Skip to main content
Log in

The Time-Inconsistency Problem of Labor Taxes and Constitutional Constraints

  • Published:
Dynamic Games and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the time-inconsistency problem of labor taxes in an economy with balanced-budget policies and no capital taxes. With full commitment, we show that Ramsey labor taxes change with the cost of distortionary taxation and with the cost of not being able to tax capital. We numerically show that these make labor taxes increasing over time. With limited commitment, we find that this time-inconsistency problem leads to underprovision of public consumption. For our baseline parameter values, we find that imposing carefully chosen bounds on labor taxes as constitutional constraints can be optimal. While our proposed bounds sustain the Ramsey as the best sustainable equilibrium, our lower bounds alone or, in combination with some upper bounds, induce higher public consumption and higher welfare in the worst sustainable equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, Lucas [17] and, more recently, Mankiw et al. [20].

  2. The finding that optimal labor taxes are increasing over time when capital cannot be taxed is connected to the comments of Atkenson et al. [3]. They observe that a positive tax on capital is comparable to an increasing tax rate on consumption and the latter corresponds to an increasing tax rate on labor income. These policies are comparable but not equivalent. In our economy, we do not count with consumption taxes and not having capital taxes eliminates an instrument that is necessary for decentralization and therefore changes the Ramsey problem.

  3. See [4, 5, 18, 26], etc.

  4. More precisely, in Ramsey problems with full commitment, access to bonds, capital taxes, and with homothetic preferences, optimal labor taxes are typically low (even negative) in the initial period and then positive and roughly constant from then on. In contrast, in our paper, labor taxes are increasing over the transitional phase.

  5. An alternative approach is to consider Markov-perfect equilibria as in [15].

  6. In this model, with only one source of government income, the non-negativity of public consumption requires a non-negative labor tax. Moreover, Laffer curve effects generate a ’natural’ upper bound on labor tax rates.

  7. The first-order conditions in period 0 are different due to the initial wealth.

  8. As usual, an optimal interior solution is assumed to exist.

  9. We refer to [12] for details in the approximation of convex-valued sets and to [10, 11] for applications of the algorithm to similar games (and for recovering the strategies).

  10. We discretize the state space with \(400\) equally spaced points for \(k\in [0.01,1.5]\), \(400\) points for \(m\), and \(100\) points for \(\tau \in [0,0.9]\). We use linear interpolation for values falling outside of the grid. We ran our C++ MPI code using an IBM iDataPlex cluster, with 50 Intel Sandy Bridge 2.6 GHZ processors.

References

  1. Abreu D, Pearce D, Stacchetti E (1990) Toward a theory of discounted repeated games with imperfect monotoring. Econometrica 58:1041–1063

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Albanesi S, Armenter R (2012) Intertemporal distortions in the second best. Rev Econ Stud 79:1271–1307

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Atkenson A, Chari VV, Kehoe PJ (1999) Taxing capital income: a bad idea. Fed Reserve Bank Minneap Q Rev 23:3–18

    Google Scholar 

  4. Chari VV, Christiano LJ, Kehoe PJ (1994) Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. J Polit Econ 102:617–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Chari VV, Kehoe PJ (1998) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Staff, Report 251

  6. Chari VV, Kehoe PJ (1990) Sustainable plans. J Polit Econ 98:783–802

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Correia IH (1996) Should capital income be taxed in the steady state? J Public Econ 60:147–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Domínguez B (2007) Public debt and optimal capital taxes without commitment. J Econ Theory 135:159–170

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Domínguez B (2010) The time-consistency of government debt and institutional restrictions on the level of debt (manuscript submitted for publication)

  10. Domínguez B, Feng Z (2014) An evaluation of constitutional constraints on capital taxation (manuscript submitted for publication)

  11. Feng Z (2014) Time consistent optimal fiscal policy over the business cycle. Quant Econ (forthcoming)

  12. Feng Z, Miao J, Peralta-Alva A, Santos M (2014) Numerical simulation of nonoptimal dynamic equilibrium models. Int Econ Rev 55:83–110

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Fernández-Villaverde J, Tsyvinski A (2002) Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model without commitment (manuscript submitted for publication)

  14. Judd K, Yeltekin S, Conklin J (2003) Computing supergame equilibria. Econometrica 71:1239–1254

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Klein P, Krusell P, Ríos-Rull J-V (2008) Time-consistent public policy. Rev Econ Stud 75:789–808

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85:473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Lucas RE (1990) Supply-side economics: an analytical review. Oxf Econ Pap 42:293–316

    Google Scholar 

  18. Lucas RE, Stokey NL (1983) Optimal fiscal and monetary policy in an economy without capital. J Monet Econ 12:55–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. McCallum BT (1995) Two fallacies concerning central-bank independence. Am Econ Rev 85:207–211

    Google Scholar 

  20. Mankiw NG, Weinzierl M, Yagan D (2009) Optimal taxation in theory and practice. J Econ Perspect 23:147–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Phelan C, Stacchetti E (2001) Sequential equilibria in a Ramsey tax model. Econometrica 69:1491–1518

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  22. Rogoff K (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Q J Econ 100:1169–1189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Rogoff K (1987) Reputational constraints on monetary policy. Carnegie–Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 26:141–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Sleet C (1997) Recursive methods for solving credible government policy problems. Mimeo, KSM-MEDS, Northwestern University, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  25. Sleet C, Yeltekin S (2015) On the computation of value correspondences for dynamic games. Dyn Games Appl. doi:10.1007/s13235-015-0139-1

  26. Stockman D (2001) Balanced-budget rules: welfare loss and optimal policies. Rev Econ Dyn 4:438–459

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhigang Feng.

Additional information

We thank the Editors and an anonymous Referee for their valuable comments. All the remaining errors are ours.

Appendix

Appendix

See Figs. 1, 2, 3 and 4.

1.1 Calibration

In order to calibrate the parameters for our quantitative exercise, we consider an initial steady state that corresponds to an economy with similar statistics to those of the USA. In our simulations, one period corresponds to 1 year.

Our calibration follows that of [4], which is consistent with US data. In the initial steady state, the tax rates on capital and labor income are set equal to 27.1 and 23.7 %, respectively. We choose a public consumption to output ratio equal to 19 % and consider no public debt.

We assume the utility function (2) and a Cobb-Douglas production function \(y_{t}=k_{t}^{\alpha }n_{t}^{1-\alpha }.\) We choose a capital share of 0.34 and a depreciation rate of 0.08. The discount factor is set to deliver a capital to output ratio of 2.71 in the initial steady state. In (2), the coefficient of risk aversion \(\sigma \) is set equal to unity and the labor-supply elasticity is set so that \(\chi \)= 0.32. The weight on labor disutility \(\gamma _{n}\) is chosen so that hours worked are 0.23 in the initial steady state. The weight on public consumption \(\gamma _{g}\) is chosen so that social planner’s solution delivers a public consumption to output ratio equal to 19 %.

Table 1 summarizes the parameter values used in our baseline economy.

Table 1 Parameter values for the baseline economy

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Domínguez, B., Feng, Z. The Time-Inconsistency Problem of Labor Taxes and Constitutional Constraints. Dyn Games Appl 6, 225–242 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-015-0149-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-015-0149-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation