(w<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), \(p^{r}(w)>w\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at \(p^{r}(w)\);

(1C) while \(\gamma _{2}>2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\), and \(w>\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\), \(p^{r}(w)<w\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at w.

(II) When \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}<w<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\), \(w<p^{r}(w)<a\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at \(p^{r}(w)\).

(III) When \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\le w\le a\), Eq. (37)\(>w\), so we just need to compare \(p^{r}(w)\) with a. Thus, we have:

(3A) while \(\gamma _{1}\le 2\beta _1(1+\alpha )\), and \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\le w\le \frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{1}}\), \(w<p^{r}(w)<a\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at \(p^{r}(w)\);

(3B) while \(\gamma _{1}<2\beta _1(1+\alpha )\), and \(\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{1}}<w<a\),\(w<p^{r}(w)>a\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at a;

(3C) while \(\gamma _{1}>2\beta _1(1+\alpha )\), and \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _1}<w<a\),\(w<p^{r}(w)>a\), \(U_{R}\) takes its maximum at a.

Substituting \(p^{r}(w)\) to Eqs. (15), (16), (17) and (25) we obtain Eqs. (28)–(30) and Proposition 3 is proven.

1.4 Proof of Proposition 4

The supplier is to maximize his profit given by Eq. (30). Combine Proposition 3, we have:

(I) When \(\gamma _{2}\le 2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\) and \(0\le w\le \frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=w\left( \frac{a-w}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{2}w}{2(1+\alpha )}\right) \) in this case. The first and second derivatives of Eq. (30) with respect to w are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w}=\frac{a}{2}-\frac{w(1+\alpha -\gamma _{2})}{1+\alpha }, \end{aligned}$$
(38)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w^{2}}=-\frac{(1+\alpha -\gamma _{2})}{1+\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(39)

Since \(\gamma _{2}<\alpha \), we have \(\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}/\partial w^{2}<0\), which means that \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) is concave in \(0\le w\le \frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\).

Letting Eq. (38) = 0, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{w}_{1}=\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{2(1+\alpha -\gamma _{2})}. \end{aligned}$$
(40)

From \(\gamma _{2}<\alpha \) we know \(\bar{w}_{1}>0\). Then we just need to compare \(\bar{w}_{1}\) with the bound \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\).

Thus we have: (i) if \(\bar{w}_{1}<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), i.e., \(\beta _{2}<\frac{1}{2}-\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha }\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{(\alpha +1)a^{2}}{8(1+\alpha -\gamma _{2})}\) at \(w=\bar{w}_{1}\) in \([0,\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}]\); and (ii) if \(\bar{w}_{1}\ge \frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), i.e., \(\beta _{2}\ge \frac{1}{2}-\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha }\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{a^{2}}{2(1+2\beta _{2})^{2}}(2\beta _{2}+\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha })\) at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\) in \([0,\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}]\).

(II) When \(\gamma _{2}>2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\) and \(0\le w\le \frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=w\left( \frac{a-w}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{2}w}{2(1+\alpha )}\right) \). Similar to case I, we need to compare \(\bar{w}_{1}\) with the bound \(\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\).

Thus, we have: (i) if \(\bar{w}_{1}<\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\), i.e., \(\gamma _{2}<\frac{1+\alpha }{3}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{(\alpha +1)a^{2}}{8(1+\alpha -\gamma _{2})}\) at \(w=\bar{w}_{1}\) in \([0,\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}]\); and (ii) if \(\bar{w}_{1}\ge \frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), i.e., \(\gamma _{2}\ge \frac{1+\alpha }{3}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{(\alpha +1)\gamma _{2}a^{2}}{(1+\alpha +\gamma _{2})^{2}}\) at \(w=\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\)in \([0,\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}]\).

(III) When \(\gamma _{2}>2\beta _{2}(1+\alpha )\) and \(\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}<w<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=w(a-w)\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{(\alpha +1)\gamma _{2}a^{2}}{(1+\alpha +\gamma _{2})^{2}}\) at \(w=\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\) in\((\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}},\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}})\).

(IV) When \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}<w<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=w\frac{(a-w)}{2}\) in this case. The first and second derivatives of Eq. (30) with respect to w are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w}=\frac{a}{2}-w, \end{aligned}$$
(41)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w^{2}}=-1. \end{aligned}$$
(42)

Since \(\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}/\partial w^{2}<0\), we let Eq. (41) = 0 and

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{w}_{2}=\frac{a}{2}. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

Thus, we have: (i) if \(\bar{w}_{2}<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\), i.e., \(\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<\frac{1}{2}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{a^{2}\beta _{2}}{2(1+2\beta _{2})^{2}}\) at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\) in \((\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}},\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}})\); and (ii) if \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}<\bar{w}_{2}<\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\), i.e., \(\beta _{1}<\frac{1}{2}<\beta _{2}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{a^{2}}{8}\) at \(w=\bar{w}_{2}\); (iii) if \(\bar{w}_{2}>\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\) , i.e., \(\beta _{2}>\beta _{1}>\frac{1}{2}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{a^{2}\beta _{1}}{2(1+2\beta _{1})^{2}}\) at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\) in \((\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}},\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}})\).

(IV) When \(\gamma _{1}\le 2\beta _{1}(1+\alpha )\) and \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\le w\le \frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{1}}\), we have\(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=w\left( \frac{a-w}{2}-\frac{\gamma _{1}w}{2(1+\alpha )}\right) \) in this case. The first and second derivatives of Eq. (30) with respect to w are

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w}=\frac{a}{2}-\frac{w(1+\alpha +\gamma _{1})}{1+\alpha }, \end{aligned}$$
(44)

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}}{\partial w^{2}}=-\frac{(1+\alpha +\gamma _{1})}{1+\alpha }. \end{aligned}$$
(45)

We obtain \(\partial ^{2}\pi _{S}^{r}/\partial w^{2}<0\) and let Eq. (44) = 0 and

$$\begin{aligned} \bar{w}_{3}=\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{2(1+\alpha +\gamma _{1})}. \end{aligned}$$
(46)

We can know \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) reaches its maximum value \(\frac{(\alpha +1)a^{2}}{8(1+\alpha +\gamma _{1})}\) at \(w=\bar{w}_{3}\) in \([\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}},\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{1}}]\).

(VII) When \(\gamma _{1}\le 2\beta _{1}(1+\alpha )\) and \(\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{1}}<w<a\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=0\).

(VIII) When \(\gamma _{1}>2\beta _{1}(1+\alpha )\) and \(\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}<w<a\), we have \(\pi _{S}^{r}(w)=0\).

Therefore, the supplier compares his profits in (I), (II), (III), (IV), (VI), (VII), (VIII) to determine the globally optimal wholesale price.

(1) When \(\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<\frac{\gamma _{2}}{2(1+\alpha )}\)and \(\gamma _{2}\le \frac{1+\alpha }{3}\), we obtain that \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\bar{w}_{1}\);

(2) When \(\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<\frac{\gamma _{2}}{2(1+\alpha )}\)and \(\gamma _{2}>\frac{1+\alpha }{3}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a(1+\alpha )}{1+\alpha +\gamma _{2}}\);

(3) When \(\frac{\gamma _{2}}{2(1+\alpha )}<\beta _{2}<\frac{1}{2}-\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha }\) and \(\gamma _{2}\le \frac{1+\alpha }{3}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\bar{w}_{1}\);

(4) When \(\frac{1}{2}-\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha }\le \beta _{2}<\frac{1}{2}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\);

(5) When \(\beta _{1}<\frac{1}{2}<\beta _{2}\), if \(\beta _{1}<\frac{1}{2}<\beta _{2}\le A\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\); if \(\beta _{1}<\frac{1}{2}<A<\beta _{2}\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\bar{w}_{1}\), where \(A=\frac{1+\alpha +2\sqrt{\gamma _{2}(1+\alpha )}}{2(1+\alpha )}\);

(6) When \(\frac{1}{2}<\beta _{1}\le \frac{1}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{1}}{1+\alpha }\), if \(\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<B\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\); if \(\beta _{2}>B\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\), where \(B=\frac{1+4\beta _{1}^{2}+(1+2\beta _{1})\sqrt{(1-2\beta _{1})^{2}+8\beta _{1}\frac{\gamma _{2}}{1+\alpha }}}{8\beta _{1}}\);

(7) When \(\frac{1}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{1}}{1+\alpha }<\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}\), if \(\frac{1}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{1}+\sqrt{\gamma _{1}}}{1+\alpha }<\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<C\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\); if \(\beta _{2}>C\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\bar{w}_{3}\); if \(\beta _{1}<\beta _{2}<B\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{2}}\); if \(\beta _{2}>B\), \(\pi _{S}^{r}\) takes its maximum value at \(w=\frac{a}{1+2\beta _{1}}\), where \(C=\frac{1}{2}+\frac{\gamma _{2}+\sqrt{(\gamma _{1}+1+\alpha )(\gamma _{1}+\gamma _{2})}}{(1+\alpha )}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, Y., Li, J. & Gou, Q. An allocation game model with reciprocal behavior and its applications in supply chain pricing decisions. Ann Oper Res 258, 347–368 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2165-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-016-2165-9

Keywords

Navigation